råáp
===
=
=
======råáîÉêëáíó=çÑ=pìêêÉó
Discussion Papers in Economics
ROBUST ESTIMATES OF THE NEW KEYNESIAN
PHILLIPS CURVE
By
Luis F. Martins
(Department of Quantitative Methods, ISCTE, Portugal)
&
Vasco J. Gabriel
(University of Surrey and NIPE-UM)
DP 02/06
Department of Economics
University of Surrey
Guildford
Surrey GU2 7XH, UK
Telephone +44 (0)1483 689380
Facsimile +44 (0)1483 689548
Web www.econ.surrey.ac.uk
ISSN: 1749-5075
On the Robustness of the New Keynesian Phillips
Curve Estimates∗
Luis F. Martins
Department of Quantitative Methods, ISCTE, Portugal
[email protected]
Vasco J. Gabriel
Department of Economics, University of Surrey, UK and NIPE-UM
[email protected]
This version: July 2006
Abstract
In this paper, we examine parameter identification in the hybrid specification of the
New Keynesian Phillips Curve proposed by Gali and Gertler (1999) by employing recently
developed inference procedures. Our results cast doubts on the empirical validity of the
NKPC.
Keywords: Weak identification; Generalized Empirical Likelihood; GMM; Phillips curve
JEL Classification: C22; E31; E32
1
Introduction
In this study, we re-evaluate the empirical validity of the hybrid version of the New Keynesian
Phillips Curve (NKPC) proposed by Gali and Gertler (1999, henceforth GG) and recently refined
by Gali, Gertler and López-Salido (2005, GGLS hereafter). In particular, we address the issue
of parameter identification of the NKPC by applying recently developed moment-conditions
inference methods. We employ Generalized Empirical Likelihood (GEL) procedures to obtain
∗
We are grateful to Jordi Gali and J. David López-Salido for providing the data used in their papers. We
are also indebted to Patrik Guggenberger for help with the GAUSS codes employed in this study. The usual
disclaimer applies.
1
parameter confidence sets, conditional on model validity. These tests have been studied by
Guggenberger and Smith (2005, 2006, GS hereafter) and Otsu (2006), based on the work of
Kleibergen (2005), developed in a GMM framework. To our knowledge, this paper is the first
empirical application of these methodologies.
GG derive their hybrid Phillips curve in a imperfectly competitive, Calvo-type price setting
framework, combining forward and backward-looking behavior in the equation
π t = λmct + γ f Et (π t+1 ) + γ b π t−1 + εt ,
(1)
where mct represents real marginal cost, Et (π t+1 ) is the expected inflation in period t and εt
captures measurement errors or unexpected mark-up shocks. The reduced-form parameters are
expressed as
λ = (1 − ω)(1 − θ)(1 − βθ)φ−1
γf
= βθφ−1
γ b = ωφ−1
φ = θ + ω[1 − θ(1 − β)]
with structural parameters β, the subjective discount rate, θ measuring price stickiness and ω
the degree of backwardness. Two main results were obtained by GG and GGLS: 1) forwardlooking behaviour is dominant, i.e., γ f is approximately as twice as large as γ b , which, although
statistically significant, was found to be quantitatively negligible; 2) real marginal cost (instead
of traditional measures of the output gap) plays a major role in driving inflation, as suggested
by a positive and significant λ.
Several authors1 have questioned the validity of these results. The issue of identification was
discussed in Mavroeidis (2005) and analysed by Ma (2002), who applies the Stock and Wright
(2000, SW henceforth) statistics. However, SW tests are not fully informative with respect
to parameter identification, since weak identification and instrument validity are being jointly
tested. Also, in an independent work, Dufour, Khalaf and Kichian (2006) use identificationrobust methods, but do so in a IV context and without taking into account the time-series
nature of the data. These studies provide evidence against the NKPC’s robustness to weak
identification, meaning that conventional GMM asymptotic theory, used in GG and GGLS, is
not valid. We rely on GEL methods, discussed in the next section, which are higher-order efficient
1
See, for example, the 2005 special issue on "The econometrics of the New Keynesian price equation" of the
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 52(6).
2
and have been found to have superior finite sample properties. Furthermore, by concentrating
on the subset of crucial parameters (θ, ω), our analysis leads to more powerful tests.
2
Econometric Framework
Given the often disappointing small sample properties of GMM, a variety of alternative estimators has been proposed. Among these, the empirical likelihood (EL), the exponential tilting
(ET) and the continuous-updating (CUE) estimators are very appealing from a theoretical perspective. Newey and Smith (2004) have shown that these methods pertain to the same class
of GEL estimators. These authors demonstrate that, while GMM and GEL estimators have
identical first-order asymptotic properties, the latter are higher-order efficient, in the sense that
these estimators are able to eliminate some sources of GMM’s biases. For example, they show
that, unlike GMM, the bias of EL does not grow with the number of moment conditions.
Consider the estimation of a p-dimensional parameter vector θ = (θ1 , ..., θp ) based on m ≥ p
moment conditions of the form E[g(yt , θ0 )] = 0, ∀t = 1, ..., T, where, in our case, g(yt , θ0 ) ≡
gt (θ0 ) = ε(xt , θ0 ) ⊗ zt for some set of variables xt and instruments zt , such that yt = (xt , zt ).
For a concave function ρ(v) and a m × 1 parameter vector λ ∈ ΛT (θ), the GEL estimator solves
the following saddle point problem
θ̂GEL = arg minp sup T −1
θ∈< λ∈ΛT
T
X
ρ[λ0 gt (θ)].
(2)
t=1
Special cases arise when ρ (v) = −(1 + v)2 /2, where θGEL coincides with the CUE, while with
ρ(v) = ln(1−v) we have the EL estimator and ρ(v) = − exp(v) leads to the ET case. When gt (θ)
is serially correlated, Anatolyev (2005) obtains similar results to Newey and Smith (2004) and
demonstrates that the smoothed GEL estimator of Kitamura and Stutzer (1997) is efficient, obP T
tained by replacing gt (θ) in (2) with the smoothed counterpart gtT (θ) ≡ 2KT1 +1 K
k=−KT gt−k (θ) .
The SEL variant, in particular, removes important sources of bias associated with the GMM,
namely the correlation between the moment function and its derivative, as well as third-order
biases.
Another major source of misleading inferences with GMM is weak identification. SW derived the appropriate asymptotic theory for this case, concluding that GMM is inconsistent and
conventional tests are therefore flawed. They developed an asymptotically valid test that allows
the researcher to construct identification-robust confidence sets (S-sets) for θ. However, SW
acknowledge difficulties with the interpretation of their method, since their procedure jointly
3
tests simple parameter hypotheses and the validity of the overidentifying restrictions. This
may be problematic since their S(θ) statistic is asymptotically χ2 (m), with degrees of freedom
growing with the number of moment conditions and, therefore, less powerful to test parameter
hypotheses, with the resulting confidence sets being less informative.
Recently, GS and Otsu (2006) propose identification-robust procedures in a GEL framework,
following the work of Kleibergen (2005). Here, we focus on the LM version of the Kleibergen-type
test proposed by GS, which was found to have advantageous finite-sample properties:
ˆ 0 )−1 Dρ (θ0 )[Dρ (θ0 )0 ∆(θ
ˆ 0 )−1 Dρ (θ0 )]−1 Dρ (θ0 )0 ∆(θ
ˆ 0 )−1 ĝT (θ0 )/2 (3)
KLM (θ0 ) = T ĝT (θ0 )0 ∆(θ
P
P
ˆ
= ST T −1 gtT (θ)gtT (θ)0 (with ST = KT + 1/2) and
with ĝT (θ) = T −1 Tt=1 gtT (θ), ∆(θ)
P
Dρ (θ) = T −1 ρ1 (λ0 gtT (θ))GtT (θ), where GtT (θ) = (∂gtT /∂θ) and ρ1 (v) = ∂ρ/∂v. The
statistic has a χ2 (p) limiting distribution that depends only on the number of parameters. This
statistic may be appropriately transformed if one wishes to test a sub-vector of θ (see GS and
Kleibergen, 2005 for details), for instance if one or more parameters are deemed to be strongly
identified. If the assumption is correct, partialling out identified parameters will deliver a more
powerful test, with a χ2 asymptotic distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number
of parameters under test.
3
Empirical Results
For comparability, we use the same dataset of GG and GGLS (see papers for details), comprising
quarterly US data (1960:1-1997:4). We concentrate on the most recent results reported in GGLS
and therefore use the same set of instruments, i.e. 2 lags of each variable, with the exception
of inflation with 4 lags. Thus, resorting to the analysis discussed in the previous section2 ,
we formed 90% confidence sets for the set of parameters (ω, θ, β) by performing a grid search
over the parameter space (restricted to the interval (0, 1), with increments of 0.01) then tested
H0 : ω = ω0 , θ = θ0 , β = β 0 and collected the values (ω 0 , θ0 , β 0 ) for which the p-value exceeded
the 10% significance level. We also present Kleibergen’s (2005) GMM approach, i.e., combining
his K statistic with an asymptotically independent J(θ) statistic for overidentifying restrictions,
distributed as χ2 (m − p), which should enhance the power of the test. For the combined J-K
test, we use αJ = 0.025 and αK = 0.075, therefore emphasizing simple parameter hypothesis
2
We used KT = 5, since the optimal bandwidth rate for the truncated kernel used in the Kitamura-Stutzer
estimator is O(T 1/3 ), (results are largely insensitive to the choice of this parameter).
4
testing3 . To save space, we report sets based on EL estimation, as there are no significant
differences with other GEL alternatives.
Moreover, we focus on the main points of contention, i.e. the relative magnitude of the
coefficients θ and ω. The latter parameter, in particular, displayed a wide range of estimated
values across the different specifications studied in GG, ranging from 0.077 to 0.522, whereas β is
estimated with more precision. Hence, in Figures 1 and 2 we present bi-dimensional confidence
sets obtained from the J-K and KLM tests, concentrated at particular values of β (here β = 0.98,
but results are the same for different values of this parameter). These sets are plotted together
with 90% confidence ellipses based on standard asymptotic theory.
As it is apparent, GMM and GEL methods produce similar results, despite their intrinsic
differences. Indeed, in both cases the robust confidence sets are much larger than standard
ellipses, with a significant proportion outside the unit cube. This feature is not only a clear
indication of weak parameter identification, but it also means that the confidence sets contain
several combinations of the reduced-form parameters that are inconsistent with the findings of
GG and GGLS. In particular, large ω’s and θ’s correspond to values of λ close to 0, which
questions the significance of the marginal cost as the forcing variable in inflation dynamics.
Furthermore, a large portion of the sets lies above ω = 0.5, hence contradicting the claim of GG
and GGLS that the degree of backwardness is negligible.
More powerful tests may be conducted if one assumes that some parameters are well identified. This involves obtaining a consistent estimate of these parameters for each value in the grid
of the parameters under test. Even when we do this, the above conclusions remain unaltered.
Figures 3 and 4 reproduce the confidence sets when β is assumed to be well identified (noted
with the superscript β̂) and the null H0 : ω = ω 0 , θ = θ0 is tested. As expected, the confidence
sets are tighter, mainly due to the reduction in the degrees of freedom. Nevertheless, they are
still unreasonably large and contain far too high values for ω when compared to what has been
reported by GG and GGLS.
Furthermore, when both β and θ are partialled out, the values of ω for which the null
H0 : ω = ω0 is not rejected reinforce the weak identification conclusion. Figures 5 and 6
plot sequences of K and KLM statistics against the corresponding χ2α (1) critical value. The
GMM procedure points to a region of non-rejection formed, roughly speaking, by the intervals
(0.2, 0.5) ∪ (0.7, 0.95), while the GEL test points to non-rejection for almost the entire range of
3
See paper for details, choosing different significance levels does not change the results qualitatively.
5
ω considered here4 , both methods thus confirming identification problems.
4
Conclusion
In summary, by employing identification-robust statistics that allow us to disentangle tests on
coefficients from tests on general model validity (and are therefore more appropriate than those
used in previous studies), we question GGLS’s claim that the NKPC is robust and empirically
plausible. We corroborate the finding that the NKPC suffers from a weak identification problem,
raising doubts on the significance of marginal costs as the forcing variable in inflation dynamics
and on the relative magnitude backward-looking of behaviour. Our conclusions are strengthened
by the use of two different approaches, GMM and GEL, which produce consistent results.
References
[1] Anatolyev, S. (2005), GMM, GEL, Serial Correlation and Asymptotic Bias, Econometrica,
73, 983-1002.
[2] Dufour, J. M., Khalaf, L. and Kichian, M. (2006), Inflation dynamics and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve: an identification robust econometric analysis, Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, forthcoming.
[3] Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (1999), Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195-222.
[4] Gali, J., Gertler, M. and López-Salido, J. D. (2005), Robustness of the estimates of the
hybrid New Keynesian Phillips curve, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1107-1118.
[5] Guggenberger, P. and Smith, R. J. (2005), Generalized Empirical Likelihood Estimators
and Tests under Partial, Weak and Strong Identification, Econometric Theory, 21, 667-709.
[6] Guggenberger, P. and Smith, R. J. (2006), Generalized Empirical Likelihood Tests in Time
Series Models With Potential Identification Failure, manuscript.
[7] Kitamura, Y. and Stutzer, M. (1997), An Information-Theoretic Alternative to Generalized
Method of Moments Estimation, Econometrica, 65, 861-874.
4
The ridge at ω = 1 corresponds to the point where {βθω = 1}, as noted by Ma (2002).
6
[8] Kleibergen, F. (2005), Testing parameters in GMM without assuming that they are identified, Econometrica, 73, 1103-1123.
[9] Ma, A. (2002), GMM estimation of the new Phillips curve, Economics Letters, 76, 411-417.
[10] Mavroeidis, S. (2005), Identification Issues in Forward-Looking Models Estimated by GMM,
with an Application to the Phillips Curve, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37, 421448.
[11] Newey, W.K. and Smith, R. J. (2004), Higher Order Properties of GMM and Generalized
Empirical Likelihood Estimators, Econometrica, 72, 219-255.
[12] Otsu, T. (2006), Generalized empirical likelihood inference under weak identification, Econometric Theory, 22, 513-528.
[13] Stock, J. H. and Wright, J. H. (2000), GMM With Weak Identification, Econometrica, 68,
1055-1096.
7
Appendix
Figure 1: J-K set concentrating at β = 0.98
1
0.8
0.6
ω
5
0.4
0.2
0
-0.2
0
0.2
0.6
θ
0.4
8
0.8
1
1.2
Figure 2: KLM set concentrating at β = 0.98
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
ω
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
θ
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
0.9
1
Figure 3: J-K β̂ set with β̂ partialled out
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
ω
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.5
θ
0.4
9
0.6
0.7
0.8
β̂
Figure 4: KLM
set with β̂ partialled out
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
ω
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
θ
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
Figure 5: K β̂ θ̂ sequence with β̂ and θ̂ partialled out
10
1
β̂ θ̂
Figure 6: KLM
sequence with β̂ and θ̂ partialled out
11