The Emerald Research Register for this journal is available at
www.emeraldinsight.com/researchregister
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
www.emeraldinsight.com/1463-7154.htm
Supply chain discontent
Supply chain
discontent
Togar M. Simatupang and Ramaswami Sridharan
Institute of Information Sciences and Technology, Massey University,
Palmerston North, New Zealand
349
Abstract
Purpose – This study was conducted to examine supply chain discontent in an integrative way.
Design/methodology/approach – The organisational economics view is adopted as an approach
to reveal multiple sources of discontent which consist of incongruent objectives, disintegrated
performance measures, unsynchronised decision-making, information asymmetry, misaligned
incentives, and fragmented business processes. All these sources separately or collectively
contribute to reduce the potential of total profits arising from collaboration.
Findings – It is argued that to effectively mitigate supply chain discontent, the chain members need
to collaboratively design antidotes for discontent. In this paper six antidotes to discontent are
proposed, namely mutual strategic objectives, appropriate performance measures, decision
synchronisation, information sharing, incentive alignment, and streamlined intercompany business
processes. It also shows that previous studies have not addressed supply chain discontent in an
integrative way.
Originality/value – This study, therefore, provides a new insight for managers to understand
multiple sources of discontent as well as its antidotes.
Keywords Supply chain management, Information disclosure, Business environment,
Economic cooperation
Paper type Conceptual paper
Introduction
A supply chain usually consists of multiple players, starting from multi-tier suppliers,
and including manufacturers, distributors, retailers, and end customers. More fierce
competition has driven most companies to seek means of enhancing performance
beyond their four wall boundaries (Bowersox, 1990). The ability of a firm in
collaborating with its upstream and downstream partners determines its success in
attaining better performance (Christopher, 1992; Jap, 2001; Spekman et al., 1998). With
collaboration, a firm is able to serve fragmented markets in which end customers
require more product varieties and availability with shorter product life cycle and at
the same time lower supply chain costs. Companies – such as Wal-Mart,
Hewlett-Packard, IBM, Intel, Saturn, Procter & Gamble, McKesson, and Starbucks –
have achieved better profitability as a result of supply chain collaboration (Fisher et al.,
2000; Kalakota, 2000; Lee et al., 1997).
A supply chain is designed to achieve a chain goal that is the result of optimising
total profits through functional differentiation and business process interdependence
in offering products to customers (Chopra and Meindl, 2001). The main concern of
supply chain management (SCM) is to create seamless and agile supply chain
processes that enable the chain members to meet customer needs at the lowest costs
The authors would like to thank Majed Al-Mashari, Karen Stanley, Alan Wright, and the two
anonymous reviewers for their helpful commentaries and support for earlier versions of this
paper.
Business Process Management
Journal
Vol. 11 No. 4, 2005
pp. 349-369
q Emerald Group Publishing Limited
1463-7154
DOI 10.1108/14637150510609390
BPMJ
11,4
350
(Kopczak and Johnson, 2003). However, the overall goal of optimising chain
profitability is difficult to achieve because of conflicting interests such as specific
wants, perceived needs, and expectations amongst chain members (Sabath and
Fontanella, 2002). The participating members are goal-seeking entities that also need to
attain their individual goals (Eliashberg and Michie, 1984). Supply chain discontent
thus occurs when two or three parties working together along the same supply chain
perceive differences in organisational settings that affect their ability to perform better.
In this situation, actions taken by one party are often beneficial to it but have
detrimental effects on other players. Supply chain discontent leads to inefficiency loss
such as high logistics costs and unnecessary costs of demand uncertainty including
surplus inventory, markdowns, and stock-outs (Buzzell et al., 1990; Fisher, 1997).
Examples of chain discontent are prevalent in various industries such as electronics
(Lee et al., 1997; Zarley, 1997), toys (Kravetz, 1999), and apparel (Fisher et al., 2000).
Each player in the examples often shifts financial risks associated with demand
uncertainty – for example, either shortages or surplus stocking costs, to other players.
Although supply chain discontent devastatingly reduces overall performance,
previous studies have paid little attention to comprehensively characterising sources
or causes of supply chain discontent (Moberg et al., 2003). Lee and Billington (1992)
first highlighted several pitfalls of collaborative inventory management. They
categorised them based on observations and interviews. After conceptualising the
enablers, impediments, and benefits, Mentzer et al. (2000) provided survey results
about the barriers to successful implementation of supply chain collaboration. Most
recently, Moberg et al. (2003) have identified seven barriers that consistently block
chain members from supply chain success, including lack of trust, little commitment to
SCM principles, fear of relinquishing control, different goals and objectives, inadequate
information systems, a short-term “Wall Street” focus on outcomes, and involvement in
too many supply chains. This study was based on observations, surveys, and
anecdotal evidence. While these studies provide a fine-grained analysis of supply chain
discontent, none of them explicitly justified the basis for identifying and categorising
sources of supply chain discontent. There is a consequent need for a research approach
that addresses sources of discontent from a structural view before initiating
appropriate ways for remedying the unfavourable situation.
Motivated by the shortcomings of previous studies, the purpose of this current
research is to conceptually examine multiple sources of supply chain discontent. It is
argued that the main responsibility of the chain members is first to identify sources of
discontent and then to find its antidotes, which help the chain members to maximise
the total profits of their collaboration efforts. Consequently, the purpose can be broken
down into three objectives:
(1) to categorise different types of discontent behaviour;
(2) to identify multiple sources of supply chain discontent; and
(3) to propose an integrative framework of antidotes to discontent.
This research departs from the organisational economics view in which
interorganisational settings influence the behaviour of actors at the
boundary-spanning interfaces of their companies (Brickley et al., 1995; Jensen and
Meckling, 1992). The emphasis is on conceptual modelling and the use of anecdotal
evidence from the real world as secondary data to illustrate and clarify the concept
(Stablein, 1999). Secondary data were commonly used in previous studies on business
process management and SCM (Barua et al., 1996; Lee, 2002; Lee et al., 1997).
Drawing on the organisational economics view (Jensen and Meckling, 1992), six
sources of supply chain discontent are identified in this study: incongruent objectives,
disintegrated performance measures, unsynchronised decision-making, information
asymmetry, misaligned incentives, and fragmented business processes. All these
sources separately or collectively contribute to reduce the potential of total profits of
collaboration. Furthermore, it is argued that to effectively mitigate supply chain
discontent, the participating members need to collaboratively design antidotes for
discontent, which consist of mutual objectives, appropriate measures of performance,
information sharing, decision synchronisation, incentive alignment, and streamlined
intercompany business processes. This integrative framework is based on the value
creation path model and adopts the complementarity theory to ensure that antidotes or
interorganisational design variables contribute maximally to the overall success of
collaboration (Milgrom and Roberts, 1990). This study thus provides a novel
conceptual model to understanding design variables in supply chain collaboration.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. The next section presents four
styles of dysfunctional behaviour of supply chain discontent. The subsequent section
discusses multiple sources of supply chain discontent that prevent players from
optimising chain profitability. Furthermore, an integrative framework of antidotes for
mitigating discontent is presented. The discussion section provides invaluable insights
about implications of the study for managers and researchers, and recommendations
for future research. The paper concludes with a summary of key ideas.
Dysfunctional behaviour of supply chain discontent
Although chain members have a common interest in expanding mutual advantage by
collaboration, a chain member may perceive its individual goal attainment as being
impeded by other members. Supply chain discontent is defined as a situation that
occurs when two or three parties working together at the same supply chain perceive
organisational differences that affect their ability to perform better to maximise
potential profits. Supply chain discontent may involve issues such as pricing control,
inventory control, operations control, control over the channel structure, and
information control, task completion, risk/reward splitting, and policy interpretation
(Munson et al., 1999; Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002). Supply chain discontent is
often characterised by a zero sum orientation that means one player wins, another
chain member must lose (Nalebuff and Brandenburger, 1996). Detrimental effects of
supply chain discontent can be inefficiencies in both operational and commercial sides
of the supply chain. Operational inefficiencies include task duplication, long lead-times,
unwanted stocks, and distorted information. Commercial inefficiencies may be pricing
distortion, unnecessary inventory costs, lost sales, and disputed risk pooling.
Supply chain discontent is manifested in dysfunctional behaviour that can be
observed during the ongoing relationship. Supply chain discontent behaviour refers to
decisions and actions – in the areas of forecasting, inventory, transportation, and
pricing – taken by individual chain members that prevent the achievement of the
chain goal. As the chain processes are interdependent, a particular action taken by one
member often affects both the operational and commercial performance of other chain
members. Individual actions such as adding a new distribution channel, reducing
Supply chain
discontent
351
BPMJ
11,4
352
Figure 1.
Different behavioural
styles of supply chain
discontent
a wholesaler’s territory, changing the discount structure, requiring existing trading
partners to perform additional services, and changing the terms of a distribution
agreement without considering the impacts of such changes on the achievement of the
chain goal are examples of chain discontent behaviour.
Chain discontent behaviour can be examined by adopting the dual concern model
(Blake and Mouton, 1964) that explains how the needs of the self and the other interact
in approaches to discontent as shown in Figure 1. The vertical axis measures one
member’s concern for its own interest on a scale from low to high. The horizontal axis
measures its concern for other members’ interests. Each player can be seen as both a
buyer and a seller; a buyer with respect to its suppliers and a seller with respect to its
buyers. A combination of these two axes posits four general styles of supply chain
discontent behaviour: avoidance, forbearance, rivalry, and compromise. Each style
leads to dissatisfaction in the relationship because it prevents each player from
improving the performance of the chain as a whole.
An avoiding style means one player has low concern for the interests both of self
and of the other (cell A in Figure 1). The typical behaviour of the avoiding style
involves changing terms of trade agreements, cannibalism of the current channel by
establishing direct selling to end customers, and speculative purchases. This
behaviour often contributes to additional costs and thereby prevents the chain
members from optimising supply chain operations. For example, Buzzell et al. (1990)
observed two common phenomena of the avoiding style exhibited by retailers during
trade promotions, namely diverting and forward buying. Diverting is a manoeuvre of
retailers to purchase goods from manufacturers at promotional prices in one region and
sell them to another region at normal prices. Forward buying is an effort of a retailer to
accumulate goods at promotional prices and sell at normal prices after the promotional
period. Both actions increase unnecessary stocking costs and provide no promotional
benefit for manufacturers to increase sales (Buzzell et al., 1990).
A forbearing style (cell B in Figure 1) refers to a party with low concern for its own
interest combined with high concern for the other party’s interest. This player may
have a vulnerable position. Some examples of forbearing behaviour in industry include
players often perceiving some costs in contending with their partners’ threats
(Anderson and Narus, 1990) and punishments generally decrease the chain members’
income (Scheer and Stern, 1992).
A rival style (cell C in Figure 1) occurs when one player has high concern for its own
interest coupled with low concern for the other parties’ interests. The rival style often
stresses the use of market power to impose unequal exchanges on other players and
thereby gain surplus from trade deals (Munson et al., 1999). The prevalent
characteristic of the rival style includes the ability of one chain member to shift the risk
of demand uncertainty – either shortage or surplus stocking costs – to other players.
For example, the retailers of the personal computer (PC) industry tend to reduce the
stock level of new products in order to avoid unsold inventories when prices drop
during the product life cycle (Zarley, 1997). This typical action dissatisfies the vendors,
who thereby fail to push more products to end customers. A similar behaviour
occurred when Compaq forced its suppliers to pay the cost of warehousing (McCartney,
1994). Betts (1994) also reported that dominant retailers were suspected of transferring
their ordering costs and inventory risk to their suppliers.
A compromising style (cell D in Figure 1) occurs when one player emphasises on
give-and-take bargaining during the relationship (Stalk et al., 1996). By compromising,
a player bargains to split cost savings because it assumes that the amount of savings is
fixed and needs to be divided amongst all players. The achievement of overall
optimisation is not expected because of sacrificing quality and delivery time. For
instance, the apparel industry experiences high fluctuations in demand due to seasonal
trends (Fisher, 1997). The retailers place orders with their manufacturers long before
the selling season begins in order to take advantage of lowered-buying expenses, but
they have to bear risks of markdowns for unsold stocks after the selling season. On the
other hand, the manufacturers cannot quickly overcome a surge of demand during the
selling season due to long procurement lead times. Mattel, the toy maker, could not
push a lot of merchandise to Toys “R” Us during the 1998 Thanksgiving weekend
(Kravetz, 1999). The retailers stopped ordering new toys from Mattel because of a
shortage of shelf space for all new products and high costs of adding a new product.
This typical decision upset the entire chain as Mattel could not replenish new products
and the retailers could not meet the demand during the peak season due to late
ordering.
The chain members need to encounter the pervasiveness of four behavioural types
of supply chain discontent as it frequently generates unnecessary inefficiencies.
Supply chain discontent not only erodes revenues and increases costs but also
diminishes trust amongst members. Consequently, the detrimental effects of supply
chain discontent on the overall performance should be mitigated by first identifying
underlying factors influencing the behaviour and then finding effective antidotes for
improvements. The next section presents sources of supply chain discontent.
Sources of supply chain discontent
The critical question of how to resolve supply chain discontent should begin with
identifying sources that influence supply chain discontent behaviours, namely
avoidance, forbearing, rivalry, and compromise. Extensive research has appeared to
identify sources of supply chain discontent. However, little attention has been given to
identifying linkages of various sources and their interactions on profitability. For
instance, the rational behaviour of chain members in optimising their own performance
instead of that of the overall supply chain is often viewed as a source of supply chain
discontent (Fisher, 1997; Lee et al., 1997). Fisher (1997) identified the fact that a lack of
coordination in dealing with demand uncertainty contributes to unnecessary costs of
markdowns and lost sales. Lee et al. (1997) discovered that the bullwhip effect as
Supply chain
discontent
353
BPMJ
11,4
354
Figure 2.
Identifying multiple
sources of supply chain
discontent
the primary source of inefficiencies amongst chain members in the supply chain was
an example of supply chain discontent.
This current research goes further to provide an alternative to previous research by
applying the view of organisational economics in identifying multiple sources of
supply chain discontent. This view assumes that interorganisational settings can
influence participating actors, actors are rational and self-interested, and information is
costly to produce and transfer among actors (Jensen and Meckling, 1992). A number of
researchers have highlighted the importance of organisational settings that influence
the behaviour of the participating members in making decisions and taking actions
(Brickley et al., 1995, 2003; Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002; Smith, 2001). This view
can be adopted to explain that poorly designed boundary-spanning interfaces
contribute to the failure of supply chain collaboration. As an independent entity, each
participating member has its own strategic objectives, performance measures, decision
authority, private information, internal costs and revenues structures, and business
processes. When the chain members collaborate with each other, any misfits in these
structural elements can contribute to lost profits (Brickley et al., 1995).
Furthermore, changes in one element without considering its effect on other
elements can result in failure in attaining potential benefits (Milgrom and Roberts,
1990). Based on this conception, Figure 2 provides a model of identifying multiple
sources of supply chain discontent. The multiple sources of discontent include:
incongruent strategic objectives, disintegrated performance measures,
misrepresentation of decision authority, misaligned incentives, information
distortion, and fragmented intercompany business processes. Incongruent objectives
and disintegrated performance measures indicate a lack of shared commitment
amongst the participating members. A lack of coordination incorporates factors that
influence individual players to take decisions that deviate from supply chain
profitability, namely unsynchronised decision-making, information asymmetry, and
inappropriate economic incentives. Fragmented intercompany business processes
indicate a lack of collaborative attention to reducing wastes and inefficiencies from
sourcing to selling activities across organisational boundaries. The remaining section
discusses each source of supply chain discontent.
An incongruent strategic objective is a situation where chain members have
different emphases on strategic options to enhance competitive positions (Bowersox,
1990; Eliashberg and Michie, 1984). This is because each player in the supply chain has
a different position and role in the supply chain that leads to different strategic
priorities. For example, the strategic objective of a supply chain to maximise a profit
margin can be perceived differently by a supplier and a retailer. For the supplier,
maximising a profit margin can be achieved through reducing product lines in order to
lower set-up costs. On the other hand, the retailer translates such an objective as
providing more product lines to customers.
Disintegrated measures of performance mean that the performance measures are
based on individual metrics isolated from the entire goal because each player has been
managed as a single entity (Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002). There are several
reasons for this disintegration. First, the chain members simply do not have
performance measures of the entire supply chain. Second, there is a bias toward
internal measures rather than overall measures. Any action directed at improving
individual metrics, without appreciation of the overall system, is likely to have a
detrimental effect on at least one of the other chain members (Goldratt, 1994). Internal
measures of performance often mislead the individual members because the overall
performance also depends on the performance of other members outside the individual
member’s four walls. Bain’s survey found that only 44 per cent of the sample tracked
performance outside the company’s four walls (Cook and Tyndall, 2001). Third,
performance measures are often based on cost reductions rather than revenue
enhancement for the entire chain. Cost reductions are often translated as cost shifting
to other members rather than cost elimination (Betts, 1994).
Unsynchronised decision-making – known as misrepresentation – refers to
differences in decision-making procedures that lead to counterproductive decisions
(Lee et al., 1997). This is because the chain members have different decision authorities
and different perspectives of responsibilities. In this situation, the player – who is
responsible for making decisions in a particular stage – optimises only its local
objectives without considering the impacts of such actions on other stages.
Consequently, the chain members suffer from task duplications, lack of tacit
knowledge, and delays in decision-making. Total profits are thus less than what could
be achieved through synchronisation (Lee et al., 1997). For instance, in the context of a
seller-buyer relationship, independent order decisions lead to suboptimal solution. The
normative literature recognises unsynchronised decision-making between a retailer
and a supplier as double-marginalisation. The retailer chooses to under stock
inventories lower than the optimal order number, whereas the supplier insists on
supplying above the optimal number.
Information asymmetry occurs when one player has better access to certain
information sources compared to other players (Lee and Whang, 2000). The member
with superior information can take advantage from either hidden information and
hidden action or both (Jensen and Meckling, 1992). The manufacturer, for instance, has
superior knowledge about its own operations including product quality, production
capacity, and delivery lead-time. The retailer, on the other hand, has better knowledge
of product demand and customer preferences in the market, but not of individual
Supply chain
discontent
355
BPMJ
11,4
356
goods. The problem of hidden information occurs if either the manufacturer or the
retailer is reluctant to share relevant information – with the result that neither party
can resolve conflicting decision criteria in inventory, transportation, lead-time,
capacity, product variety, and quality (Simchi-Levi et al., 2000). The problem of hidden
action means that one party cannot observe actions taken by another party. For
instance, a car manufacturer may depend on its dealers if its product sales depend on
the dealer’s level of efforts to serve customers.
Inappropriate economic incentives refer to assigning rewards and punishments
incompatible with optimising the performance of the supply chain as a whole
(Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002). Misaligned incentives induce the individual players
to intentionally make decisions which deviate from the satisfactory solution because
the local solution provides more benefits – even though individual parties know the
optimal solution (Lee et al., 1997). It is often believed that incentive to reduce the costs
of each part of a supply chain can optimise the overall profitability. However, since the
chain members are interdependent, cost reduction for one member might be revenue
reduction for others. Furthermore, any cost reduction has a lower bound (i.e. the
theoretical limit is zero) because the individual member cannot produce outputs
without incurring costs. Such perverse incentive of cost reduction motivates an
individual member to suboptimise its own economic interests instead of striving to
achieve overall profitability (Gjerdrum et al., 2002). For example, a retailer prefers to
maintain a low level of a particular brand on store shelves because there is no incentive
to avoid lost sales for that particular brand (Raman, 1998). A similar misaligned
incentive situation occurs across departments in many retailing companies. A buyer,
for instance, wants to reduce purchasing costs including better quantity discounts with
large order sizes. On the other hand, a warehouse manager has an incentive to
minimise inventory-holding costs including receiving, unloading, and put-away costs.
Similarly, a manufacturer of cell phones – dictated by full truckloads in order to
minimise transportation costs – lost market value as high as 20 per cent (Cook and
Tyndall, 2001).
Fragmented intercompany business processes often contribute to various wastes
along the supply chain that lead to unnecessarily high operating costs and
considerable unnecessary costs of supply-demand mismatch, which lead to poor
profitability. Indicators of undesirable situations include long lead-time, unreliable
delivery, overlapping ordering processes, considerable expediting costs, high
transportation costs, high process variability, markdowns, and high levels of
inventories (Goldratt, 1994; Lee et al., 1997; Simchi-Levi et al., 2000). Kurt Salmon, for
instance, estimated that an apparel retailing industry incurred over $16 billion of
efficiency loss per year due to markdowns, out-of-stock items, and the cost of carrying
excess inventory (Blackburn, 1991). The reason was simply fragmented apparel
pipeline processes, which result in a long time-to-market from the production stage to
the consumer’s buying decision.
Antidotes for supply chain discontent
The common feature of supplier-retailer relationships is a mutual understanding that
the success of each player depends, in part, on other players (Frankel et al., 2002;
Sabath and Fontanella, 2002). The chain members need to understand which are
flawed assumptions that prevent them from making further improvement. One
prevalent example of a flawed assumption that allows supply chain discontent to
persist during a relationship is that the participating members believe that the sum of
local optimisation taken by individual members is equal to the total improvement. The
current practice of the relationship overlooks the facts that a supply chain consists of
interdependent processes that serve the same customers and total profits are not fixed.
It is not surprising that chain members behave either to diminish total profits (e.g.
avoidance and forbearance) or split total profits (e.g. rivalry and compromise). In fact,
the total profits are not fixed and can be enlarged through collaboration (i.e. we all win).
Supply chain collaboration occurs when the participating members work together for
solutions that maximise the gains for all parties. The total improvement thus depends
on how the chain members diminish common constraints that prevent them from
attaining better profitability (Goldratt, 1994).
In this study, antidotes for supply chain discontent are recommended. Each antidote
is designed to mitigate the detrimental effects of a corresponding source of supply
chain discontent. It is derived from the logic of identifying “what to change from” that
represents a typical source of unwanted discontent to finding “what to change to” that
represents effective solutions that lead to desirable effects. Figure 3 shows antidotes
that operate at two different levels: a shared commitment and collaborative business
drivers. At the level of a shared commitment, the chain members need to agree on
developing and communicating mutual strategic objectives and appropriate
performance measures of mutual success. At the level of business drivers, the chain
members should collaboratively design appropriate business drivers of their
collaborative efforts that mostly contribute to supply chain profitability. These
business drivers include information sharing, decision synchronisation, incentive
alignment, and streamlined intercompany business processes.
Having stated the antidotes of discontent, three important characteristics of the
framework warrant further examination. First, each type of antidote serves as a design
variable for intervention that can have profound effects on overall performance
because this chosen antidote affects the behaviour of the chain members in pursuing
overall profitability. Therefore, the redesigning of interface variables or antidotes
should stem from mitigating the core problem that prevents the chain members from
getting more profits.
Supply chain
discontent
357
Figure 3.
Antidotes for supply chain
discontent
BPMJ
11,4
358
Second, Figure 3 provides a framework for designing more effective
boundary-spanning interfaces amongst the chain members. Based on this
framework, the chain members are able to analyse the connections between one
antidote and others and the likely consequences of changes across multiple antidotes to
overall performance. This integrative framework allows them to take advantage from
redesigning combined antidotes that accelerate the increase of total profits. This logic
is consistent with the complementarity theory, which postulates that if two antidotes
are complements then the marginal contribution of one increases as the level of the
other one increases. Milgrom and Roberts (1990) have used it to explain that modern
manufacturing firms adopted coordinated innovative activities rather than the
traditionally separate activities of design, engineering, manufacturing, and marketing.
Additionally, Barua et al. (1996) have developed a theoretical model to explain that the
reengineering project should consider coordinating reengineering activities rather than
isolated activities in order to obtain the complementarity effects of activities.
Third, the framework implies that the four business drivers ultimately affect total
pay-offs. The interactions between antidotes serve as input variables that determine
operational outputs and ultimately contribute to overall performance. Figure 4 shows
the interrelation between intercompany business drivers that affect intermediate
measures, which in turn impact financial outputs (Simatupang et al., 2002). This value
creation path model allows the chain members to identify a set of collaborative
business drivers that impact overall pay-off including intermediate performance
measures of their collaboration. They are also able to coordinate choices of the levels
and improvement directions of the business drivers in a complementary manner. The
model in Figure 4 is akin to business value modelling represented as a two-stage model
developed by Barua et al. (1995) in explaining that the economic benefits of information
technology (IT) investments can be assessed through recognising that choice variables
such as IT and other input investments affect intermediate measures such as capacity
utilisation and inventory turnover, which in turn contribute to financial performance
measures such as return on assets and market share. The remaining section describes
each antidote for mitigating supply chain discontent.
Mutual strategic objectives
Strategic objectives are specific targets of competitive positions that the chain
members can apply in order to create competitive advantage through collaboration
such as accurate response, inventory deployment, customer loyalty, target costs, rapid
Figure 4.
A value creation path
model: from intercompany
business drivers leading to
financial outcomes
product development, and so on (Frankel et al., 2002; Simchi-Levi et al., 2000). The
chain members need to specifically determine their strategic objectives that impart
survival reasons for creating competitive responsiveness to market changes.
Appropriate performance measures
Appropriate measures of performance can be defined as a set of measures used to
evaluate participating members’ performance and overall performance. The measures
should allow the chain members to judge the impact of every action on overall pay-off
(Figure 4). The effectiveness of individual members in contributing to strategic
objectives can be evaluated using intermediate or operational metrics that span across
companies such as customer service, perfect order, new product introduction, speed,
and operating costs (Banker and Snitkin, 2003; Lapide, 2000). Overall collaborative
business outputs are usually measured in terms of net profit, cash flows, return on
investment (ROI), market growth, and market share (Grey et al., 2003; Simatupang and
Sridharan, 2002).
Coordination structure
At the level of coordination, chain members need to harmonise distributed decisions,
information, and incentive amongst themselves in supporting their interdependent
business processes that contribute to mutual objectives. As the chain members need to
share decision authorities, each individual member is responsible for different decision
variables and makes those decisions based on different information. The outcome of
the supply chain depends jointly on the separate decisions taken by the members and
on some environmental uncertainties. As mentioned before, information asymmetry,
when combined with a divergence of interests of the individual decision makers, leads
to inefficiencies of decision-making. Therefore, addressing the problem of coordination
means recognising that there are three kinds of diversity amongst chain members:
(1) a diversity of decision rights;
(2) a diversity of private information; and
(3) a diversity of incentive.
The problem of coordination thus can be summarised as: to choose a coordination
structure which energises the chain members to pursue competitive outcomes,
recognising the constraints imposed by the diversity of decision rights, private
information, and incentives among the chain members.
In this study, a coordination structure is defined as a strategic choice of shared
responsibility of decision right, level of information sharing, and level of incentive
alignment in order to enhance the overall mutual benefits of the collaboration such as
increasing customer value and lowering total supply chain costs. Initiatives that can be
taken to mitigate supply chain discontent include decision synchronisation,
information sharing, and incentive alignment. When combined, the intensity of
decision synchronisation, information sharing, and incentive alignment determines the
spectrum of the coordination structure, as shown in Figure 5. This spectrum level
indicates the degree of collaboration at interface level amongst chain members. The
chain members need to cooperate with each other to determine the appropriate
spectrum level of coordination structure that enables them to effectively realise mutual
Supply chain
discontent
359
BPMJ
11,4
360
Figure 5.
Displaying the spectrum
of a coordination structure
advantage. For ease of description, each component of the coordination structure can
be generally divided into three levels.
Decision synchronisation can be defined as the degree of cooperative
decision-making amongst chain members that jointly determine areas of
responsibilities and allocation of decision rights (Jensen and Meckling, 1992;
Simatupang et al., 2002). The allocation of decision rights (who decides what) should be
accompanied by a set of rules or contracts to ensure that the recipient of decision rights
exercises its rights in a way that results in collective mutual advantages such as better
customer service and lowered costs. The intensity of decision synchronisation ranges
from independent decision-making (i.e. no allocation of decision rights), consultative
decision-making (i.e. joint exercise of decision rights and responsibilities), and
synchronised decision-making (i.e. redesigning decision rights and responsibilities).
The chain members should be able to choose which type of decisions they need to
synchronise in order to ensure direct impacts on chain performance. Decision-making
along the supply chain relates to three general levels: strategic, tactical, and operational
decisions (Simchi-Levi et al., 2000). The strategic level is concerned with decisions that
have strategic importance and involve the long-term game plan for a firm. This type of
decision includes capability building (product design and technologies) and network
configuration. Tactical decisions are concerned with short-term resource allocation
such as collaborative product planning, forecasting, inventory planning, and
distribution planning. These decisions are affected by customer service, inventory,
product pricing, and transportation costs. For example, a retailer gives the stocking
decision right to a supplier like a vendor-managed inventory (VMI) system because the
supplier knows better about its product characteristics, production capacity, and
distribution system (Simchi-Levi et al., 2000). Operational decisions must resolve all the
issues of controlling daily activities on chain operations. Examples of this type of
decision are routing vehicles, developing and modifying a production schedule and
replenishment schedule, and filling customer orders on time.
Information sharing refers to a description of the range of each firm’s private
information (who knows what) and information dissemination among the members
(Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002). The chain members need to determine information
requirements that can be used to make effective decisions. Information sharing enables
the chain members to consider a bigger picture in optimising supply chain operations.
Previous studies demonstrate that information sharing leads to lowered inventory
levels, effective allocation of resources, lowered operating costs, and improved total
profits (Fisher, 1997; Lee et al., 1997). For example, Thonemann (2002) showed that all
participating members benefit from sharing advance demand information in a
supplier-installer supply chain. The supplier mainly benefits from reduced
inventory-holding costs and installers benefit from lowered shortage penalty cost
and better product availability.
Information sharing facilitates data collection, documentation, computation,
transfer, and access to various kinds of private information. It ranges from one-way
communication to data exchange, and exclusive visibility. One-way communication
means the chain members communicates with each other through transactional data
such as purchase orders, order and delivery status, product catalogues, and price
quotation (Lee et al., 1997). Data exchange allows sharing private data in two-way
communication such as points-of-sale data, delivery schedules, inventory levels,
forecasts, capacity planning, and performance status (Lee and Whang, 2000).
Exclusive visibility includes sharing proprietary data such as strategic planning,
market research, product blueprint, and sensitive costs-related data (Fisher, 1997). This
enables chain members to carry out mutual optimisation of business process that
enhances a distinct competitive edge (Konsynski and McFarlan, 1990).
Incentive alignment reflects various inducements (i.e. reward and penalty schemes)
to sharing costs, benefits and risks to be applied by the chain members during the
collaboration (Simatupang and Sridharan, 2002; Simatupang et al., 2002). Since each
member may bear a portion of the total chain costs, the agreement to optimise the chain
performance may not automatically minimise individual member costs. Incentive
alignment thus means to design proper incentives that motivate players in aligning
individual decision-making more closely to the overall goal by sharing costs,
distributing risks, and sharing benefits. If the incentive scheme is not designed
properly, the individual member will be tempted to deviate from the agreement in order
to maximise its short-term gain. How should one take into account the private
economic interest of the individual decision maker? Incentive alignment assumes that
the individual member bases decision-making on the compensation it receives from
others. This compensation depends on the actions of the various decision makers,
either directly (e.g. actions may be audited to see if they are correct, and incorrect
actions may lead to penalty), or indirectly (e.g. profit sharing, bonuses based on sales,
splitting the savings, and so forth).
The intensity of incentive alignment ranges from elementary, to professional and
sophisticated schemes of inducements. An elementary scheme consists mainly of
transfer payments based on current market mechanisms – such as zoning, quota,
rebates, warranties, price discount, quantity discount, and so on – necessary to move
products swiftly to end customers (Buzzell et al., 1990). A professional scheme attempts
Supply chain
discontent
361
BPMJ
11,4
362
to share costs and benefits tied to mutual objectives. Options can be made more
economically attractive by applying inducements – such as accurate forecast, quick
response (e.g. on-time or responsiveness related payment), shared cost-savings, and
gain sharing – based on improved performance (Chopra and Meindl, 2001). A
sophisticated scheme is a change of priorities within the partners’ decision framework
of risk sharing (Billington et al., 2003). It clearly spells out obligations, expectations,
and remedies. The calculation of this scheme often requires complex algorithms.
Sophisticated schemes for risk sharing include flexible quantity contracts, returns
policies, price protection, real options, and dynamic pricing (Billington et al., 2003; Lee,
2002). For example, a manufacturer can offer two options of order delivery to a retailer
in an attempt to share risks associated with demand uncertainty: lower unit price with
long lead-times and higher unit price for production and delivery but with short
lead-times. Both options enable the retailer to improve the right product availability
during a short selling season.
The spectrum of the coordination structure is useful to specify who the players are
and what kind of coordination structure they might operate. For example, tight
collaboration occurs when the chain members operate in a synchronised
decision-making process with exclusive visibility and sophisticated incentives. A
clear picture of the whole coordination spectrum enables the chain members to identify
the sources of supply chain discontent and devise initiatives to remove problems.
Initiatives for decision synchronisation, information sharing, and incentive alignment
should be carefully selected in order to ensure that they have direct impacts on total
profits.
Streamlined intercompany business processes
The chain members need to collaboratively eliminate waste across their supply chain
processes in order to create the flexibility required to respond to constant market
changes. Initiatives of intercompany business process reengineering can be in the
forms of product redesign, process redesign, reducing on-time variability, reducing
demand variability, lead-time reduction, improving forecast accuracies, cross-docking,
and postponement (Blackburn, 1991; Christopher, 1992; Kalakota, 2000; Kopczak and
Johnson, 2003). For example, Dell collaborated with its main suppliers to adopt various
types of postponements and process improvements in order to create a flexible and
lean supply chain with a minimum level of inventory pipeline to a few days (Dell and
Fredman, 1999). As a result, Dell had a significant advantage in cash collection time
and an increase of profit margin.
Discussion
This paper contributes to the literature of SCM by providing a conceptual model for
identifying and mitigating discontent as shown in Figure 6. The model begins with
recognising the pervasiveness of four types of behaviour of supply chain discontent
that lead to scepticism about collaboration. The responsibility of the chain members is
to identify potential sources of discontent that could have a detrimental impact on
overall pay-off. Revealing multiple sources of discontent helps the chain members to
determine where their strategic objectives are not compatible; pinpoint performance
problem areas; build consensus around joint decision-making, information visibility,
and incentive issues; and set priorities for streamlining intercompany business
Supply chain
discontent
363
Figure 6.
The discontent model:
identifying and mitigating
discontent
processes. Eroding revenues and increasing costs must be prevented through applying
the integrative framework of six antidotes for mitigating supply chain discontent. The
chain members need to engage in dialogue and use the value creation path model and
the complementarity theory to devise appropriate directions and levels of
improvements. This dialogue ensures that time and resources are dedicated to
implementing only those initiatives which will truly contribute to overall pay-off (Grey
et al., 2003).
The framework of antidotes (Figures 3-5) provides several managerial implications
on how to apply this concept in supply chain collaboration. First, the chain members
need to determine an interorganisational business value of collaboration. The value
creation path model suggests that all antidotes must be directed to supporting the goal
of supply chain profitability. A top-down analysis can be carried out to firstly specify
overall measures of success such as profitability, market share, and market growth,
secondly identify intermediate measures of performance which contribute to overall
measures, and at the lowest level identify collaborative business drivers (Figure 4).
Second, the chain members should identify and validate complementarity relationships
amongst the business drivers. This means, for instance, assigning decision rights to a
particular member should encourage this member to use its private information to
make better decisions. If the chain members decide to redesign a performance system,
they must ensure that they also redesign appropriate incentive schemes to motivate
individual members to make decisions that support overall performance. A scenario
analysis can be conducted to assess the combined effects of changing the levels of
business drivers on profitability. Finally, the chain members need to devise how to
effectively cause the change. They also need to identify a catalyst for the change such
as choices of technologies that are suitable to the selected design variables of antidotes.
This study provides the first conceptual model that comprehensively incorporates
elements of interorganisational designs used to mitigate detrimental impacts of supply
chain discontent on overall pay-off. Previous approaches have tended to focus on a
single antidote, or on two antidotes such as information sharing and streamlined
business processes (Kalakota, 2000; Lee et al., 1997). Little attention has been given to
explicitly exploiting the complementarity effects of antidotes in the process of attaining
BPMJ
11,4
364
profitability. The first antidote is often called strategy making that specify mutual
strategic objectives of collaboration, whereas the last five antidotes constitute
interorganisational elements designed to fit strategy. Table I compares the five design
elements of collaboration to other common approaches used to mitigate supply chain
discontent. Game theory, for example, provides a systematic way of developing
strategies when one player’s pay-off depends on what other players do (Nalebuff and
Brandenburger, 1996). Although this approach can be used to determine appropriate
policies that maximise overall performance and ensure a Pareto optimal solution for all
chain members (Gjerdrum et al., 2002), there is little guideline for determining what
factors drive the collaborative pay-off. To enhance the analysis of game theory,
Figure 4 provides a more comprehensive approach for the chain members to
understand and identify appropriate interorganisational business drivers that could
affect overall pay-off. Another example is business process reengineering, which is
defined as the fundamental rethinking and radical redesign of business processes to
improve business performance and to stay competitive (Hammer and Champy, 1993).
Reengineering changes often involve a large amount of IT investments and the
reassignment of decision rights. However, the reengineering approach pays little
attention either to guidelines for tracing and measuring the engineering changes on
overall pay-off (Barua et al., 1996) or to redesigning incentive and performance
systems.
Study aimed at promoting an integrative framework of antidotes for mitigating
supply chain discontent has recently emerged. The first stages of this new
research are necessarily description and classification (Kerlinger, 1973).
Simatupang and Sridharan (2004) provide empirical evidence of applying this
approach to a study of benchmarking in supply chain collaboration. Nevertheless,
several issues of further extensions, mathematical modelling, and empirical
evidence of the framework proposed in this paper warrant further research. While
this study focuses on dyadic collaboration, future research can be extended to
include more than two participating members (Blackburn, 1991). Another extension
of this research is to develop a portfolio of collaboration because not every
business relationship in the supply chain is collaborative but varies in its
intensity. Future research is also required to develop mathematical foundations to
ensure the complementarity conditions (Topkis, 1995) of intercompany business
drivers and the strong supermodularity conditions (Barua et al., 1996) of the value
creation path model. Finally, the integrative framework of antidotes proposed in
this paper uses a normative approach, which allows researchers to scrutinise how
the chain members ought to manage collaboration given particular objectives.
However, this approach must be balanced with the findings from descriptive
research, which focuses on what managers actually do in the collaborative efforts.
The remaining section provides directions for descriptive research.
Changing the mind-set from the competitive supply chain (i.e. avoidance,
forbearance, rivalry, and compromise) to the collaborative supply chain (i.e. a
win-win relationship) is a vital prerequisite to understanding the mutual benefits of
improvement initiatives. Identifying sources of supply chain discontent provides a
starting point to recognising deficiencies in the current practice of the relationship. The
main trigger that drives the chain members to redesign their interorganisational
structures is deficiency – indicated by the fact that realised outcome is much lower
Selected approaches
(influencers)
Description
Quick response
(Blackburn, 1991;
Kurt Salmon
Associates)
A consumer-driven
strategy that
promotes pulling
things through the
pipeline and letting
the consumers decide
what they want
Business process
reengineering
(Hammer and
Champy, 1993)
The fundamental
rethinking and
radical redesign of
business process to
achieve overall
pay-off
The choice of optimal
strategy that
combines
competition and
collaboration
Game theory
(Nalebuff and
Brandenburger,
1996; Gjerdrum
et al., 2002)
Accurate response
(Fisher, 1997; Fisher
et al., 2000; Raman,
1998)
Appropriate
performance system
A successful
collaboration means
higher inventory
turns and improved
ROI for each member.
Little guidance is
given to develop
cross-boundary
performance
measures except time
related measures
Little attention is
given to redesigning
intercompany
performance
measures
The pay-off is the
outcome of each
strategy. Little
attention is given to
restructuring
cross-boundary
measures
Fitting the nature of The focus is on
measures such as
the demand of
contribution margin,
products to the
forecast error,
appropriate supply
chain design strategy stockout rate,
markdowns, and
because of
lead-time. Little
differences in
production costs and attention is given to
the costs of a supply- restructuring cross
-boundary measures
demand mismatch
The five elements of collaboration proposed in this paper
Decision
Information sharing synchronisation
Incentive alignment
Streamlined business
processes
Each link in the chain
shares data about
sales, orders, and
inventories with
others via electronic
data interchange
(EDI)
Quick response
involves
reassignment of
decision rights and
joint decision-making
in planning and
execution
Little attention is
given to
restructuring
rewards, costs, and
risks
Quick response
involves process
improvements such
as modular
manufacturing,
lead-time reduction,
and smaller and more
frequent orders
Reengineering
involves high
investments in IT
Reengineering
involves
reassignment of
decision rights
Little attention is
given to
restructuring
rewards and
punishments
Reengineering
involves radical
redesign of business
processes
The focus is on fair
sharing of risks,
costs, and profits
No guideline is given
about improving
business processes
Guidance is given
about rewarding
responsiveness and
sharing markdown
costs
Physical efficient
process involves
minimising
inventory and
shortens lead-time.
Market-responsive
process aggressively
reduces lead-time
and uses modular
design
Each player makes
This approach
assumes visibility on strategic decisions to
gain advantage over
costs and revenues
a rival. Little
attention is given to
reassignment of
decision rights
Accurate response
Accurate response
involves data sharing involves
reassignment of
about advance
demand information, decision rights and
joint decision-making
sales, inventory
levels, capacity, and in planning and
control
lead-time
Supply chain
discontent
365
Table I.
Comparisons with
selected approaches for
mitigating supply chain
discontent
BPMJ
11,4
366
than might be expected. Future research is needed to elaborate upon methods for
measuring deficiency and its linkage to sources of supply chain discontent. This
includes how and why supply chain discontent exists amongst participating members.
Since boundaries of the context and the phenomenon of supply chain collaboration are
not obvious and investigators have little control over events, case study research is
recommended as an appropriate method to better understand collaborative efforts
(Yin, 2003).
The people factor plays a key role in the success of supply chain initiatives.
However, little research has been dedicated to pinpointing the mental models of people
who actually carry out the improvement process (Akkermans et al., 1999; Covington,
1996). Further research is required to capture mental models of participating managers
about interorganisational redesigns as an integrative way of improving overall
performance. Cognitive mapping, for instance, can be used to elicit and describe mental
models (Akkermans et al., 1999).
Conclusion
The difficulty of creating collective advantage from adopting supply chain
collaboration as a strategic initiative is strongly related to supply chain discontent.
Supply chain discontent occurs when the chain members cannot realise their potential
due to differences in interest, and thereby the realised outcome is much lower than
expected. This research has identified four styles of discontent behaviour: avoidance,
forbearance, rivalry, and compromise. Where supply chain discontent is prevalent, the
individual member cares only about its private agenda instead of about enlarging total
profits. As a result, inefficiency loss such as excessive inventories, stockouts,
markdowns, and resource misallocations are prevailing undesirable symptoms in
many supply chains.
The research reported herein has revealed sources of supply chain discontent that
include incongruent strategic objectives, disintegrated performance measures,
unsynchronised decision-making, information asymmetry, misaligned incentives,
and fragmented intercompany business processes. Each source of chain discontent
provides an opportunity for identifying a remedy or antidote. This study has also
proposed the integrative framework of antidotes for mitigating supply chain
discontent. Antidotes for supply chain discontent incorporate initiatives to resolve
shared commitment and collaborative business drivers. Gaining shared commitment
involves setting mutual strategic objectives and defining appropriate measures of
performance. Collaborative business drivers incorporate decision synchronisation,
information sharing, incentive alignment, and streamlined intercompany business
processes. Furthermore, the value creation path model provides directions for
improvements, whereas the complementarity theory serves as a basis for choosing the
right levels of improvements among intercompany business drivers, which contribute
maximally to the overall pay-off of collaboration.
In this paper, a new alternative for interorganisational redesigns is proposed, which
is based on the organisational economics view and the complementarity theory and
thereby contributes to a novel understanding of supply chain collaboration. This new
alternative explicitly conceptualises the complementarity effects of antidotes on
intermediate performance measures, which in turn determine overall financial
outcomes. Only when the chain members discuss and design coordinated antidotes can
the real pay-off of collaboration be traced and measured. Finally, in this paper is
provided a set of agendas for further research including developing mathematical
foundations for ensuring complementarity conditions, the case study for identifying
multiple sources of discontent, and the use of the integrative framework of antidotes to
capture the cognitive models of participants.
Supply chain
discontent
367
References
Akkermans, H., Bogerd, P. and Vos, B. (1999), “Virtuous and vicious cycles on the road towards
international supply chain management”, International Journal of Operations &
Production Management, Vol. 19 Nos 5/6, pp. 565-81.
Anderson, J.C. and Narus, J.A. (1990), “A model of distributor firm and manufacturer firm
working partnerships”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 54 No. 1, pp. 42-58.
Banker, S. and Snitkin, S. (2003), “Continuous improvement: a foundation for operational
excellence”, Supply Chain Management Review, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 42-8.
Barua, A., Kriebel, C.H. and Mukhopadhyay, T. (1995), “Information technologies and business
value: an analytic and empirical investigation”, Information Systems Research, Vol. 6 No. 1,
pp. 3-23.
Barua, A., Lee, C.S. and Whinston, A. (1996), “The calculus of reengineering”, Information
Systems Research, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 409-28.
Betts, M. (1994), “Manage my inventory or else!”, Computerworld, Vol. 28 No. 5, pp. 93-5.
Billington, C., Johnson, B. and Triantis, A. (2003), “A real options perspective on supply chain
management in high technology”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 15 No. 2,
pp. 32-43.
Blackburn, J.D. (1991), “The quick-response movement in the apparel industry: a case study in
time-compressing supply chains”, in Blackburn, J.D. (Ed.), Time-Based Competition,
Business One Irwin, New York, NY, pp. 246-69.
Blake, R. and Mouton, J. (1964), The Managerial Grid, Gulf, Houston.
Bowersox, D.J. (1990), “The strategic benefits of logistics alliances”, Harvard Business Review,
Vol. 68 No. 4, pp. 36-43.
Brickley, J., Smith, C. and Zimmerman, J. (1995), “The economics of organizational architecture”,
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 8 No. 2, pp. 19-31.
Brickley, J., Smith, C. and Zimmerman, J. (2003), “Corporate governance, ethics, and
organizational architecture”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 15 No. 3, pp. 34-45.
Buzzell, R.D., Quelch, J.A. and Salmon, W.J. (1990), “The costly bargain of trade promotion”,
Harvard Business Review, Vol. 68 No. 2, pp. 141-9.
Chopra, S. and Meindl, P. (2001), Supply Chain Management, Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River,
NJ.
Christopher, M.G. (1992), Logistics and Supply Chain Management, Pitman Publishing, London.
Cook, M. and Tyndall, R. (2001), “Lessons from the leaders”, Supply Chain Management Review,
Vol. 5 No. 6, pp. 22-32.
Covington, J.W. (1996), Tough Fabric: The Domestic Apparel and Textile Chain Regain Market
Share, Chesapeake Consulting, Severna Park, MD.
Dell, M. and Fredman, C. (1999), Direct From Dell: Strategies That Revolutionized an Industry,
Harper Collins, London.
BPMJ
11,4
368
Eliashberg, J. and Michie, D.A. (1984), “Multiple business goals sets as determinants of
marketing channel conflict: an empirical study”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 21
No. 1, pp. 75-88.
Fisher, M.L. (1997), “What is the right supply chain for your product?”, Harvard Business Review,
Vol. 75 No. 2, pp. 105-16.
Fisher, M.L., Raman, A. and McClelland, A.S. (2000), “Rocket science retailing is almost here: are
you ready?”, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 78 No. 4, pp. 115-24.
Frankel, R., Goldsby, T.J. and Whipple, J.M. (2002), “Grocery industry collaboration in the wake
of ECR”, International Journal of Logistics Management, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 57-72.
Gjerdrum, J., Shah, N. and Papageorgiou, L.G. (2002), “Fair transfer price and inventory holding
policies in two-enterprise supply chains”, European Journal of Operational Research,
Vol. 143 No. 3, pp. 582-99.
Goldratt, E.M. (1994), It’s Not Luck, North River Press, Great Barrington, MA.
Grey, W., Katircioglu, K., Shi, D., Bagchi, S., Gallego, G., Adelhelm, M., Seybold, D. and Stefanis,
S. (2003), “Beyond ROI”, Supply Chain Management Review, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 20-7.
Hammer, M. and Champy, J. (1993), Reengineering the Corporation: A Manifesto for Business
Revolution, Harper Business, New York, NY.
Jap, S.D. (2001), “Pie sharing in complex collaboration context”, Journal of Marketing Research,
Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 86-99.
Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1992), “Specific and general knowledge and organizational
structure”, in Werin, L. and Wijkander, H. (Eds), Contract Economics, Basil Blackwell,
Oxford, pp. 251-74.
Kalakota, R. (2000), “Inter-enterprise fusion: the future of supply chains”, eAI Journal, May
pp. 72-6.
Kerlinger, F.N. (1973), Foundations of Behavioural Research, 2nd ed., Holt, Rinehart and Winston,
New York, NY.
Konsynski, B.R. and McFarlan, E.W. (1990), “Information partnerships: shared data, shared
scale”, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 68 No. 5, pp. 114-20.
Kopczak, L.R. and Johnson, M.E. (2003), “The supply-chain management effect”, Sloan
Management Review, Vol. 44 No. 3, pp. 27-34.
Kravetz, S. (1999), “Mattel revamps retail plan to reduce its independence on traditional outlets”,
Wall Street Journal, Vol. 233 No. 32, p. B8.
Lapide, L. (2000), “True measures of supply chain performance”, Supply Chain Management
Review, Vol. 4 No. 3, pp. 25-8.
Lee, H.L. (2002), “Aligning supply chain strategies with product uncertainties”, California
Management Review, Vol. 44 No. 3, pp. 105-19.
Lee, H.L. and Billington, C. (1992), “Managing supply chain inventory: pitfalls and
opportunities”, Sloan Management Review, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 65-73.
Lee, H.L., Padmanabhan, V. and Whang, S. (1997), “The bullwhip effect in supply chains”, Sloan
Management Review, Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 93-102.
Lee, H.L. and Whang, S. (2000), “Information sharing in a supply chain”, International Journal of
Technology Management, Vol. 20 Nos 3/4, pp. 373-87.
McCartney, S. (1994), “Compaq borrows Wal-Mart’s idea to boost production”, Wall Street
Journal, 17 June, pp. B4.
Mentzer, J.T., Foggin, J.H. and Golicic, S.L. (2000), “Collaboration: the enablers, impediments, and
benefits”, Supply Chain Management Review, Vol. 4 No. 5, pp. 52-8.
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990), “The economics of modern manufacturing: technology,
strategy, and organization”, American Economic Review, Vol. 80 No. 3, pp. 511-28.
Moberg, C.R., Speh, T.W. and Freese, T.L. (2003), “SCM: making the vision a reality”, Supply
Chain Management Review, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp. 34-9.
Munson, C.L., Rosenblatt, M.J. and Rosenblatt, Z. (1999), “The use and abuse of power in supply
chains”, Business Horizons, Vol. 42 No. 1, pp. 55-65.
Nalebuff, B.J. and Brandenburger, A.M. (1996), Co-opetition, Harper Collins, London.
Raman, A. (1998), “Towards finding the perfect match: matching supply with demand in supply
chains”, in Gattorna, J. (Ed.), Strategic Supply Chain Alignment: Best Practice in Supply
Chain Management, Gower Publishing, Aldershot, pp. 171-87.
Sabath, R.E. and Fontanella, J. (2002), “The unfulfilled promise of supply chain collaboration”,
Supply Chain Management Review, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 24-9.
Scheer, L.K. and Stern, L.W. (1992), “The effect of influence type and performance outcomes on
attitude toward the influencer”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 29 No. 2, pp. 128-42.
Simatupang, T.M. and Sridharan, R. (2002), “The collaborative supply chain”, International
Journal of Logistics Management, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 15-30.
Simatupang, T.M. and Sridharan, R. (2004), “Benchmarking supply chain collaboration: an
empirical study”, Benchmarking: An International Journal, Vol. 11 No. 5, pp. 484-508.
Simatupang, T.M., Wright, A.C. and Sridharan, R. (2002), “The knowledge of coordination for
supply chain integration”, Business Process Management Journal, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 289-308.
Simchi-Levi, D., Kaminsky, P. and Simchi-Levi, E. (2000), Designing and Managing the Supply
Chain, McGraw-Hill, Boston, MA.
Smith, C.W. (2001), “Organizational architecture and corporate finance”, The Journal of Financial
Research, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 1-13.
Spekman, R.E., Kamauff, J.W. and Myhr, N. (1998), “An empirical investigation into supply chain
management: a perspective on partnership”, Supply Chain Management: An International
Journal, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp. 53-67.
Stablein, R. (1999), “Data in organization studies”, in Clegg, S.R. and Hardy, C. (Eds), Studying
Organization: Theory & Method, Sage, London, pp. 255-71.
Stalk, G.H., Pecaut, D.K. and Burnett, B. (1996), “Breaking compromises, breaking growth”,
Harvard Business Review, Vol. 74 No. 5, pp. 131-9.
Thonemann, U.W. (2002), “Improving supply-chain performance by sharing advance demand
information”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 142 No. 1, pp. 81-107.
Topkis, D.M. (1995), “Comparative statics of the firm”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 67 No. 2,
pp. 370-401.
Yin, R.K. (2003), Case Study Research, 3rd ed., Sage, Newbury Park, CA.
Zarley, C. (1997), “Price protection is not a game”, Computer Reseller News, No. 754, p. 14.
Supply chain
discontent
369