Crime as governance: towards a 21st century
criminology
John Lea 2002
This is a paper I gave at the 2001 Annual Conference of the German Criminological Association in
Bielefeld. It is published in German as: ‘Kriminalität als Governance. Überlegungen zu einer
Kriminologie des 21. Jahrhunderts’ in M. Althoff, P. Becker et al. (eds) (2004) Zwischen Anomie
und Inszenierung: Interpretationen der Entwicklung der Kriminalität und der sozialen
Kontrolle. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlag. (ISBN 3-8329-0561-8)
As we enter the twenty-first century we need a new understanding of crime adequate
to the new conditions in which we live. If we are to avoid the continual
marginalisation of criminology we must be aware that the development of our
discipline was based on particular historical conditions which are fast changing
beyond recognition. Traditionally, criminology, echoing criminal law, presupposed a
view of crime as
•
•
•
•
An exceptional event rather than a normally expected occurrence
A form of pathology, originating from and overwhelmingly located in, the
marginalised periphery of society
An episodic, and frequently brutal, disruption of otherwise normal socioeconomic processes.
An object, or target, of governance. Criminality is a phenomena to be
regulated and reduced to manageable proportions by the resources at the
disposal of the modern state and other social institutions. The role of
criminology is to assist in this process of management and control.
This perspective was sufficiently strongly rooted that it seemed almost a logical
contradiction to question whether crime had these characteristics. The perspective is
still strongly entrenched in popular opinion and the working of criminal justice
institutions. Nevertheless, for a number of years, critical criminologists have been
pushing beyond the confines of this traditional view: not to negate it entirely, but to
show that it is one aspect of a more complex and rapidly changing state of affairs.
Crime as normal and non pathological
For the last thirty years, until recently, in most societies we have witnessed rising rates
of crime. As crime becomes more frequent it loses its status as an exceptional event
and becomes “a standard, background feature of our lives—a taken for granted
1
element of late modernity.” (Garland 1996: 446) Crime rates recently have been
falling slightly, but this only serves to underline the changed situation. It is no longer
simply a question of the amount of crime but, more importantly, the change in its
socio-economic role and function.
An aspect of this which has attracted some recent comment is the increasingly
blurred boundaries both between criminality and other forms of risky behaviour to
be avoided. There is a growing confusion between actual criminality and a diffuse
feeling of the need to fortify oneself, one’s family and neighbourhood, against risky
people, against the new ‘dangerous classes’, with the latter often taking on ethnic as
well as class connotations. And as the other side of the coin, those who have money
and property, and are members of groups with whom one has no social relations of
trust and dependency increasingly appear as legitimate targets for crime. People who
are not known or interacted with become the vehicle for suspicion and fear. This
echoes the ‘society of others’ characteristic of early capitalism captured by Frederick
Engels’ portrayal of urban life in the English industrial city in which
“(t)he brutal indifference, the unfeeling isolation of each in his private interest…
The dissolution of mankind into monads, of which each one has a separate
principle, the world of atoms, is here carried out to its utmost extreme.” (Engels
1845: 329)
Various aspects of this theme have been reflected in criminology. Thus Sebastian
Scheerer has written about the process whereby our image of the delinquent is
undergoing a process of “decategorization in a fragmented society…” as a result of
which there is a “fading or withering away of the clear-cut categories of
‘delinquent’…”(Scheerer 1996: 440). Georges Vigarello, in his study of the history of
rape and sexual abuse in France observes how “…the degenerate on the social
margins, has been replaced by the anonymous abuser… a culprit with no special
features, socially integrated and professionally accepted…” (Vigarello 2001: 235). For
Jock Young those people that we regard as risks are “…everywhere and not restricted
to criminals and outsiders.” (Young 1999: 66) The result is that the criminal justice
institutions are joined by, and become integrated with, a variety of other discourses
and strategies oriented to the management of risks.
The fact that crime becomes a normalised risk of postmodern life and the identity of
criminal offenders becomes blurred, implies also, as its accompaniment, the
normalisation of activities and motivations hitherto considered criminal. Crime
becomes an increasingly normal activity to be entered into. There is a decreasing
need for guilt, rationalisation or ‘techniques of neutralisation’ (Sykes and Matza
1957). Criminals are no longer innovators in the Mertonian sense, (Merton 1957)
2
seeking status by deviant means, they are just doing what everyone else is doing.
Crime is increasingly “…generated less by a deficit than a hypertrophy of
opportunities… the effect of the gigantic and uncontrolled proliferation of ways in
which status can be achieved…” (Ruggiero 1993: 135)
All these themes relate to a perceived process of social and economic fragmentation
characteristic of ‘postmodern’(for example Bauman 1995) or ‘late modern’ (Giddens
1990) or ‘risk’ society (Beck 1992), with an implied weakening of the distinctions
between normal and pathological, culture and subculture, moral and immoral.
Twenty years ago this fragmentation could still be celebrated as the beginning of an
epoch of postmodernity which “expands the potentialities and identities available to
ordinary people in their everyday working, social, familial and sexual lives.” (Hall
1989: 129) But now we are more aware of the dark side of this process. A collapse of
the ‘organised modernity’ of welfare state Keynesianism (Wagner 1994) has led to
expanding opportunities for those with wealth but only as part of a growing crisis of
poverty and social inequality combined with a new aggressive ‘Americanised’
capitalism which is concerned only with profit taking and is decreasingly concerned
to fulfil the requirements of social integration and solidarity. This tendency is fostered
by two factors. Firstly, the increasing role of speculative finance capital in the world
economy which, deploying purely monetary methods of profit taking such as
speculation in currency and bond markets, has little interest in the sustaining social
integration. Secondly, globalisation and the massive expansion of communications
networks (Castells 1996) enhances the ability of manufacturing capital to move its
labour intensive processes to low wage regions rather than sustain the wage and
social welfare costs of a traditional ‘Fordist’ working class. One important
manifestation of this is the progressive decline in taxation revenues from business
corporations (Martin and Schumann 1997, Hertz 2001)
This brings us to a second aspect of the changing nature of crime. Behind the
statistical and cultural normalisation of crime lies the process of structural
normalisation whereby criminality—especially, but not only, economic criminality—
increasingly functions as a mechanism for the reproduction of social and economic
life rather than simply its disruption. This was foreseen some years ago by the Italian
criminologist Umberto Santino who identified a transition whereby “…events
formerly considered as ‘criminal ways to capitalism’, occurring in peripheral zones
and in secondary social spheres, have turned into ‘the criminal ways of capitalism
and contemporary society’.” (Santino 1988: 232) We enter the epoch of a ‘mixed
economy of governance’ in which criminality is no longer simply a target of, but itself
a form of, governance: at the level of economic processes related to the accumulation
of capital, the social processes of the reproduction of community life, and the political
processes of power and rule. In becoming a form of governance criminality does not
3
cease to be brutal and disruptive of civilised life. It is simply that this is the direction
of development of social and economic processes in general. The increasing
instability, risky, and even barbaric nature of social life in the twenty-first century,
involves in some respects a return to forms of society that predated the development
of modern industrial capitalism.
Crime and capital
The increasing blurring of boundaries between organised crime, corporate crime and
legitimate business is well known (Ruggiero 1996, 2000). Organised crime is a branch
of big business: it is simply the illegal sector of capital. It has been estimated that by
the middle of the 1990s the ‘gross criminal product’ of organised crime made it the
20th richest organisation in the world and richer than 150 sovereign states (Castells
1998: 169). The world’s gross criminal product has been estimated at 20 percent of
world trade. (de Brie 2000)
The structure of criminal enterprise no longer conforms to archaic forms of ‘family’
organisation such as characterised the old Sicilian Mafia. Rather, newer flexible
forms of ‘entrepreneurial’ criminal organisation and methods of operation, highly
adapted to fast moving global networks, achieve increasing integration into the
legitimate economy through sophisticated money laundering techniques (see Carter
1997). The use of encrypted electronic mail, anonymous Web sites and the myriad of
instantaneous transactions which constitute the Internet in general and financial
markets in particular, render the legal and the illegal increasingly indistinguishable
and where distinguished, beyond the reach of national law enforcement agencies.
Criminality is normalised by the networks. (see Castells 1998: 202, van Duyne 1997)
Meanwhile legitimate business both actively seeks relations with criminal
organisations and adopts methods akin to those of organised crime. Immigrant
smuggling eases labour supply problems in a variety of manufacturing sectors such as
clothing and food, construction and agriculture and in ‘dirty economies’ where semilegal employment is interspersed with employment in more directly criminal activity.
(Ruggiero 1997) Conversely, the global sphere of operations of multinational
corporations enables the export of the most brutal aspects of cheap labour to
convenient locations in the southern hemisphere where “…workers have to contend
with thugs hired by the bosses, blackleg trade unions, strike-breakers, private police
and death squads.” (de Brie 2000: 4) Such brutal labour regimes in third world
countries can then be presented as characteristics of the ‘lack of governance’ in these
societies and nothing to do with the dynamics of global capitalism. In fact
competition and the need to minimise production costs create a situation in which
“corporations find it less and less possible to operate without engaging in criminal
4
activity.” (Bello 2001: 16, see also Mokhiber and Weissman 1999, Ganesan 1999)
The collusion of multinational corporations with various forms of violence evokes
memories of an earlier stage of capitalist development such as the period of the
American ‘robber barons’ (Sombart 1967)
The legal financial sector meanwhile, with an eye on the growing wealth of organised
crime, may go out of its way to attract criminal investments. The closure of the Bank
of Credit and Commerce International in 1991 gave a glimpse of the tip of an
iceberg whereby legitimate private banks and investment traders openly tout for legal
and illegal funds without making a fuss about the distinction between the two.
(Kochan and Whittington 1991, see also Chossudovsky 1996, de Brie 2000) A further
indicator is the fact that legitimate capital is turning to the same tactics as organised
crime. The activity of drugs cartels laundering their profits through ‘offshore’
banking facilities (banks in states which guarantee zero taxation of deposits and
absolute secrecy about the identity of investors) “…pales, however, beside the
gigantic losses to the public purse that result from the legally organised flight of
capital.” (Martin and Schumann 1997: 63) In this way legitimate capital enhances its
power over governments to reduce tax burdens not only with the threat to relocate
employment but also by adopting some of the tactics and resources of organised
crime. Indeed, criminal capital forces legitimate capital to compete with it to
overcome the ‘burden’ of having to pay at least some minimal tax revenue. (Shelley
1998: 608-9)
Crime and community
The second arena in which the ‘mixed economy of governance’ develops is in the
role of criminality as a social cushion against poverty and economic collapse. As a
United Nations research report observed
“At a time of narrowing economic opportunity across wide areas of the world,
participation in the illegal economy furthermore constitutes one of the few
realistic options available to many families who simply need to ensure a basic
level of subsistence. Illegality makes certain commodities or services unusually
profitable. Thus the drug trade has become one of the central economic
activities of the late twentieth century, drawing millions of people - from the
peasant villages of Third World countries to the inner cities of the industrialized
North - into networks of exchange which provide great wealth for some and a
tolerable living for many who have limited alternative sources of income.”
(UNRISD 1994: 3)
5
Cocaine production acts as a counter to the impoverishment of thousands of Latin
American peasant farmers, reducing the impact of falling world prices for agricultural
products and raw materials in these areas. Attempts, usually financed by the United
States, to eradicate coca production are periodically met with organised resistance
(Thorpe 2000). Illegal imports of hard currency in Latin American drug producing
states, usually in US dollars, may help counteract the effects of export of profits by
foreign companies and investors. (Keh 1996, Santino 1988) The laundering of profits
from the drugs trade helps sustain the growth of offshore banking facilities whose
closure would have a devastating effect on already meagre living standards in the
impoverished economies where they are located. In a similar way, drugs profits
function, in both producing and consuming countries, as a source of capital and
credit for legal enterprise, particularly small business, which also provide conduits for
money laundering. (Ruggiero 1993, Ruggiero and South 1995) Meanwhile low wage
jobs in poor communities do not enable escape from poverty into stable legal jobs but
rather lead back into the criminal and informal economies. The networks of legal job
search are often simultaneously those that yield information about criminal
opportunities and the availability of drugs or cheap stolen goods. (Johnston et al.
2000) Widespread criminality in poor areas both brutalises and terrorises
populations, but at the same time is a factor in social and economic survival.
However, just as criminality can no longer be seen as an economic and socially
marginal parasite which simply disrupts legal activity, neither is it some beneficent
force defying the logic of capital accumulation. Workers and producers in the illegal
sector are not protected from the rigours of the market and employment insecurity.
Drugs are generally carried across international frontiers by unskilled and low paid
couriers, often young women from third world poor communities who are ruthlessly
exploited and end up being coerced into prostitution in the country of destination,
high levels of burglary to secure money for drug purchases disrupt poor communities.
Coca leaf or poppy farmers in Latin America or Asia at one end of the production
chain, and street dealers at the other end, are paid a pittance compared to the
enormous profits made by criminal entrepreneurs. Profits from drug sales are
increasingly less likely to be reinvested in local activities, either legal or illegal, than in
global financial markets.(Hagan 1994: 96) As it expands its scope of activities,
organised crime’s employment structure assimilates to that of legal employment with
unskilled street workers facing scant chance of upward mobility. (Ruggiero and South
1995, Bourgois 1996)
Crime and power
The final dimension of the ‘mixed economy of governance’ is the substitution of
criminal rule for that of legitimate state agencies. Criminal organisations, without
6
ceasing in any way to engage in criminality and brutal violence, substitute themselves
for a weak, distant legal authority and appropriate to themselves the role of
punishment, dispute mediation, and the pacification of various social groups, usually
the poor. In Europe we encountered this phenomenon in the form of the old Sicilian
Mafia (Blok 1975, Arlacchi 1988, Hess 1998, Catanzaro 1992) and in the United
States on a more localised level in the old Cosa Nostra regimes of New York and
Chicago during the 1920s and 1930s (Abadinsky 1994). During the 1950s it was
widely believed that the economic and social stabilisation inaugurated by the
Keynesian welfare state was undermining the power of such organisations and
reducing them to the status of simple petty crime. (Arlacchi 1988, Merton 1957, Bell
1961)
The demise of organised crime was a premature hypothesis which was falsified by the
rise of new forms of ‘entrepreneurial’ criminality mentioned above, oriented to
trading and the accumulation of wealth. These organisations are seen as having less
interest in political control over territory. Their main interest is making money and,
furthermore, they cannot possibly substitute themselves for the power of the modern
state. They seek rather to neutralise the capacity of the state either by corrupting
particular groups of state functionaries—judges, police, politicians—or by escaping,
like nineteenth century bandits and robbers, into areas beyond the reach of the state.
Some of these areas take a radically new form in the shape of the global electronic
networks, sophisticated money laundering and complex financial disguises. The
inability of national states to effectively police such areas, despite much celebrated
international co-operation, is well known (Strange 1996, George 1999).
However, more traditional forms of sanctuary are of increasing importance. The
dynamics of global capitalist development have lead to the reappearance of large
tracts of territory which include parts of large cities and even entire regions in which
governance by legitimate political or even commercial institutions is episodic or nonexistent and which also function as effective sanctuaries for criminal organisation.
During the heyday of the Keynesian welfare state, the 1950s and 1960s, such areas
were seen as indications of ‘backwardness’, resistant to the modernising and socially
inclusive tendencies of the epoch, but which would eventually be integrated into the
mainstream by means of correct social and economic planning. But now such areas
are expanding rather than contracting. The expansion of these derelict ‘wild zones’ of
the city is increasingly as much a problem in Europe as in North America or the third
world. We have already noted how globalisation is leading powerful sectors of capital
to lose interest in providing funds for social integration. A particular manifestation of
this process is the neglect of the city as integrating space. As the geographer David
Harvey has noted
7
“In the past, capital regarded cities as important places which had to be
efficiently organised and where social controls needed to operate in some sort of
meaningful way. We now find that capital is no longer concerned about cities.
Capital needs fewer workers and much of it can move all over the world,
deserting problematic places and populations at will. As a result, the coalition
between big capital and bourgeois reformism has disappeared.” (Harvey 1997:
20)
Under such conditions criminal organisations oriented to trade and money making,
in seeking sanctuary from the surveillance of the state in such areas, also find
themselves embracing once again some of the older functions of mediation of
conflicts and pacification of populations. Meanwhile we are reminded that traditional
criminal organisations such as the Sicilian Mafia never converted to a purely
entrepreneurial money making organisation nor relinquished its aim of territorial
domination. (Paoli 1998, 2000) Rather than, or in addition to, corrupting and
neutralising the existing state agencies to ‘make the world safe for crime’ criminal
come to constitute brutal and violent regimes of governance from below (Stenson
1998, 1999). Needless to say, cities in the United States provide to most extreme
examples with criminal groups
“…exercising extraordinary levels of quasi-legitimate coercive and commercial
power in hundreds of housing projects, poor neighborhoods, and city halls all
over the United States—those who dissent against them can be tortured, those
who oppose them are murdered, those who accept them are exploited, those
who openly embrace them can be served.” (Luke 1996. See also Davis 1990,
1998)
Even such violent regimes are complex mixed economies of governance, involving
alliances and forms of ‘political compromise’. Local government agencies,
commercial entrepreneurs, political parties, ethnic organisations and police agencies
even if weak in such areas, are still important sources of funds, real estate and
protection for criminal activities. Add to this the dependence of poor communities on
products of criminal activity—such as cheap stolen goods—and rather than a
sovereignty of pure force we have rather complex dynamics of governance of
populations; a state of affairs appropriately described by Manuel Castells with the
term perverse integration. (see Castells 1998: 141-2)
The entire dynamic is repeated on a global scale in which “huge areas of the world
already lie outside the jurisdiction of any state.” (George 1999: 13) and provide
sanctuaries for powerful criminal organisations, terrorists and warlords. These
ungovernable chaotic entities, are to be found in many parts of Africa, East Asia and
parts of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. They are characterised by
8
“…the state's inability to maintain control of its national territory and
population. Whole sectors of the economy, towns, provinces and regions fall
under the yoke of new warlords, drug traffickers or Mafia. Respect for law and
order and the institutions of civil society evaporate. The people fall prey to
armed groups, and then come to rely, not on government or national
authorities, but on humanitarian organisations such as the International Red
Cross, Médecins sans Frontières and Oxfam, and various branches of the
United Nations.” (de Rivero 1999)
In such situations what remains of the legitimate state apparatus may be simply
pillaged and transformed into an instrument of such factions with the result that “noone can tell any longer which parts of the state apparatus still defend the rule of law,
and which have been contracted by one set of criminals to wage war on their rivals.”
(Martin and Schumann 1997: 210) In Sub-Saharan Africa, for example, the collapse
of political rule into forms of criminal activity “…has become the dominant trait of a
sub-continent in which the state has literally imploded under the combined effects of
economic crisis, neo-liberal programs of structural adjustment and the loss of
legitimacy of political institutions.” (Bayart et al. 1999: 19)
Such chaos and violence frequently appears as the breakdown of all governance
while in fact, as with the role of criminal groups in urban areas, quite complex forms
of regulation are taking place, coherent strategies are being pursued by well
organised groups. This can be illustrated with three examples. Firstly, in the area of
war and political conflict criminal groups may be linked with terrorist or guerrilla
groups in the fighting of the ‘new wars’ which have tended, in the period since the
ending of the Cold War, to replace classic conflicts between nation states. Mary
Kaldor, observing the wars in former Yugoslavia during the 1990s, describes the
ingredients of new military machines as including “a disparate range of different
types of groups such as paramilitary units, local warlords, criminal gangs, police
forces, mercenary groups and also regular armies including breakaway units of
regular armies.” (Kaldor 1999: 8) This blurring of criminality and warfare results in a
situation in which
“…no one knows who should be considered ‘as a criminal’, who are ‘the police’,
and who are ‘the army’. Criminals become incorporated into formal control
agencies and criminal behaviour is not only unpunished—it is even regarded as
desirable as a strategy of inter-ethnic war.” (Nikolic-Ristanovic 1998: 475)
Nevertheless behind the apparently chaotic nature of these new forms of warfare
clear strategies are visible, relating to the consolidation of ‘ethnically cleansed’
territories and with even the interests of the major world states being reflected in such
9
conflicts. Secondly, in many areas criminal groups may be serving the interests of
powerful elites who remain distant from the actual sites of conflict. In nineteenth
century Sicily the old mafia pacified the local population in the interests of powerful
agrarian elites who were generally absentee landlords. The twenty-first century
version is that of multinational corporations financing smugglers and mercenary
armies to control diamond deposits and destabilise fragile African states to the
advantage of western capital (Hart 2001).
The final example is the experience of Russian organised crime which by some
commentators has been regarded for a time as a form of ‘transitional governance’
awaiting the stabilisation of more modern state institutions. Russian organised crime,
expanding rapidly after the collapse of the Soviet Union, facilitated by large scale
privatisation of state assets, has been portrayed by some imaginative commentators as
a necessary transitional phenomena between the old Soviet system and a new
dynamic capitalism. In this argument organised crime takes the form of an
embryonic business class analogous to the nineteenth century American ‘robber
barons’ who showed contempt for the criminal law but nevertheless developed the
capitalist economy. Additionally, the weakness of the Russian state creates a
situation, analogous in some ways to nineteenth century Sicily, (Varese 1994) in
which the organised crime provides the only viable form of governance. From this
standpoint
“Russia's criminal world… has become the only force that can give stability,
that is capable of stamping out debts, of guaranteeing the banks repayment of
loans and of considering property disputes efficiently and fairly. The criminal
world has essentially taken on the state functions of legislative and judicial
authority.” (Leitzel 1995: 43, see also Williams 1997: 6-7)
The fact is however that at least some of the wealth of American ruthless capitalists
like John D. Rockefeller or Cornelius Vanderbilt (see Abadinsky 1994) was reinvested
under conditions favourable to sustained economic development. In Russia the irony
of a group of criminals who have “…contributed nothing, produced nothing, risked
nothing… who simply robbed what was there… manipulating the country's
currency, destabilising its fragile economy, stripping it of its oil, gold, timber…”
(Sterling 1994: 96-97) being taken seriously as a business class is that they indeed
represent something, albeit in an exaggerated form, of the future for capitalism as a
whole under present conditions. Capitalism is indeed developing apace in Russia but
it is the type of capitalism which portends the future of the system as a whole:
increasingly breaking its own rules of legality in order to maintain the short term rate
of profit and the wholesale wrecking of national economies through the rapid export
of large amounts of capital, by a mixture of legal and illegal means, to areas of higher
profitability justified by an aggressive ethic of cynical self interest. Organised crime,
10
rather than a parasitic capitalism, as a disruption of normal and efficient capital
accumulation is, unfortunately an increasingly important tendency of the system as a
whole. If unchecked, the end result of such a tendency will be a new form of
barbarism, appropriately termed by Susan George ‘gangster capitalism’ which
“if it succeeds in supplanting legitimate business, traditional rules of competition
would be blasted to bits while corporate terrorism would become the order of
the day. Today's relatively predictable business climate would be replaced by
durable anarchy and a Hobbesian war of all against all among individuals, firms
and nations.” (George 1999: 15)
Under such a nightmare scenario law enforcement would be recruited by powerful
corporations as simply another weapon against competitors.
Conclusion
This is rather a gloomy point at which to conclude and it is necessary to emphasise
that I have tried to give an illustration of tendencies at work, tendencies whose pace
of development differs profoundly between countries, communities and types of
crime. Such tendencies can undoubtedly be halted long before the type of ‘gangster
capitalism’ described in the previous paragraph becomes a reality or before the
disappearance of the utility of the concept of crime as an ingredient of the defence of
human rights. Already there are new forms of opposition to these tendencies, now
developing on a global scale both within and outside official institutions. What I have
tried to underline is that the best contribution that critical criminology can make to
such a movement is to firmly insist that our object of study is not the exhaust fumes of
modern—or perhaps rather, postmodern—social and economic life but some of the
most important components of its motor and steering mechanism.
Bibliography
Abadinsky, Howard (1994) Organized Crime (fourth edition). Chicago: Nelson-Hall.
Arlacchi, P. (1988) Mafia Business. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bauman, Zigmunt (1995) Life in Fragments: Essays in Postmodern Morality. Oxford:
Blackwell.
Bayart, J. Ellis, S. Hibour, B. (1999) ‘From Kleptocracy to the Felonius State?’ in The
Criminalization of the State in Africa. Indiana University Press.
11
Beck, Ulrich (1992) Risk Society. London: Sage Publications. (orig. 1986
Risikogesellschaft: Auf dem Weg in eine andere Moderne. Frankfurt am Main:
Suhrkamp Verlag)
Bell, Daniel (1961) 'Crime As An American Way of Life: A Queer Ladder of Social
Mobility' in The End of Ideology pp 127-150. New York: Collier.
Bello, Walden (2001) ‘The Global Conjuncture: Characteristics and Challenges’
International Socialism no 91 pp 11-20
Blok, Anton (1975) The Mafia of a Sicilian Village 1860-1980: A Study of Violent
Peasant Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bourgois, Philipe (1996) In Search of Respect: selling crack in El Barrio. Cambridge
University Press.
Carter, David (1997), 'International Organized Crime: Emerging Trends in
Entrepreneurial Crime. in Ryan, P. Rush, G. eds. Understanding Organized Crime
in Global Perspective., Newbury Park: Sage Publications.
Castells, Manuel (1996) The Rise of the Network Society (The Information Age:
Economy Society and Culture. volume I.) Oxford: Blackwell.
Castells, Manuel (1998) End of Millenium (The Information Age: Economy Society
and Culture. volume III.) Oxford: Blackwell.
Catanzaro, Raimondo (1992) 'Men Of Respect': A Social History of the Sicilian
Mafia. New York: The Free Press
Chossudovsky, Michel (1996), 'The Business of Crime and the Crimes of Business:
Globalization and the Criminalization of Economic Activity', Covert Action
Quarterly No 58 (Fall) pp 24-30.
Davis, Mike (1990) City of Quartz: excavating the future in Los Angeles. London:
Verso.
Davis, Mike (1998), ‘Beyond Blade Runner’ Ecology of Fear: Los Angeles and the
Imagination of Disaster, New York: Henry Holt.
12
de Brie, Christian (2000) ‘Thick as thieves’ Le Monde Diplomatique (April) electronic
edition: http://www.monde-diplomatique.fr/en/2000/04/05debrie
de Rivero, Oswaldo, (1999) ‘States in Ruin, Conflicts Without End: The Economics
Of Future Chaos’ Le Monde Diplomatique (English Electronic Edition) June.
http://www.monde-diplomatique.fr/en/1999/06/?c=03rivero
Engels, Frederick (1845/1975), 'The Condition of the Working Class in England' in
Marx, Engels, Collected Works volume 4., Moscow: Progress Publishers. (orig.
MEGA?)
Ganesan, A. (1999) 'Corporation Crackdowns: Business backs brutality'. Dollars and
Sense. No 223 May-June
Garland, David (1996), ‘The Limits of the Sovereign State: Strategies of Crime
Control in Contemporary Society’, British Journal of Criminology vol 36 pp 445471.
George, Susan (1999), The Lugano Report: On Preserving Capitalism in the
Twenty-first Century, London: Pluto Press.
Giddens, Anthony. (1990) The Consequences of Modernity: Self and Society in the
Late Modern Age. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Hagan, John (1994), Crime and Disrepute, Berkeley: Pineforge Press
Hall, Stuart, (1989) ‘The Meaning of New Times’ in Hall, S. and Jaques, M. eds.
New Times. London: Lawrence and Wishart
Harvey, David (1997) 'Contested Cities: social processes and spatial form' in Jewson,
Nicholas, MacGregor, Susanne. (eds.) Transforming Cities: contested governance
and new spatial divisions. London: Routledge.
Hart, M. (2001) Diamond: The History of a Cold Blooded Love Affair. London:
Fourth Estate.
Hertz, Noreena (2001), The Silent Takeover: Global Capitalism and the Death of
Democracy, London: Heinemann.
Hess, Henner (1998) Mafia and Mafiosi: Origin, Power and Myth. London: Hurst
(orig. 1970 Mafia, Zentrale Herrschaft und Lokale Gegenmacht. Tubingen: Mohr)
13
Johnston, Les, MacDonald, R., Mason, P., Ridley, L., Webster, C. (2000), Snakes
and Ladders: Young People, Transitions, and Social Exclusion, Bristol: Policy Press.
Kaldor, Mary (1999), New and Old Wars: organized violence in a global era,
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Keh, Douglas (1996), ‘Drug Money in a Changing World: Economic Reform and
Criminal Finance’. UNDCP Technical Series: No 4, Vienna, United Nations
International Drug Control Programme.
Kochan, N. Whittington B. (1991), Bankrupt: The BCCI Fraud, London, Victor
Gollancz.
Leitzel, Jim (1995), Russian Economic Reform, London: Routledge.
Luke, Tim (1996) 'Nationality and Sovereignty in the New World Order'.
AntePodium: [3/96] electronic edition
(http://www.vuw.ac.nz/atp/articles/Luke_9608.html)
Martin, Hans-Peter Schumann, Harald. (1997) The Global Trap: Globalization and
the Assault on Democracy and Prosperity. London: Zed Books. (orig. 1996 Die
Globalizierungsfalle: der Angriff auf Demokratie und Wohlstand. Reinbeck bei
Hamburg: Rowohlt Verlag.)
Merton, Robert (1957) Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: Free Press.
Mokhiber, Russell, Weissman, Robert. (1999) Corporate Predators: the hunt for
mega-profits and the attack on democracy. Monroe, Maine: Common Courage
Press.
Nicolic-Ristanovic, Vesna (1998), ‘War and Crime in the Former Yugolslavia’ in
Ruggiero, V., South, N., Taylor, I. eds. The New European Criminology: Crime and
Social Order in Europe, London: Routledge.
Ruggiero, Vincenzo (1993), ‘Organized Crime in Italy: Testing alternative
definitions’, Social and Legal Studies vol 2. no. 2 pp 131-148.
Ruggiero, Vincenzo (1997), 'Trafficking in Human Beings: Slaves in Contemporary
Europe', International Journal of the Sociology of Law 25(3): 231-44.
14
Ruggiero, Vincenzo, South, Nigel (1995), Eurodrugs: drug use, markets and
trafficking in Europe, London: UCL Press.
Santino, Umberto (1988), ‘The financial mafia: the illegal accumulation of wealth
and the financial industrial complex’, Contemporary Crises 12 pp 203-43.
Scheerer, Sebastian. (1998) 'The Delinquent as a Fading Category of Knowledge' in
V. Ruggiero, N. South, I. Taylor eds. The New European Criminology: Crime and
Social Order in Europe. pp 425-440. London: Routledge.
Shelley, Louise (1998), 'Crime and Corruption in the Digital Age', Journal of
International Affairs vol. 51 no.2 pp 605-620.
Sombart, Werner (1967) The Quintessence of Capitalism: A Study of the History and
Psychology of the Modern Businessman. New York: Fertig Howard
Stenson, Kevin (1998) 'Beyond histories of the present'. Economy and Society 27:4
333-352.
Stenson, Kevin (1999) 'Crime Control, Governmentality and Sovereignty' in Russell
Smandych ed. Governable Places: Readings in Governmentality and Crime Control
pp 45-73. Aldershot: Dartmouth Press.
Sterling, Clare (1994), Crime Without Frontiers: the worldwide expansion of
organised crime and the pax mafiosa, Boston: Little Brown .
Strange, Susan (1996) The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World
Economy. Cambridge University Press.
Sykes, Gresham, Matza, David. (1957) 'Techniques of Neutralization: a theory of
delinquency'. American Sociological Review (22) pp 664-70.
Thorpe, Nick (2000) ‘Leaves on the line’ The Guardian (London) August 25
United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) (1994) Social
Integration: approaches and issues. World Summit for Social Development Briefing
Paper 1. Geneva: UNRISD
van Duyne, Petrus (1997), ‘Organized Crime, corruption and power’, Crime Law
and Social Change 26: pp 201-238.
15
Varese, Frederico (1994), 'Is Sicily the Future of Russia? Private Protection and the
rise of the Russian Mafia, European Journal of Sociology vol xxxv no 2 pp 224-258.
Vigarello, Georges. (2001) A History of Rape: Sexual Violence in France from the
16th to the 20th Century. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Wagner, Peter (1994) A Sociology of Modernity: Liberty and Discipline. London:
Routledge.
Williams, Phil ed. (1997), Russian Organized Crime: The New Threat, Liverpool:
Frank Cass.
Young, Jock (1999) The Exclusive Society: Social Exclusion, Crime and Difference in
Late Modernity. London: Sage Publications.
16