DEMOCRATIC DEVELOPMENT IN CHINA’S URBAN COMMUNITIES
A dissertation presented
by
Chow Bing NGEOW
to
The Department of Political Science
In partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy
In the field of
Public and International Affairs
Northeastern University
Boston, Massachusetts
January, 2010
1
Democratic Development in China’s Urban Communities
by
Chow Bing NGEOW
ABSTRACT OF DISSERTATION
Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of
Philosophy in Political Science in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of
Northeastern University, January 2010
2
ABSTRACT
Since mid-1990s, the Chinese government has been promoting a policy of community
construction (shequ) in urban areas. One of the main focuses of this policy is to build up
the democratic infrastructure and institutions at the grassroots level in the cities. As a
result, political and institutional reforms to make grassroots governance more democratic
have been experimented and implemented in many cities. Members of the residents’
committee, the “mass-organization” entrusted to governance the communities (shequ),
are now to be democratically elected. The administration of the communities has to
adhere to the principles of democratic decision-making, democratic management, and
democratic supervision. The grassroots organs of the ruling Chinese Communist Party
have to adapt to the democratic institutions, while non-governmental organizations,
especially in the form of the homeowners’ committee, also emerges as another channel
for urban residents to participate in public affairs. The major aim of this study is to
document and analyze these institutional designs and reforms. It also provides an
interpretive perspective for these grassroots democratic reforms, arguing that these
reforms embody a Chinese model of democratic development.
3
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This dissertation would not have been possible without the guidance and support
of many people, especially my mentor, advisor, dissertation committee chair, and friend,
Professor Suzanne Ogden. She has always assured me my ability to undertake this
challenging intellectual journey even if I had had doubts about myself. I was in her class
on Chinese politics the very first semester as a graduate student at Northeastern
University. Since then, she has been a constant source of inspiration. During my writing
process, she patiently and carefully read every chapter and took the extraordinary steps to
correct many mistakes and errors. She also provided many challenging questions that
forced me to rewrite many parts of the dissertation. Without her constructive criticism,
this dissertation would be a much poorer work.
Prof. Denise Horn at the International Affairs program at Northeastern University
and Prof. Shiping Hua at the University of Louisville, both of them served as my
dissertation committee members, also deserve my upmost gratitude. I also want to thank
the staff at the Political Science Department for their help. Prof. Portz, the chair of the
department, has been supportive of my research and given me many opportunities to
continue teaching for the department so that I don’t have to worry about my income when
writing the dissertation. The department also provided a grant for my research trip. I wish
to express my sincerest appreciation for all the help provided by Northeastern
University’s Political Science Department.
I want to thank Dr Liu Ye and Dr. Peng Bo for facilitating my research trip to
Shanghai in Fall 2007. In fact, it was my conversation with them in a conference in 2005
that inspired my interest in the democratic reforms in China’s urban communities. As a
4
special research student at Fudan University in Shanghai, I wish to thank the help of Prof.
Liu Chunrong, Prof. Lin Shangli, and Prof. Zheng Changzhong.
Finally, none of this would have been possible without the support of my friends
and family. My friend Ban-Hong Wong remains my closest friend for all these years
studying in Boston. I want to thank my wife Hwee-Thing, for her patience, sacrifice, and
love throughout the process. In the process she also gave me a daughter, Li-Yue. I was
really afraid when she was born that I could not handle the simultaneous tasks of writing
a dissertation and taking care of a full family. But Li-Yue actually gave me the
determination to finish the project. Finally, I wish to thank my parents. Their love and
support have made it possible for me to continue on this intellectual journey.
5
Table of Contents
Abstract------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------2
Acknowledgements ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------4
Table of Contents-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------6
List of Tables -----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------7
List of Figures ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------8
Chapter 1 Introduction: Democratic Development in China’s Urban Communities -------9
Chapter 2 The Concept and Meaning of Shequ in China’s Political System---------------23
Chapter 3 The Background of Shequ’s Democratization--------------------------------------73
Chapter 4 Institutionalizing and Reforming Elections in Shequ------------------------------91
Chapter 5 Toward Democratic Public Administration and Governance in Shequ:
Institutional Innovations--------------------------------------------------------------------------169
Chapter 6 Accommodating the Party or Accommodating Democracy: Shequ Party
Building and Shequ Democratic Development------------------------------------------------209
Chapter 7 Homeowners’ Committees: The Emergence of Shequ-Based Civil Society--242
Chapter 8 Conclusion and Discussion----------------------------------------------------------282
Appendices ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------304
Works Cited ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------330
6
List of Tables
Table 4.1: Average Election Expenses per Shequ
Table 4.2: Nomination Methods
Table 4.3: “Degree” and “Range” of Differential Elections
Table 6.1: Responsibilities of Street and Shequ Party Organizations
Table 6.2: Percentages of Jiaocha renzhi and Yijiantiao
Table 7.1: Homeowners’ Committees in 12 Chinese Cities
7
List of Figures
Figure 2.1: Administrative Structure in China
Figure 2.2: Organizational Structure of the Residents’ Committee
Figure 4.1: Legal Framework of Residents’ Committee Elections
Figure 4.2: Different Types of Differential Elections
Figure 5.1: Two Models of Yixing fenshe
8
Chapter 1 Introduction: Democratic Development in China’s Urban
Shequ/Communities
The “reform and opening up” policy of China, launched after the ascendancy of
the then paramount leader Deng Xiaoping in 1979, has brought tremendous material
improvements to China and has made China a rising power in East Asia and the world.
The reform policy, successful as it is, is mostly understood in economic terms. With the
ruling Chinese Communist Party still restricting multi-party competition, full judicial
independence, free flow of information and media liberalization, and freedoms of speech
and association, there is a strong perception that no significant political reforms have
taken place.
Nevertheless, this is a simplistic perception. It is true that reforms have not made
China a liberal democratic polity, not even an electoral authoritarian regime. But politics
in the reform era is very different from the politics in the pre-reform era. Succession of
leadership has been institutionalized. The legislative institution is becoming more
assertive and independent. Government actions are less arbitrary and more predictable.
Rule of law and the building of legal institutions have been expanded and are recognized
as foundational to the “socialist political civilization.” A modern, technocratic civil
service system has taken the place of the old revolutionary cadres system. Proliferation of
interest associations has reduced the omnipresent power of the state. On an individual
level, Chinese citizens now enjoy more freedoms and rights than before.
Among the political changes that have occurred in the reform era, elections
naturally attract the most attentions. Since elections are generally seen as synonymous
with “democracy” as narrowly defined, many China watchers have tried to gauge the
9
“true” extent of political reforms by looking at Chinese elections. Grassroots elections of
villagers’ committees in the rural areas, introduced in the late 1980s and early 1990s, thus
is one of the most popular subjects for political scientists studying China.1
China, however, is rapidly urbanizing. A 2009 report released by the Chinese
Academy of Social Sciences shows that Chinese urbanization rate is estimated at 45.7%,
which means that China now has more than 600 million urban residents, almost half of
the population. There are 118 cities with a population size of more than a million.2
Focusing on political reforms in rural villages is no longer adequate for assessing China’s
overall political reforms. Political reforms undertaken in cities, the political-economiccultural centers in China, could have implications as well. This dissertation, therefore, is
a study of political reforms/democratic development in Chinese cities, with a special
focus on its grassroots shequ (communities).
In this introductory chapter I will first discuss the use of the term “democracy,”
and then proceed to briefly discuss the literature on Chinese shequ. I will follow this with
a discussion of my methodological approach, and to introduce the chapters of this
dissertation
1.1 Democratic Development in Chinese Shequ (Communities)
Since the late 1990s, the Chinese central government has launched and supported
a policy of shequ jianshe (community construction). Elements of political reforms could
1
For instance, see Larry Diamond and Ramon H. Myers, eds., Elections and Democracy in Greater China,
New York, NY: Oxford University Press (2001); Qingshan Tan, Village Elections in China: Democratizing
the Countryside, New York, NY: Edwin Mellen Press (2006); Baogang He, Rural Democracy in China:
The Role of Village Elections, New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan (2007).
2
“Zhongguo chengzhen renkou tupo liuyi (Chinese Urban Population more than 600 million)” BBC
Chinese June 15, 2009, available at
http://news.bbc.co.uk/chinese/simp/hi/newsid_8100000/newsid_8101900/8101933.stm , accessed June 15,
2009.
10
be found in this policy, such as the emphasis on democratic elections and democratic
self-governance of the residents’ committee. Shequ jianshe has been hailed in official
discourse and by optimistic academics in China as a strategy of developing civil society
and grassroots democracy, rationalizing urban governance, and promoting political
reforms. According to these assessments, shequ is becoming an important part in the
reform and modernization of China’s political and administrative system. The
development of shequs in China’s cities has also received increasing attention by scholars
and government policymakers. The shequ jianshe policy, although not always the highest
priority in the nation’s agenda, nevertheless remains in the government’s vision in the
reform of urban governance in China.
This study mainly focuses on the democratic development aspect of shequ
jianshe, investigating and analyzing what kind of democratic institutions that are being
experimented and implemented in urban grassroots communities. This study will
principally focus on three important shequ organizations: the residents’ committee, the
shequ party organization, and the homeowners’ committee.
For some readers, my use of the terms “democracy” or “democratic” in this study
could be the main objection. The many institutions that I will discuss in this study
certainly do not resemble the democratic institutions of a liberal democratic system.
“Democracy” of course is a term that could be, and has been, abused to justify or mask
certain truly undemocratic institutions and polities. Some political scientists have
undertaken efforts to do some “conceptual housecleaning” work, to get rid of the
11
modifying adjectives such as “sovereign” and “popular” that distort the meaning of
democracy, and to come up with a more or less universal understanding of the term.3
I do not disagree with the importance of making democracy a more conceptually
precise term. Having a more or less universal understanding of the term is also the
foundation of comparative analysis. However, in this study, I wish to take a broader
approach, for two purposes. First, strictly following a universal definition could limit our
understanding of some of the political institutional reforms in China that could make the
political system more accountable, and indeed, more “democratic.” It could also limit out
understanding of the efforts of reformist officials and scholars to increase the democratic
aspects of existing institutions. If we take a narrow perspective on the meaning of
democracy, we might have simply dismissed such institutional innovations and political
reforms as insubstantial.
Second, using a strict definition could easily lead us to dismiss the official actions
to promote democracy, and the official model of democracy in China, as nothing more
than propaganda. This will restrict our understanding of the official model, how the
model functions, what are the institutions that sustain this model, and whether this model
is compatible with the strict definition. The official model may not be genuinely
democratic after all, but we should not rule it out by definition, without first looking and
investigating the “democratic” potential of its institutions.
The use of “democracy” here, therefore, is more broadly conceptualized. In
November of 2009, I attended an international conference on “Chinese-style democracy”
3
Philippe C. Schmitter & Terry Lynn Karl, “What Democracy Is…and Is Not,” in Annual Editions:
Comparative Politics 09/10, edited by O. Fiona Yap, New York, NY: McGraw-Hill (2010), pg. 4-10. The
article is originally published in the Summer 1991 issue of the Journal of Democracy.
12
held in Wuhan, China. In the conference, many thoughtful Chinese participants proposed,
analyzed, and discussed some of the alternative models of “democracy” that are sensitive
to the historical and political realities of present-day China. In this dissertation, I take
seriously, though not necessarily agree with, the official model of “socialist democracy
with Chinese characteristics,” which champions a conception of democracy that includes
and goes beyond electoral institutions. The official discourse of “four democracies”
emphasizes election, democratic decision-making, management, and supervision. In this
discourse, democratic public administration is as important as the question of whether the
decision makers are appointed or elected. Leadership of the party is unquestionable, but
the party itself is also subject to the rule of law, and could be subject to popular
supervision and accountability. This conception of democracy also tolerates, and even
encourages, a cooperative and active civil society.
Some of the questions for this study will then be: What democratic institutions are
being established in the shequ? Can these institutions improve governance and
participation? How does the party solve the conflicts arising from the principles of
democracy and of party’s leadership? What institutions foster civil society development
at the urban grassroots level? How will this development affect the power dynamics
within a shequ?
1.2 Literature Review and Methodological Approach
In contrast to the blossoming studies on village political reforms, political reforms
in shequs receive relatively fewer scholarly attentions in Western academia. One reason
is timing: village democratization preceded shequ jianshe by at least ten years. It might
still be too early to come to a definite scholarly and theoretical assessment of the
13
relatively new (and unevenly spread) urban grassroots political reforms. Many studies on
shequs in by Western scholars are descriptive. They introduce the background, structure,
transition, and organization of shequ institutions, mainly the residents’ committee. The
articles by Read and by Derleth and Koldyk are representative of this kind of studies.
Read is one of the first scholars to pay attention to the Chinese government’s policy to, in
his own word, “revitalize the state’s urban ‘nerve tips’.” Read discusses extensively the
historical evolution and functions of the main shequ organization –the residents’
committee, and explores the changing relationship between residents and residents’
committees in the reform era. Many of his observations, such as the generally closer
relationship between retirees in the neighborhood and residents’ committees, the
importance of informal, personal networks and face-to-face interaction in the work of
residents’ committees, and the spontaneous and bottom-up fashion of the homeowners’
movement, are still valid today.4 Derleth and Koldyk discuss the historical background of
shequ jianshe and some of the reforms that have taken place in the last decade, which
served to strengthen and expand the functions of shequ. Nevertheless, they caution
against over-reading the impact of shequ jianshe on the overall political system.5
In recent years, more analytical studies have emerged. Most of these studies are
based on case studies of a number of shequs in a city. Based on his field research in
Shenyang, Bray interestingly concludes that shequ self-governance is in essence a
continuation of the previous strategy of danwei (work unit)-based governance. Shequ
jianshe appears to be a strategy to beef up the institution of the residents’ committee so
4
Benjamin L. Read, “Revitalizing the State’s Urban ‘Nerve Tips’,” The China Quarterly 163 (2000), pg.
806-820.
5
James Derleth and Daniel R. Koldyk, “The Shequ Experiment: Grassroots Political Reform in Urban
China,” Journal of Contemporary China, 13:41 (2004), pg. 747-777.
14
that it could fulfill the role played by the work units before. Moreover, Bray highlights
the implied ethnical training and moral self-regulation in the shequ jianshe policy, from
which he contends that it is useful to think of shequ jianshe (and shequ self-governance)
as “governing the [collective] self” in the Foucaultian sense.6
Wong and Poon trace the changing emphasis of China’s community policy, which
evolved from an emphasis on welfare provision to the more recent program of
community building. Based on their research in Guangzhou, they conclude that the
combination of “welfare and control” functions of the shequ jianshe policy “raises the
political profile of [the residents’ committee] as an institutional devise to re-impose
control on a more mobile and heterogeneous [urban] society.”7 An examination of this
policy by Yan and Gao basically come to the same conclusion. The authors characterize
the shequ jianshe policy as a “massive social engineering project.” The communities
constructed under the shequ jianshe policy are not synonymous with notions of civil
society or civic communities in Western societies. They are rather to be understood as
reconstructed administrative units. Residents’ participation in shequ self-governance is
heavily regulated by the party-state. Residents’ committees, the authors conclude, remain
tools of political control despite their new found mission as welfare providers.8
Some other studies compare the political reforms of villagers’ institutions and of
shequ institutions. Such comparison leads Benewick and his colleagues to conclude that
shequ jianshe strengthens and consolidates the rule of the party rather than democracy.
6
David Bray, “Building ‘Community’: New Strategies of Governance in Urban China,” Economy and
Society, 35:4 (2006), pg. 530-549.
7
Linda Wong and Bernard Poon, “From Serving Neighbors to Recontrolling Urban Society: The
Transformation of China’s Community Policy,” China Information 19:3 (2005), pg. 413-442.
8
Miu Chung Yan & Jian Guo Gao, “Social Engineering of Community Building: Examination of Policy
Process and Characteristics of Community Construction in China,” Community Development Journal 42:2
(2007), pg. 222-236.
15
Despite substantial political reforms of these institutions, both villagers’ committees and
residents’ committee, the authors contend, should be viewed as “surrogates of statecorporatist structures” that “represent adaptations of a Party-state determined to keep its
dominance.” They should not be considered equivalent “to self-determination, popular
sovereignty or democracy.”9
While most Chinese scholars are optimistic about the democratic potentials of
shequ jianshe and residents’ committees, studies on shequs in the West tend to be more
skeptical. My study is also concerned about the democratic implications of shequ jianshe.
It is different from the existing literature on two grounds. First, this study is not based on
in-depth case studies. I base my studies on many empirical examples across China.
Second, this study especially focuses on the institutional aspects. The shequ jianshe
policy is not a coherent policy. In the varying local designs of shequ jianshe, there are
both institutional innovations and reforms that could have democratic consequences and
institutional flaws and inadequacies that become obstacles to shequ democratic
development. The primary focus of this study is to investigate the institutions.
The theoretical and methodological assumption of this study is naturally
institutionalism. Institutionalism in political science, of course, has many schools (such as
rational choice institutionalism, historical institutionalism, old institutionalism, new
institutionalism, etc.). This study, however, is not primarily concerned about theoretical
abstraction and sophistication. Suffice to state here that this study agrees with the
statement “Political democracy depends not only on economic and social conditions but
9
Robert Benewick, Irene Tong, Jude Howell, “Self-Governance and Community: A Preliminary
Comparison between Villagers’ Committees and Urban Community Councils,” China Information 18:1
(2004), pg. 11-28.
16
also on the design of political institutions.”10 I also use a broad definition of institutions,
including both formal, written structure of rules and informal patterns and practices.
Most of the materials of study come from a research trip to Shanghai in the
autumn of 2007. I was a visiting research student at Shanghai’s Fudan University.
Initially I planned to conduct a large number of interviews and to observe grassroots
elections in Shanghai. However, I was restricted by the policy in which a foreign
researcher has to have an official permission to carry out interviews. I was grateful to get
permission from my host institution to carry out interviews in two shequ. Nevertheless
this would not be enough materials for this study. I also missed the opportunity to directly
observe urban grassroots elections, since the election cycle had just ended the year
before. I decided to pursue another research strategy. I spent a lot of time in Fudan’s
library collecting documents, journal articles, press reports, magazine reports, books, and
other publications on Chinese shequs. I continued to collect these materials after I left
Fudan, utilizing the skills in getting hold of Chinese print materials that I learned in
working in Fudan’s library.
Among the print materials, I heavily rely on the articles in the magazine Shequ
(Community). Published by the Ministry of Civil Affairs since 2002, this magazine is the
primary authoritative source for materials such as central directives on the shequ jianshe
policy, local documents, latest developments of shequ jianshe in various localities, shequ
issues and problems, innovative local institutional designs, achievements of shequ
democratic development, and many others. For chapter 7, I rely also rely heavily on
several magazines that are at the forefront of reporting issues related to property
10
James G. March and Johan P. Olsen, “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political
Life,” American Political Science Review 78:3 (1984), pg. 738.
17
management and the homeowners’ committee: Xiandai Wuye (Modern Property
Management), Xiandai Wuye-Xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor), and Zhongguo Wuye Guanli (Chinese Property Management).
1.3 Chapter Summaries
Chapter 2: The Meaning and Concept of Shequ in China’s Political System
In this chapter I discuss the concept and meaning of shequ in China. Although it is
translated as “community” in English, it has some specific meanings in China. The most
obvious difference is that it is actually designated as an administrative level. I also
discuss in this chapter the institutions of the street office and the residents’ committee,
but particularly the latter, since it is the designated principal governing organization of a
shequ. The laws and regulations, history, functions, organization of the residents’
committee will be presented in this chapter. I will also discuss the historical background
and the rationale of the formulation of the shequ jianshe (community construction)
policy, especially how it evolved from an earlier policy of community services. Finally, I
briefly discuss the present state of the shequ jianshe policy.
Chapter 3: The Background of Shequ Democratization
In the discourse of “socialist democracy with Chinese characteristics,” grassroots
democratic self-governance is generally presented as a key element. What is the nature of
this grassroots self-governance and what is the relationship between democratic
development in shequ and other forms of grassroots democracy will be explored in this
chapter. I will particularly pay attention to the thought of Peng Zhen. One of the
“gerontocrats” in the reform era and generally regarded as a conservative outside of
18
China, Peng nonetheless is the main Chinese communist leader to advocate giving more
democracy to the mass in rural villages and urban communities.
In this chapter I also discuss the main causes of official promotion of shequ
democracy. Apart from the changing socio-economic environment, I point out that
government’s consideration of the costs and benefits of shequ democratic development
also played an important part in the decision to allow experiments of democratic political
reforms in grassroots China. I also draw attention to the impact of village democracy on
shequ democratization, and present a preliminary comparison of village democracy and
shequ democratic development in terms of their strengths and weaknesses.
Chapter 4: Institutionalizing and Reforming Shequ Elections
Central to grassroots political reform in cities is the institutionalization and
reforms of the elections of residents’ committees. Until the last decade, residents’
committees were mainly staffed by retired cadres from work units and household wives,
Elections were nominally held, but these elections were nonetheless mostly meaningless
exercises. A typical way to conduct an election was for the street office to first select the
candidates and in an “election” voters confirmed the selection.
Reforming the electoral process thus is vital in making residents’ committees
more accountable and democratic. In this chapter I will first discuss the general
conceptualization of elections in China, especially how official views toward election
have evolved from early Marxist influences to the recent model of “one-party competitive
elections.” I then proceed to discuss ten institutional aspects of the electoral process that
are essential and crucial in defining the success or failure of election reform. I will show,
in the discussion of these ten institutional aspects, that shequ elections in China have an
19
extremely decentralized character, with varying electoral institutional practices and
different outcomes in different localities. This decentralized character, while permitting
some local reformist officials to come up with institutional innovations that improve the
election process, nevertheless also have the drawbacks of making all these elections
unsystematic, unconsolidated, and subject to local influences.
Chapter 5: Toward Democratic Public Administration and Governance in Shequ
Apart from the election of the residents’ committee, shequ democratic
development includes the introduction of several institutions to make the public
administration of shequ more democratic. Following the official discourse on democracy,
I look at what kinds of institution embody democratic decision-making, democratic
management, and democratic supervision, and how these institutions are implemented in
shequ. I also discuss what kind of institutional innovations have been introduced in trying
to reform the existing institutions, as well as the potentials of these institutions in
effecting a more democratic public administration.
All these reform measures can be understood as efforts to democratize the shequ
in a top-down manner. Both central and provincial governments have encouraged local
governments to experiment, within certain perimeters, with institutional innovations that
would make residents’ committee more accountable to the residents. This top-down
process of democratization, imperfect as it is, signifies the political reforms that are being
encouraged in China.
Chapter 6: Accommodating the Party or Accommodating Democracy?
Notwithstanding the institutional innovations and experimentations, the political
structure within a shequ is supposed to mirror the political structure at the national level.
20
One of the perimeters of these innovations and experimentations is that each shequ is to
maintain a party organization that plays a “leadership role.” Critical scholars and China
observers will remain skeptical of any claims of “democratic breakthrough” resulted from
shequ jianshe as long as the power of the ruling party is unquestionable. In this chapter I
focus on the shequ party organization –the nationwide party building program, the nature
and content of the program of “shequ party building” that is to running together with the
shequ jianshe policy, the organizational and penetration work of party building, the party
organization’s relationship with the other shequ institutions, and what kind of
institutional innovations have taken in shequs that would democratize the party
organization.
Chapter 7: The Homeowners’ Committee: the Rise of Shequ-based Civil Society
While the previous chapters focus on the top-down direction of shequ
democratization, this chapter analyzes the bottom-up process of democratizing the shequ.
Despite the visible hand of the government in the community construction project and the
fact that many residents have not enthusiastically responded to this project, there are
signs that these urban communities could slowly evolve into a foundation for civic
society.
The most important shequ-based non-governmental organization is the flowering
homeowners’ committees and their “weiquan” (rights-defense) movement. Originated in
Shenzhen, this phenomenon has spread to other cities. The homeowners’ committee is
established to protect the rights of homeowners in the face of developers, property
management companies, and occasionally local governments. In most cases they do not
challenge the local authorities overtly. The more affluent middle-class members, who are
21
usually thought of being politically obedient, nevertheless demonstrate their “rightsconsciousness” and organizational capabilities in the homeowners’ rights-defense
movement. This chapter analyzes the structural origins of the homeowners’ movement,
the concept, laws and regulations of property management, the main issues of concern to
homeowners, the institutional obstacles of establishing of a homeowners’ committee, and
the institutional innovations the homeowners have come up with.
The relationship between the homeowners’ committee, civil society, and
democratic development is further developed in the last section of this chapter. There are
contradictory trends. On the one hand the homeowners’ committee has characteristics of
a civil society organization that could strengthen the democratic foundation of China. On
the other hand, the homeowners’ committee is also heavily regulated, restricted, and in
some instances penetrated by the party.
Chapter 8: Conclusion and Discussion
In this concluding chapter, I discuss three theoretical perspectives for shequ
democratic developments. The first perspective interprets shequ democratization as the
foundation for the eventual democratization of China. The second perspective sees shequ
political reforms as the coping strategies for an authoritarian system that will prolong its
longevity. The third perspective sees shequ democratic developments as exemplification
of the “socialist democracy with Chinese characteristics.” In the final part of this chapter,
I provide an explanation why I see the third perspective as the more fruitful interpretation
compared to the first two.
22
Chapter 2 The Concept and Meaning of Shequ in China’s Political
System
In China, areas under the administration of street offices and residents’
committees are popularly known as shequs/communities. But in strict official usage of
the term, shequ has a specific meaning and is demarcated in accordance to the boundary
of an administrative level. The shequ jianshe (community construction) policy aims to
make urban shequs the robust, vigorous, self-reliant, and stabilizing building blocks in
China’s cities, which have been going through rapid demographic, social and economic
transformation and face many critical issues.
In this chapter, I will first discuss the differences between the Chinese concept of
shequ and the general notions of community, and then proceed to present a brief history
of the residents’ committee, the laws, functions and responsibilities, and organization of
the residents’ committee, shequ reforms in macro-perspective, and the current state of
shequ jianshe (community construction).
2.1 Shequ and Community
German sociologist Ferdinand Tönnies is the first major thinker to formulate a
comprehensive theory of community (Gemeinschaft). Tönnies views community as a
form of pre-industrial, pre-modern human association that is characterized by unity of
human wills among members. According to him, “Community by blood, indicating
primal unity of existence, develops more specifically into community of place, which is
expressed first of all as living in close proximity to one another. This in turn becomes
23
community of spirit, working together for the same end and purpose.”11 Home,
neighborhood and comradeship are the corresponding expressions of these three elements
of community.12 The rural village during the pre-industrial era that features strong
kinship ties, high level of face-to-face interactions and familiarity, moderate division of
labor, commonality of physical life, belief, and social norms, as well as the closeness of
living and working spaces, embodies Tönnies’ conception of community. The onslaught
of industrial modernity disrupted and dissolved the community type of human
association, and brought forth a new mode of human association: society (Geselleschaft).
The society exhibits characteristics that are opposite to the nature of community:
depersonalized relationships, interaction based on utilitarian motives, diversity of beliefs
and social mobility. The rise of the modern city and the trend of urbanization exemplify
the displacement of community by society. In his classic essay on urbanism, Louis Wirth
suggested that, “Nowhere has mankind been farther removed from organic nature than
under the conditions of life characteristic of great cities.”13
The transition from traditional community to modern society was also the major
theme occupying the thought of many classical social theorists. Durkheim differentiates
modern organic societies from traditional mechanical societies. Weber sees urbanization
as part of the process of rationalization and bureaucratization –the most important
changes in the era of industrialization. And Marx would see the process of capitalistic
mode of production displacing feudalistic mode of production being reflected in
11
Ferdinand Tönnies, Community and Civil Society, edited by Jose Harris, New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press (2001), pg. 27.
12
Ibid, pg. 28-29.
13
Louis Wirth “Urbanism as a Way of Life,” in Neighborhood, City, and Metropolis: An Integrated Reader
in Urban Sociology, edited by Robert Gutman and David Popenoe, New York: Random House (1970), pg.
54.
24
industrial urbanization. The town is the productive and revolutionary center of a new
civilization, while the countryside, filled with peasants, can only follow the lead of the
town in entering a new stage of history.
The presumed death of traditional, organic, natural communities in the modern,
“artificial”, urban society needs to be qualified. It is true that the community that features
closed territorial boundary belongs to a long-gone era. But sociologists also have found
that grassroots communities that cherish social bonds and natural common identity
continue to exist and evolve in the supposedly impersonal metropolises. The rise of
industrial, urbanized society as the age of the European Enlightenment drew to a close
was thought to be a liberating force for the people who yearned to escape from the
encapsulating bonds and ties of traditional communities and to live a more privately
guarded life. But the negative consequences of the demise of traditional communities
were also apparent, with crime, divorce, and suicide rates rising. Grassroots communities,
usually formed along ethnic ties or similar class background, were able to provide some
refuge from these negative effects.
The ideas of community by spirit and unity of will also resonate with modern
theorists and thinkers who are concerned with the ill effects of industrialization and
urbanization, such as the decline of civic responsibility and public-spiritedness. They see
this decline as responsible for the range of social problems in modern society. Theorists
of different ideological persuasions, ranging from “third way” social democracy to
communitarianism, therefore argue for a more cohesive, integrated, and participatory
social life oriented towards grassroots communities. “Third way” advocate Anthony
Giddens writes that “community building emphasizes support networks, self-help and the
25
cultivation of social capital”14, and it “doesn’t imply trying to recapture lost forms of
local solidarity: it refers to practical means of furthering the social and material
refurbishment of neighborhoods, towns, and larger local areas.”15 In short, “the theme of
community is…fundamental to the new politics” of the social democracy of the Labor
Party in Britain.
On the other hand, the communitarian movement led by American sociologist
Amitai Etzioni also takes community as the core of a new policy and ideological platform
that positions itself between liberal-individualists and moralistic social conservatives.
Communitarians seek to establish community as an alternative mechanism to the state
and market for distributing goods. They are unsatisfied with the overemphasis on
individual rights in the dominant liberal paradigm. They contend that the enjoyment of
rights comes with the moral obligations and responsibilities to the communities in which
an individual is embedded. Although Etzioni asserts that community is “not a concrete
place but a set of attributes,”16 the communitarian writings generally do emphasize
individuals’ local relationships and the importance of organizations and associations
being properly rooted in, and responsive to, their local constituents.17
2.1.1 Shequ in China
Similar to “third way” and communitarian writers, in recent years China also
seeks to address some of the social problems emerge from the reform process through
14
Anthony Giddens, The Third Way: The Renewal of Social Democracy, Cambridge, UK: Polity Press
(1998), pg. 110
15
Ibid, pg. 79.
16
Amitai Etzioni, The New Golden Rule: Community and Morality in a Democratic Society, New York,
NY: Basic Books (1996), pg. 6.
17
Elizabeth Frazer, “Communitarianism,”, in New Political Thought: An Introduction, edited by Adam
Lent, London: Lawrence and Wishart (1998), pg. 117.
26
community organizing and institutions.18 The concept of “community” was imported into
China during the 1930s through the flowering of sociological studies at that time. The
term was translated as shequ by the eminent sociologist Fei Xiaotong.19 However, the
term rapidly disappeared in China after the new People’s Republic condemned sociology
as a “bourgeois” discipline and banned its teaching and research. Shequ only resurfaced
in the post-Mao era when social science disciplines were rehabilitated. It became part of
the official discourse in the mid 1980s when the Ministry of Civil Affairs promoted the
policy of shequ fuwu (community service) in the cities. In 2000, the Ministry of Civil
Affairs issued the document “Opinion on Promoting Shequ Construction Nationwide”.
The document was later re-issued as Central Document No.23 jointly by the State
Council and the Central Committee of the Communist Party. This officially began the
central government’s push for shequ jianshe (community construction) nationwide.20
With the initiatives and support of the party and government, shequ has become a regular
term appearing in the media and popular discussion.
The official revitalization of shequ carries certain policy implications. Shequ in
China does not simply mean a grassroots, “organic” community. An important feature of
Chinese shequ is that it is a “combination of administrative unit and community.”21 From
its very inception, shequ jianshe is not only meant for community construction. It has
18
David Bray, “Building ‘Community’: New Strategies of Governance in Urban China,” Economy and
Society, 35:4 (2006) pg. 530-549.
19
Yu Yanyan, Shequ zizhi yu zhengfu zhineng zhuanbian (Community Self-governance and Transformation
of Government Functions), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 18
20
Chen Zhiwei & Dai Zhiwei, Shequ jianshe lilun yu shijian tansuo (An Inquiry into Community Theory
and Practice), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 2-3.
21
Xu Yong, Chen Weidong et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Community Self-governance in Urban
China), Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe (2002), pg, 34.
27
strong elements of social control and urban management.22 Just as the village is the
lowest level of administration in the rural areas, shequ is designated as the lowest level of
the administrative hierarchy in the cities (see Figure 2.1). Predominantly the boundary of
each shequ is demarcated as the jurisdiction of a shequ residents’ committee (jumin
weiyuanhui).23 In rarer instances it is demarcated as the jurisdiction of a street office
(jidao banshichu).
However, it would be a mistake to conclude that shequ serves no greater purpose
than being a convenient instrument for managing and controlling urban population, and
that the residents’ committee as nothing more than a field office of the local government.
The Chinese Constitution and the principal law on the residents committee designate the
residents’ committee as a “mass self-governance” organization. Although shequ (and
village) constitutes a level of administration and its authority sanctioned by the state, it is
not considered part of the formal state apparatus. The lowest reach of the formal power
of the Chinese state is the township level in the countryside and the street-office level in
the cities. Members of the residents’ committee are not considered state cadres or civil
servants.
Some may consider this assertion to be insignificant since the residents’
committee in practice has always been performing social, political and policing
responsibilities entrusted by the government. Nevertheless we should also pay attention
to the fact that the government has never made any attempt to incorporate the residents’
committee into its formal apparatus. Instead, the government has always insisted that the
22
Yu Yanyan, Shequ zizhi yu zhengfu zhineng zhuanbian (Community Self-governance and Transformation
of Government Functions), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 21.
23
Sometimes it is also translated as “neighborhood committee” in some English publications. To maintain
consistency throughout this dissertation I will use the term “residents’ committee”.
28
residents’ committee remains a self-governance organization. Despite being a
government-initiated program, one of the goals of the shequ jianshe policy is to
eventually make shequs less reliant on the state and become a self-sustaining, selfgoverning and harmonious community.
Shequ thus has different meanings from what is traditionally understood as
“community”. At the risk of over-simplification, we can say that there are at least four
principal differences between shequ in China and a typical community.
First, a “community”, as usually understood in developed societies, implies a
common attachment developed naturally by the people inhabiting an area with open
boundary and usually minimal government’s interference. Whereas in China, the
formation, organization and development of shequ is the result of government’s policy
initiative and planning, though its future development could make it more like a
“community” than an administrative unit.
Second, a shequ in China has some functions that a typical community does not
usually have –such as acting as an agent of social and political control for the state.
Although a community generally also has some sort of social control mechanisms to
preserve community tradition, morality and coherence, the political, policing and security
responsibilities being entrusted to shequ organizations in China are not something
commonly found in typical communities.
Third, community governance in general has a strong voluntary element. But in
China almost all shequ residents’ committees in one way or another have to take some
instructions and orders from their administrative superiors in the street office. Residents
29
in general perceive the residents committee as an agent of the government rather than
being a genuinely autonomous self-governance body.24
Fourth, community development, as suggested by Giddens or Etzioni, aims to
foster civic responsibilities and public spiritedness, rebuild trust among the atomized
individuals, reduce the sense of alienation and the associated social ills, and to rely on the
local populace to take care of their own community problems. In short, community
development is meant to deal with problems in a post-industrialized, postmodern society.
In China, however, the shequ jianshe policy was initiated with the hope of mobilizing
urban residents to help the government in the modernization process. A Chinese scholar
argues, “Shequ itself has become a factor in modernization; it helps China’s present
transition to a modern society, modern economy, and even democratic development.”25
2.2 A Brief History of the Residents’ Committee
The principal self-governance organization of shequ is the residents’ committee.
Unlike its rural counterpart –the villagers’ committee, which was established after the
dissolution of the people’s communes in the early 1980s, the history of the residents’
committee is only two or three years shorter than the history of the People’s Republic.
Despite being a grassroots organization, the residents’ committee played an important
role in the state rebuilding process after the 1949 revolution. The China that the Chinese
Communist Party (here after CCP or simply the party) inherited from its defeated rival,
the Kuomintang, was a broken one, exhausted by civil wars, economic mismanagement,
24
Chen & Dai, Shequ jianshe lilun yu shijian tansuo, pg. 78.
Guo Shengli, Jumin weiyuanhui de chuangjian yu biange: Shanghaishi gean yanjiu (The Establishment
and Change of the Residents Committee: A Case Study in Shanghai), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe
(2006), pg. 158.
25
30
and social disintegration, particularly in urban areas.26 The CCP’s power was built in the
rural areas. After leaving the cities in 1927 as a result of Kuomintang’s sudden
suppression, the CCP returned to the cities only in 1948-49.27 After the CCP captured the
cities, it decided to dismantle the entire administrative apparatus left behind by the
Kuomintang and wanted to start all over. But the immediate Herculean task was: How to
govern these populated cities with practically no state institutions of its own? The
residents’ committee was one of the Chinese communist responses to this question.
2.2.1 The Residents’ Committee and the Baojia System
The residents’ committee shares some similarities with the pre-1949 baojia
system, a grassroots political management system that has its origins in the dynastic
periods in rural China. But its modern form was introduced by the Japanese occupation
forces in occupied cities during the Sino-Japanese War in 1937 to1945. The organizing
principle of the baojia system was simple. Below the city government was the district
level, and within a district, around ten to thirty households formed a jia; and ten to thirty
jias were organized as a bao.28 Under this system, all families were integrated into a
baojia network, and each unit within the baojia would have a designated leader who
could liaise with the local policy authority. The city policy chief was also then the top
official to oversee all baojia organizations in a city.29 This system, though disliked by the
26
Maurice Meisner, Mao’s China and After: A History of the Peoples’ Republic, revised edition, New
York, NY: The Free Press (1986), pg. 86.
27
Jürgen Domes, “The Emergence of the People’s Republic of China,” in China: Seventy Years after the
1911 Hsin-hai Revolution, edited by Hongdah Chiu & Shao-Chuan Leng, Charlottesville, VA: University
Press of Virginia (1984), pg. 65-67.
28
Ding Chao, “Chengshi shequ jianjiu zhiyi: Chuantong chengshi shequ xiang xiandai shizheng zuzhi de
zhuanxing (A Study of Urban Community Part 1: Traditional Urban Communities’ Transition to Modern
Municipal Administrative Organizations),” Zhongguo fangyu (Chinese Territories) 3 (2001), pg. 8.
29
Franz Schurmann, Ideology and Organization in Communist China, Berkeley and Los Angeles:
University of California Press (1968), pg. 369-370.
31
residents in general, was impressively effective in maintaining law and order, performing
surveillance and control functions, and keeping and managing information about
households and residents. The Kuomintang, despite branding baojia organizations as
symbols of Japanese occupation and oppression, nevertheless found their usefulness once
they re-captured the cities from the Japanese forces. The urban “re-organization” scheme
of the Kuomintang never went beyond the superficial stage. The baojia system and most
of its personnel were effectively retained by the Kuomintang.
When the CCP took over the cities, the baojia system was (again) declared a tool
of the reactionary and imperialist forces. It was, therefore, an illegitimate institution that
had to be disbanded. A significant number of baojia personnel were targets of
persecution, though in reality, many of them were also temporarily retained by the CCP
for lack of a better choice; for these people were still needed to maintain local order in
the chaotic period of regime transition in the cities.30 But importantly, the CCP also
understood very well that this type of system was essential for its control and social
management functions, for securing a foundation of the new regime, and for its role in
social re-integration in the process of regime change.31 The residents’ committee was the
communists’ answer to the baojia system.
2.2.2 The Residents’ Committee: 1949 to 1976
According to the most recent archival research, the first residents’ committee was
founded in Hangzhou. In December 1949, Hangzhou city government promulgated an
ordinance on the residents’ committee. This ordinance stipulated that the baojia
30
Zhu Guoming, “Shanghai: Cong feibaojia dao jumin weiyuanhui de dansheng (Shanghai: From the
dissolution of Baojiao to the Birth of the Residents’ Committee),” Dangan yu shixue (Archives and
History) 2 (2002), pg. 58.
31
Guo, Jumin weiyuanhui de chuangjian yu biange, pg. 29-30.
32
organization had to be smashed and replaced by a new mode of democratic organizing
and participation –the residents’ committee. The residents’ committee would not become
part of the official governmental structure but rather would be a self-governance
organization. The “Organic Rules on Urban Residents’ Committee”, the national law on
this organization that would be promulgated 5 years later, contained many provisions that
originated from this ordinance.32
But before 1954, the residents’ committee was only one of the many types of
neighborhood and grassroots organizations proliferating in China’s cities. Most of these
organizations were ad hoc in nature, and resulted in disorganized and chaotic urban
administration.33 For instance, in Shanghai, grassroots organizations such as “tenants’
union”, “tap water managerial committee”, “workers’ welfare union”, and “winter
defense team” became widespread in many neighborhoods.34 The CCP also utilized their
time-tested mobilization capability to build up their own support base, especially among
the marginalized groups in the cities under Kuomintang rule, such as workers, hawkers,
and petty artisans. These grassroots activists became the backbone of a wide variety of
grassroots organizations in the cities.
The leaders of these organizations were generally appointed and supervised by
local public security officers. Although the multiplicity and ad hoc nature of these
organizations presented administrative problems such as overlapping functions and multi32
Han Quanyong, “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin zuzhi de fazhan yu qishi (zhiyi): Xin Zhongguo diyige
dansheng shimo (The Development and Inspiration of Urban Residents’ Organizations in the Early History
of the PRC (part 1): The Beginning and End of the First in New China),” Shequ (Community) 9 (2006), pg.
34-36.
33
Schurmann, Ideology and Organization, pg. 369-373.
34
Han Quanyong, “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin zuzhi de fazhan yu qishi (zhi er): Zhengti chuding,
juweihui zhongjie baojiazhi lishi (The Development and Inspiration of Urban Residents’ Organizations in
the Early History of the Peoples' Republic of China (part 2): Early Establishment of the Regime, the
Residents’ Committee System Ending the Baojia System),” Shequ (Community) 11 (2006), pg. 24.
33
head leadership, these organizations were to play an important role in “poverty and
disaster relief, administration of refugees and jobless wanderers, propaganda of party
policies, smoothing over residents’ doubts [of the new regime], security work, census,
and household registration.”35 These organizations were therefore vitally important for
the consolidation of the communist rule in the cities, and helped the new city
governments to formulate policies on production, education, health and urban
administration.
The process of standardizing, formalizing, and consolidating these various
grassroots organizations began in 1952. In June 1952, the East China Military and
Political Committee drafted a plan on establishing residents’ committees in cities with
population larger than 100,000. At the national level, a national decree was issued to
launch a campaign to mobilize urban residents to “cleanup” the remnants of Kuomintang
and other resistance forces in the cities. It was in this decree that the residents’ committee
for the first time was being acknowledged by the laws and regulations at the national
level.36 The campaign had the effect on consolidating the diverse grassroots organizations
into what would become residents’ committees. The residents’ committee was to play the
key organizing and mobilizing role in the cities in subsequent national campaigns,
including the Resist America Aid Korea, Three-Anti (corruption, waste, bureaucratism),
35
Chen Hui & Xie Shicheng, “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin weiyuanhui yanjiu (A Study of Urban
Residents’ Committees in the Early History of the PRC,” Dangdai Zhongguoshi yanjiu (Contemporary
China History Studies) 9:4 (2002), pg. 45.
36
Han, “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin zuzhi de fazhan yu qishi (zhiyi)”, pg. 20.
34
and Five-Anti (bribery, tax evasion, theft of state properties, dishonesty in work, theft of
state economic intelligence) campaigns.37
In 1953, Peng Zhen, the then mayor of Beijing and the party leader in charge of
legal work at that time, in a report suggested that
An organization such as the residents’ committee needs to be established. Its
nature is a mass self-governance organization, not a governmental organ. Its
primary mission is to organize the residents who are not working in factories,
shops, schools or government offices. Under the principle of self-governance,
they should take care of the residents’ welfare, publicize policies and laws of the
government, mobilize the residents to support the government’s appeal, and
communicate to the base-level government the opinions of the residents. The
residents should elect members of the residents’ committee. The work of the
residents’ committee should be under the guidance of urban base-level
government or its field office, but organizationally the residents’ committee is not
a “leg” of the base-level government, it should not be given too many tasks.38
According to Peng Zhen, both the street office and the residents’ committee were meant
to be temporary organizations. They were meant to compliment the production or work
units (danwei) in a dual administrative system. Therefore, whereas workers and students
were organized at their places of employment or study,39 the primary mission of the street
office and residents’ committee was to organize residents outside the orbit of danweis
(factories, schools, enterprises, army units, government organs, hospitals) such as
housewife, hawkers, artisans, jobless youth and the elderly people, who were then
estimated to comprise around 60% of the urban population. With industrialization,
economic growth, and the completion of socialist transformation, the danwei system
37
Frederic Wakeman Jr., “‘Cleanup’: The New Order in Shanghai,” in Dilemmas of Victory: The Early
Years of the People's Republic of China, edited by Jeremy Brown & Paul G. Pickowicz, Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press (2007), pg. 57.
38
Peng Zhen, Peng Zhen xuanji (Selected Work of Peng Zhen), Beijing: Remin chubanshe (1991), pg. 240.
39
Martin King Whyte and William L. Parish, Urban Life in Contemporary China, Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press (1984), pg. 22; Janet Weitzner Salaff, “Urban Residential Communities in the Wake of
the Cultural Revolution,” in The City in Communist China, edited by John Wilson Lewis, Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press (1971), pg. 289.
35
would eventually cover every single individual in the cities. Both the street office and
residents’ committee would eventually cease to exist. But for the time being, these
organizations were needed for the purpose of “total organization of the population.”40
With Peng Zheng’s urging, the Standing Committee of the National People’s
Congress (China’s legislative body) passed both the “Organic Rules on Urban Residents’
Committee” and the “Regulations on Street Office” in 1954. These two laws put the
Street Office-Residents’ Committee system (jiejuzhi) fully in place. This system played a
vitally important role in the early history of the republic, mobilizing urban residents to
support and consolidate the new regime, as well as extending the penetration of the
party’s power deep into the society, something never achieved by the Kuomintang.
During the Great Leap era (1958-1962), street offices were replaced by urban
people’s communes. The people’s commune was a vastly expanded and highly
centralized bureaucratic organ. The residents’ committee became an organizing part of
the commune, losing much of its self-governance functions and nature.41 As a campaign
to increase dramatically China’s economic production to “surpass Britain and catch up
with America”, the Great Leap spared no one from contributing to this highly politicized
economic goal. As mentioned before, the Street Office-Residents’ Committee system was
meant to organize residents outside of work units, which in the CCP’s socialist
ideological framework they were considered the “non-productive” population. A primary
mission of urban communization under the Great Leap therefore was to organize these
residents to engage in economically productive activities. The slogans used by Beijing
40
Schurmann, Ideology and Organization, pg. 377.
Chen Hui, “Woguo chengshi jumin weiyuanhui de huigu yu sikao (A Review and Reflection on the
Residents’ Committee),” Zhonggong dangshi yanjiu (Journal of Chinese Communist Party History Studies)
6 (1999), pg. 28.
41
36
municipal party committee during that era were “transforming a consuming city into a
productive city,” and “each individual has to work; each household has no idler.”42
Economic entities, including production type (such as small-scale processing plants) and
service-oriented type (such as canteens and childcare centers), were established in urban
neighborhoods.
There were several positive features in this experience. Women were liberated
from their housework and became members of the productive forces, elevating their
status in a regime committed to realizing the goal of a “workers’ state.” Neighborhoodlevel economic activities also generated resources for members of the commune. In fact,
these economic entities served as the foundation of the shequ fuwu (community services)
policy in future development. The downside was the increasingly bureaucratization of,
and residents’ alienation, from residents’ committees. Corruption on the part of resident’
committee members also increasingly became an issue, when they took over residents’
properties in the name of communization. Urban people’s communes, together with the
Great Leap, ultimately failed because of the highly unrealistic and politicized conception
of economic production. In 1962, most cities halted the communization movement and
reverted to the Street Office-Residents’ Committee system.43
42
Ding Chao, “Chengshi shequ jianjiu zhier: quanneng zhuyi jiangou zhong de shequ yu danwei (A Study
of Urban Community Part 2: Communities and Work Units Within the Totalistic Framework),” Zhongguo
fangyu (Chinese Territories) 4 (2001), pg. 5.
43
The above discussion is based on Guo Shengli & Gao Minzheng, “1958-1966: Jumin weiyuanhui
gongneng de bianyi yu huifu –yi shanghai shi weili de lishi kaocha yu fenxi (1958-1966: Deviation and
Restoration of Residents’ Committee Functions –A Historical Analysis on Shanghai),” Shanghai shehui
kexue yuan xueshu jikan (Quarterly Journal of the Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences) 3 (2002), pg.
183-192.
37
Notwithstanding its many positive roles in providing services and employment,
the residents’ committee was not a very popular institution among residents.44 The close
working relationship between local public security bureaus and the Street OfficeResidents’ Committee system brought to “bear upon every individual a pervasive and
overwhelming public pressure.”45 Spying on and denunciation of fellow neighbors by
members of the residents’ committee were not uncommon.46 As a nation with long
history of patriarchal tradition, women members of the residents’ committees acting as
bosses of the neighborhood also made many male residents uncomfortable.47 Therefore,
when the Cultural Revolution (1966-1976) engulfed the whole of China into a destructive
revolutionary frenzy, residents’ committees would not escape from the inevitable fate of
being targeted and struggled against.
Under these conditions, many residents’ committees were suspended, leading to a
chaotic situation in many neighborhoods. Frequently, neighborhood security and order
broke down. Residents’ committees were ultimately brought back to maintain
neighborhood order, but they were re-organized and renamed as “revolutionary residents’
committees”, mimicking the “revolutionary committees” popping up at the higher levels
of administration. They consisted of revolutionary rebels, members of the original
residents’ committees, and public security officers, and in some cases also the army
soldiers sent to the neighborhoods. The revolutionary residents’ committees’ main
44
Whyte & Parish, Urban Life in Contemporary China, pg. 285.
John King Fairbank, The United States and China, Fourth Edition, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press (1979), pg. 368.
46
Meisner, Mao’s China and After, pg. 90.
47
Schurmann, Ideology and Organization, pg. 377.
45
38
responsibility was to preserve order even as they pursued class struggle.48 They were also
given a vital mobilization task and became an important mechanism to transfer the urban
youth to the rural areas in the 1968 “up to the mountains, down to the villages”
campaign.49 For much of the Cultural Revolution period, the revolutionary residents’
committees excelled in the functions of organization, mobilization and control, while
only playing a secondary role in providing residential services.50
The Cultural Revolution ended with the death of Mao Zedong and the overthrow
of the Gang of Four in 1976. What followed were the rehabilitation of wrongfully
prosecuted individuals and the restoration of political institutions in place of the
“revolutionary” institutions set up during the Cultural Revolution era. The residents’
committee was re-instated in place of the revolutionary residents’ committee. In January
1980, the National People’s Congress re-promulgated the 1954 “Organic Rules Urban
Residents’ Committees” and “Regulations on Street Offices”. The sudden return of
millions of “transferred youth” to the cities created a huge employment problem. The
residents’ committees across the country helped alleviate the situation by employing
these returned young people in whatever economic activities they were still permitted to
do. The “reform and opening up” of China also gradually also began to alter the
ubiquitous landscape of danweis (work units) in China and presented new challenges in
48
Guo Shengli & Wang yinong, “Cong liweihui dao geweihui: “wenge” shinianzhong juweihui de kaocha
yu sikao (From the Neighborhood Committee to the Revolutionary Residents’ Committee: Investigating
and Reflecting on the Residents’ Committee in the Ten Years of Cultural Revolution),” Guangzhou daxue
xuebao (Journal of Guangzhou University) 3:7 (2004), pg. 7-8. See also B. Michael Frolic, Mao’s People:
Sixteen Portraits of Life in Revolutionary China, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (1980), pg. 232.
49
Thomas P. Bernstein, Up to the Mountains and Down to the Villages: The Transfer of Youth from Urban
to Rural China, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press (1977), pg. 85.
50
Liu Jitong, “Zuzhixing dongyuan yu zhengzhi jingji yundong: 20 shiji 60-70 niandai Zhongguo chengshi
shequ gongzuo moshi (Organizational Mobilization and Political and Economic Campaigns: The
Community Work Model in Urban China in the 1960s and 1970s),” Beijing keji daxue xuebao (Journal of
Beijing University of Science and Technology) 2 (2005), pg. 34.
39
which the danwei-based governance system was unable to cope with. The residents’
committee began to receive attention from national leaders to play a role in urban
governance.
After the re-promulgation of the 1954 “Organic Rules on Urban Residents’
Committees” in 1980, the Ministry of Civil Affairs had been soliciting opinions to revise
this law.51 In 1989, the NPC passed a new “Organic Law on Urban Residents’
Committees”. The law affirms the role and status of the residents’ committee while
expanding its responsibilities in the reform era. About ten years after the passage of this
law, the policy of shequ jianshe (community construction) was introduced. This would
ultimately lead to dramatic change in China’s urban grassroots governance, supposedly in
a direction of more participation and democracy.
It is ironic that the street office and the residents’ committee were originally
designed as temporary institutions that would wither away once “work unit socialism”
was fully built in China. Instead, both organizations have found a new mission in reformera China. In a reflection, a Chinese scholar writes that “50 years ago, the active
promotion of the residents’ committee was based on the assumption that active
mobilization of citizens would help the development and consolidation of the new regime
in urban areas. After 50 years, the intentions of reforming the residents’ committee under
the rubric of shequ jianshe are to readjust the state-society relationship, increase social
capacity for self-governance, and promote grassroots democracy.”52
51
“Cui Naifu jiu chengshi juweihui zuzhifa caoan zuo shuoming (Cui Naifu Explains the Draft of the
Urban Residents’ Committee Law” Renmin ribao August 30, 1989.
52
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The
Residents’ Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee
in Urban Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 46.
40
2.3 Laws, Functions and Responsibilities, and Organization of the Residents’
Committee
Article 3 of the 1982 Constitution of the Peoples’ Republic states that:
The residents’ committees and villagers’ committees established among urban and
rural residents on the basis of their place of residence are mass organizations of
self-management at the grassroots level. The chairman, vice-chairman and
members of each residents’ or villagers’ committee are elected by the residents.
The relationship between the residents’ and villagers’ committees and the grassroots organs of state power is prescribed by the law. The residents’ and villagers’
committees establish committees for people’s mediation, public security, public
health and other matters in order to manage public affairs and social services in
their areas, mediate civil disputes, help maintain public order and convey
residents’ opinions and demands and make suggestions to the people’s
government.53
The Street Office, which plays an important role in shequ jianshe, is the lowest level of
the administrative apparatus that guides the work and development of the residents’
committee. Nonetheless, it has no legal provisions in the Constitution. Technically is not
a formal level of government but rather a “field office” of the district government. The
1954 “Regulations on the Street Office” is still the only national law on the street office.
The law stipulates that the jurisdiction of a street office should be the same as the
public security office at the same level. There are only three official responsibilities: to
undertake the job assignments given by the municipal or district government, to guide
(zhidao) the residents’ committees’ work, and to communicate residents’ demands and
opinions to the district government. Before the reform of the danwei system, the
administrative structure was designed to strengthen the danwei and its vertical line of
authority. The street office had no power over these danweis and the government
departments under its jurisdiction. But with the implementation of shequ jianshe policy,
53
Appendix 3 in Kenneth Lieberthal, Governing China: From Revolution Through Reform, 2nd edition,
New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Co. (2004), pg. 426.
41
there is an attempt to strengthen the powers of the street office over the danwei
organizations under its jurisdiction, especially through the re-organization of street-level
party organization (to be discussed in Chapter 6).
Apart from the constitution, the most important law is the1989 “Organic Law on
Urban Residents’ Committees” (Residents’ Committee Law hereafter). Some of the more
important provisions in this law are as briefly listed below.
Article 2 states that the residents’ committee is a “self-management, selfeducation and self-service” mass organization. Its work is to be guided by the field office
of the municipal or district government.
Article 3 contains stipulations about the six primary responsibilities of a residents’
committee (to be discussed more extensively later).
Articles 8 and 9 contain rules regarding the composition and election of the
residents’ committee (to be discussed in Chapter 4).
Article 10 stipulates the status, power, and composition of the residents’
assembly, an organ in which the residents’ committee is responsible to (to be discussed in
Chapter 5).
Article 15 provides the basis and procedure of formulating a “residents’ selfgovernance charter” (to be discussed in Chapter 5).
Article 19 states that the work units (danweis) within the jurisdiction of a
residents’ committee (meaning the shequ) are not required to take part in the activities of
42
the residents’ committee. However, they should provide support when there is such
demand.54
It is interesting to note here, that unlike its rural counterpart –the 1987 Villagers’
Committee Law, Residents’ Committee Law provides no legal ground of party leadership
in a shequ. In fact, the law has no mention of the party organization at all.
Apart from these three basic laws, many other laws and departmental regulations
also have provisions pertaining to the residents’ committee and the street office.55
Provincial, city, and district governments also enact their own policies, rules and
regulations regarding the street office and the residents’ committee. While the national
laws provide the basis, it is these local policies and regulations that constitute the way
shequ jianshe is carried out in each locality, and it is here that we usually find some
institutional innovations in shequ governance. Many of these laws and regulations also, in
effect, expand the functions and responsibilities of the residents’ committee beyond what
is stated in the constitution and the Residents’ Committee Law.
54
“Zhonghua renmin gongheguo chengshi jumin weiyuanhui zuzhifa (Organic Law on the Urban
Residents’ Committee),” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s Community Construction
Yearbook 2003), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 133-135.
55
Below are some of the examples: Article 12 of the Law on Physical Culture and Sports states that
residents’ committees should organize exercises and other physical activities for the residents; Article 13 of
the Compulsory Education Law states that residents’ committees shall assist the government in bringing
school-age children and adolescents to school; Article 12 of the Law on Population and Family Planning
states that residents’ committees shall conduct the family planning work in accordance to the law; Articles
43 and 44 of the Marriage Law give residents’ committees the power to intervene in family issues such as
domestic violence, maltreatment and deserted family members; the 2007 Emergency Response Law
effectively incorporates the street office and the residents’ committee into the emergency response and
control mechanism. For a detailed discussion of the many laws that touch upon the residents’ committee,
see Deng Enyuan & Zhao Xuechang (ed), Shequ jianshe zhengce yu fagui (Policies and Laws of
Community Construction) Beijing: Zhongguo qinggongye chubanshe (2003). According to one count, as of
1998, there are around 130 laws and regulations that contain articles on the street office and/or the
residents’ committee. See Yang Hongtai, Wu Zhihua & Shen Haiping (ed.) Chengshi shequ tizhi gaige yu
fazhi jianshe yanjiu (System Reform in Urban Communities and a Study of Legal Institutional
Construction), Shanghai: Shanghai Jiaotong daxue chubanshe (2004), pg. 35.
43
2.3.1 Functions and Responsibilities of the Residents Committee
Historically, the important functions performed by the residents’ committee were
mobilization, security, mediation, propaganda and welfare. As the historical introduction
in the previous section has illustrated, the new regime relied on the mobilization capacity
of the residents’ committees to carry out many political campaigns. Mobilizations were
not always for political goals. A former member of a residents’ committee recalled that
public sanitation and health campaigns were more frequent than political campaigns.56 It
was a crude but effective method to accomplish the policy goals of different campaigns.57
Apart from mobilization, security and control were other primary functions of the
residents’ committee.58 Each resident’ committee was responsible for forming a local
security committee (with one of the members of the residents’ committee being the leader
of this security committee). The main job of this security committee was to keep an eye
on the neighborhood and report suspicious activities to the police. Political monitoring
was also an important part of the job description.59 Jerome Cohen, an American expert on
the Chinese criminal justice system, wrote that this civilian security committee was able
56
Michael Frolic, Mao’s People, pg. 228.
A memoir by a Chinese writer told a story in which each family in a pest elimination campaign was
required to present evidence of eliminated pest such as chopped-off tails to the residents’ committee. See
Chen Chen and Ted King, Come Watch the Sun Go Home, New York: Marlowe & Company (1998), pg.
98.
58
Schurmann, Ideology and Organization, pg. 378; Fairbank, pg. 369; Meisner, Mao’s China and After,
pg. 90.
57
59
A civil affairs official mentioned in an article in 1990 that after the Tiananmen crackdown, residents’ committees
were the main forces to maintain political stability in neighborhoods with many college students. See Bai Yihua,
“Chengshi, juweihui, lingdao (Cities, Residents’ Committees, Leadership)” Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems) 6
(1990), pg. 59-60. A memoir by a dissident who had participated in the Tiananmen movement mentioned that aftermath
of the crackdown, “all residents’ committees and police in each city went house to house to check on the people in each
family.” See Zhang Boli, The Long Journey from Tiananmen to Freedom, New York, NY: Washington Square Press
(2002), pg. 89.
44
to bring surveillance “down to the level of the individual household, a task that the police
alone could not perform.”60
Since its formal establishment in 1954, mediation of neighborhood and family
disputes had always been an important quasi-juridical function performed by the
residents’ committee. A residents’ committee was responsible for forming a local
mediation committee (with one of the members of the residents’ committee being the
leader of this mediation committee) to oversee the mediation process. This local
mediation mechanism operated by the residents’ committee had provided an effective
alternative to China’s underdeveloped judiciary and contributed to the maintenance of
social stability. In addition, residents’ committees were also important organizers of
propaganda, ideological education, and policy promotion classes.61
The traditional political functions are not as important in today’s residents’
committees as they used to be. My interviewees confirmed to me that there were very few
political campaigns and propaganda activities, except for such occasions as the convening
of a new national party congress. Mobilization for crisis management continues to be an
important function. During the 2002-2003 SARS Crisis, residents’ committees were
mobilized to control and monitor the movement of migrant workers, inspect, question,
and isolate people who might have SARS symptoms, set up checkpoints, monitor the
entrance to their residential compounds, propagate official information on the crisis, and
60
Jerome Cohen, The Criminal Process in the People’s Republic of China, 1949-1963: An Introduction,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (1968), pg. 19-20.
61
Salaff, “Urban Residential Communities in the Wake of the Cultural Revolution,” pg. 292; see also the
memoir by Nine Cheng, Life and Death in Shanghai, New York, NY: Grove Press (1986), pg. 158.
45
clean the neighborhood.62 The effectiveness of this residents’ committee-based
emergency mobilization network is often cited as an important factor in China’s eventual
success in containing the SARS Crisis. Political security and surveillance, although not as
pervasive and invasive as they used to be, also remain to be an important job for many
residents’ committees.
In addition to these activities, the welfare functions had been the raison d'être of
residents committees. Even during the most turbulent Maoist years in which residents’
committees were loaded with mobilization and propaganda functions, welfare and
services remained basic responsibilities of the residents' committees. In the early postMao era, the Chinese leadership intended to make the residents’ committee a more
benign organization, strengthening its role in providing welfare and service. Articles on
the residents’ committee in Beijing Review, the primary official magazine in English
intended for foreign consumption, generally featured the residents’ committee as a
“good-neighborly” organization that takes care of public welfare, handles family issues,
provides employment opportunities to the jobless youth, provides services to the needy
and marginalized groups such as the elderly and the handicapped, acts as a liaison
between the government and residents, and even performs the role of matchmaker for
singles.63
62
Patricia M. Thornton, “Crisis and Governance: SARS and the Resilience of the Chinese Body Politic,”
The China Journal 61 (2009), pg. 42-43.
63
Luo Fu, “City Dwellers and the Neighborhood Committee,” Beijing Review 23:44 (1980), pg. 19-25;
Cheng Gang, “The Neighborhood Committee –Residents’ Own Organization,” Beijing Review 33:15
(1990), pg. 30-32; Yang Ji, “Neighborhood Committee: A Versatile Grassroots Organ,” Beijing Review
39:49 (1996), pg. 22-23.
46
By 1989, when the new Residents’ Committee Law was written to reflect changes
in China’s polity and society, six formal responsibilities were given to the residents’
committee:
(1) Publicizing the Constitution, laws, regulations and state policies, safeguarding
the lawful rights and interests of residents, educating residents for the fulfillment
of their statutory obligations and for the protection of public property, and
conducting various forms of activities for the development of an advanced
socialist culture and ideology;
(2) Handling public affairs and public welfare services of the residents in local
residential areas;
(3) Mediating disputes among residents;
(4) Assisting in the maintenance of public security;
(5) Assisting the local people’s government or its agency in its work related to the
interests of residents, such as public health, family planning, special care for
disabled servicemen and for family members of revolutionary martyrs and
servicemen, social relief, and juvenile education; and
(6) Conveying residents’ opinions and demands and making suggestions to the
local people’s government or its agency.64
A typical residents’ committee is more likely to undertake a staggering amount of
work in addition to the formal responsibilities contained in the law. A residents’
committee member described to me that the work and responsibilities of a residents’
committee are baoluo wanxiang (all-embracing), covering from the most trivial matters
in the neighborhood to the most important tasks such as fighting a pandemic crisis.
Numerous factors contributed to this increased amount work of the residents’
committee. First, as discussed earlier, many laws and departmental regulations
conveniently include the residents’ committee in the implementation of certain policies.
64
From LawinfoChina, a legal database managed by Peking University,
http://www.lawinfochina.com/law/display.asp?db=1&id=1207&keyword=residents, accessed September
19, 2008.
47
Second, many local government departments, in an effort to streamline their operations,
also conveniently prefer to transfer the numerous functions and responsibilities to the
residents’ committee.65 According to a number of Chinese press reports, typically a
residents’ committee would have to undertake from 100 to 200 work items, a majority of
them being tasks and responsibilities sent to them by different department and offices at
higher level.66 Somewhat ironically, although a policy goal of shequ jianshe (community
construction) is to increase their “self-governing” quality, many residents’ committees
have indeed been loaded with more functions and responsibilities since the promotion of
this policy (to be discussed more in a later section).
The many functions and responsibilities of the residents’ committee raise the
concern that this organization is becoming less of a “self-governance” organization. In
some cities reforms that are meant to alleviate the heavy workload of residents’
committees have been carried out.67 However, in general, most residents’ committees
today still describe their work situation as “shangmian qiantiao xian, xiamian yigen
zhen” (thousands of thread on top trying to squeeze in one needle hole at the bottom),
vividly portraying the demanding tasks and responsibilities being loaded to them.
2.3.2 Organization of the Residents’ Committee
According to Article 7 of the Residents’ Committee Law, a residents’ committee
shall have 5 to 9 members, depending on the size of the population under its jurisdiction.
65
Suzanne Ogden, Inklings of Democracy in China, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center
(2002), pg. 223.
66
Zhao Hongwen, “Juweihui de fudan daodi you duozhong (How Heavy is the Burden of the Residents’
Committee)?” Zhongguo shehuibao April 27, 2005; Zhi Xiumei, “Juweihui buneng shedouzhuang
(Residents’ Committees Cannot Take Care of Everything),” Zhongguo funubao July 13, 2005; Qian Lan,
“Yige shequ yao fuze 140 duoxiang gongzuo (A Community is Responsible for More than 140 Items of
Work),” Taizhou ribao November 15, 2008.
67
I will elaborate further these reforms in Chapters 3 and 5 later.
48
The residents’ committee has one chairperson. Each member of the residents’ committee
is in charge of one or two “lines of work” or “portfolios”. One (or sometimes two) of the
committee members will serve as a deputy to the chairperson. The chair may or may not
be in charge of one of the “lines of work”. In general, these responsibilities include
security, mediation, family planning, health, culture and education, women, youth and the
elderly affairs, welfare, among others.68 One of my interviewees describes the
chairperson and the residents’ committee as the “neighborhood prime minister (xiaoxiang
zongli) and his/her cabinet”.
Furthermore, Article 13 of the Residents’ Committee Law states that specialized
committees (such as security committee and mediation committee, which historically had
existed before the 1989 Residents’ Committee law) could be established under the
leadership of the residents’ committee. Generally speaking, only security, mediation, and
health committees are likely to be established. Article 15 of the law also stipulates the
establishment of a number of “residents’ small groups”, informal organizations of
residents based on housing blocks and buildings (to be discussed more extensively in
Chapter 4), under the leadership of the residents’ committee. Figure 2.2 illustrates the
general organizational structure of a residents’ committee.
2.4 Shequ Jianshe (Community Construction) in the Reform Era: A Macro
Perspective
As mentioned before, street offices and residents’ committees were revitalized to
play a larger role in urban governance after the decline of the danwei (work unit) system.
The areas under the administration of residents’ committees became known as the shequs
(communities). In order to understand the increasing significance of the shequs in the
68
Wang et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 183.
49
political system, we would have to first understand importance of the danwei system, as
well as the historical background of this system –the “totalistic” party-state in the Maoist
era.69
The danwei system was one of the institutions that buttressed the totalistic
political structure. Other institutions included the people’s communes (renmin gongshe)
in rural areas, the household registration system (hukou or huji) that restricted internal
migration, the class identification system (shenfen jieji zhidu) that classified the “class
backgrounds” of the citizens, the centralized job allocation and employment planning
system that highly restricted social and occupational mobility, the personal dossier
system that kept track of an individual misconduct throughout his or her life, the state and
collective ownership of means of production that centralized the control of economic
resources,70 and the extensive party networks among the people. The street officeresidents’ committee system (jiejuzhi) in the cities itself could also be considered as a
member of these totalistic institutions, although it was more a complimentary institution
to the danwei system.
It was through these institutions that communist party-state achieved a high
degree of centralized political control and penetrated into social, economic, and even
family life of the people. The communist political elite believed that such totalistic
control of the population was not only a necessary response to decades of wars, internal
69
The “totalitarian” model as applied to China in recent years has been criticized by a number of western
scholars as too simplistic (for example, Vivienne Shue, The Reach of the State: Sketches of the Chinese
Body Politic, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press [1988]), but in China increasingly many scholars use
the label quanneng zhuyi (which could be translated into “totalitarian” or “totalistic”) to describe the
political system under Mao’s rule. For example, see Guo Jiangang & Xi Xiaoqin, “Quanneng zhuyi zai
zhongguo de xingqi, gaochao jiqi weilai (The Rise, Climax and Future of Totalistic Politics in China),”
Zhejiang xuekan (Zhejiang Academic Journal) 5 (2003), pg. 157-159.
70
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu, ed., Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian (Community
Party Building in Urban China) Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2000), pg. 84-89.
50
strife, chaos, famines, political instability, and economic backwardness, but also to
organized and galvanize the population to achieve socialist targets and goals.71
Notwithstanding some of the achievements made during the Mao’s era, the
totalistic system severely stifled economic initiatives, innovation and development. The
market-oriented “reform and opening up” programs in the post-Mao era thus required the
dismantlement of these totalistic institutions. The system of classifying an individual’s
class background was abolished in 1979. Practically all people’s communes were
dissolved in the 1980s. Geographic, social, and occupational mobility also dramatically
increased with the abolition of the centralized job allocation system and the easing of the
household registration rules. The danwei system has survived, but its functions have been
dramatically transformed.
2.4.1 Emergence of the Shequ: Basic Factors72
The reform era thus dramatically transformed China from a totalistic party-state to
an authoritarian state. In the process shequs increasingly became more important in the
political system. In general, there are three principal factors that have contributed to the
emerging importance of the shequ: reform of the danwei system, the rise of non-danwei
population, and housing policy reforms.
71
See Lin Shangli, Dandai Zhongguo zhengzhi xingtai yanjiu (A Study of China’s Contemporary Political
Formation), Tianjin: Tianjin renmin chubanshe (2000), pg. 57-64.
72
The following discussion is based on Peng Bo, “Democracy, Governance and Party Legitimacy: A Study
of the Neighborhood in Shanghai,” in China at the Turn of 21st Century, edited by Jørund Buen and Björn
Kjellgren, Stockholm: Nordic Association for China Studies (2002), pg. 62-65; Yang Hongtai, Wu Zhihua
& Shen Haiping (ed.) Chengshi shequ tizhi gaige yu fazhi jianshe yanjiu (System Reform in Urban
Communities and a Study of Legal Institutional Construction), Shanghai: Shanghai Jiaotong daxue
chubanshe (2004), pg. 5-10; Xu & Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg, 9-10; Wang et al.
Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 375-380. Liang Qidong, “Chengshi shequ jianshe guanli de tizhi quexian yu
chuangxin gouxiang (The System Defects and the Innovative Thought in the Construction and Management
of Urban Community),” Shehui kexue (Journal of Social Sciences) 6 (2001), 39-40; Ogden, Inklings of
Democracy in China, pg. 222-223.
51
2.4.1A Reform of the Danwei System73
The pre-reform institution of the danwei is well known as the main mechanism to
provide employment, collect taxes, disperse welfare resources, monitor and control the
movement of its employees, certify births, deaths and marriages, and implement
governmental policies. Danwei could be the state and collective enterprises, bureaucratic
organs and agencies at different levels of government, and the state’s “service units”
(shiye danwei) such as hospitals, universities and schools, and research centers.
The basic foundation of the danwei system was established in 1956 with the
completion of the “socialist transformation” of urban private enterprises. At the height of
its development, most residents in urban China were organized into different danwei, and
it became the single most effective channel through which the state connected with and
controlled each individual. Beginning in the 1990s, the Chinese government undertook
the task of state-enterprise reforms. A more competitive market economy required the
enterprises to be more efficient and market oriented. Partly in pursuit of this goal, reforms
also tried to separate the government from state enterprises and service units, making
them more autonomous economic and social units.
The reforms also demanded the danweis to relinquish, on the one hand, their
welfare functions, such as housing, medical care, education, childcare, and residential
administration, and on the other hand, the political functions, such as ideological
education and mobilization. In doing so, the danwei reforms released the urban
73
For studies of the danwei system in English, see Marc J. Blecher & Gordon White, Micropolitics in
Contemporary China: A Technical Unit During and After the Cultural Revolution, White Plains, NY: M.E.
Sharpe (1979); Gail Henderson, The Chinese Hospital: A Socialist Work Unit, New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press (1984); Andrew Walder, Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese
Industry, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press (1986); Xiaobo Lu & Elizabeth Perry (ed.) Danwei:
The Changing Chinese Workplace in Historical and Comparative Perspectives, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe
(1997).
52
population from the tight control of the state, but at the same time also cut off the existing
channels for allocating welfare resources. China’s “danwei society,” a unique
phenomenon that characterized Chinese socialism, was disintegrating. A popular saying
in China is that the urban populace is experiencing a transition from being “danwei ren”
(unit persons) to “shehui ren” (social persons). Many of those relinquished functions,
especially those of welfare services and administrative nature, were now to be taken up
by residential units, primarily the residents’ committee. For example, pension payments
by the state and unemployment insurance are now to be administered by the residents’
committees.74
2.4.1B The Increase of Non-Danwei Population
While the above scenario points out the changing nature of danwei, the number of
people not covered by a danwei had also increased significantly. This is due to the
following reasons:
1) The Increase of Laid-off Workers: As a result of the reform of state-owned enterprises,
“iron rice bowl” employment by danwei was no longer guaranteed to the workers. Some
state-owned enterprises went beyond paring down the number of life-time jobs and
became fully privatized. Since 1996, the number of workers in state-owned enterprises
was reduced by 31 millions. Every year, millions of laid-off employees from state-owned
enterprises were added. The residents’ committee is now tasked to take care of the
management (such as birth/death certification, marriage licenses, school enrollment for
74
Kazuko Kojima and Ryosei Kokubun, “The ‘Shequ’ Construction Programme and the Chinese
Communist Party,” in Bringing the Party Back In: How China is Governed, edited by Kjeld Erik
Brødsgaard & Zheng Yongnian (2004), Singapore: Eastern Universities Press, pg. 218. It is important to
note here the reform of the danwei system does not mean that the danweis are no longer an important
institution. In many ways the reform makes them more efficient organizations. Many state and collective
danweis continue to exert certain influence in the shequs in which they are stationed.
53
their children, enforcement of family plan, etc.) of this increasingly large group of people
who no longer have connection to their danwei. The re-employment scheme increasingly
has to rely on the work of the residents’ committee as well.75
2. Rise of Non-State Enterprises: China in the reform era has witnessed the rapid
development of private, joint venture, and foreign invested enterprises. These enterprises,
unlike the pre-reform danwei, have no legal obligation toward the social welfare of their
employees. Without an advanced governmental social welfare system in place, the social
welfare of these employees falls to shequ organizations.
3. The Aging of the Population: One cumulative effect of the one-child policy over the
years is the aging of the population. In 1982, the ratio of the elderly people age 60 and
over to the whole population was 7.6%. In 2000 the number increased to 10.1%, which
translates into 130 million senior citizens in China.76 The problem of an aging population
is compounded by the adoption of a nuclear family life by many families, particularly in
the cities. The result is that, in spite of controlled population growth, the number of
households in China had increased substantially. When the danwei system shed its
welfare responsibilities, this also meant that that the retirees among the elderly population
could no longer rely on their former work units to take care of them. Community (shequ)
care for the elderly population thus became one more task assigned to the shequ.
4. Rising Migrant Population: China’s urbanization process likewise picked up its pace
after 1979. While the 1980s saw the income of peasants increased substantially, in the
75
Zhang Yong, “Chengshi shequ tizhi gaige xianzhuang yu sikao (The Present Situation and Thoughts on
Urban Community System Reform),” Guanxi shehui kexue (Guanxi Social Sciences) 6 (2001), pg. 102.
76
In Shanghai, in 1999 the ration of the elderly people age 60 and older to the whole city population was a
staggering 18.2%, which translates into 2.3 million people. See Wang et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg.
379.
54
1990s rural income lagged behind urban income. Urban jobs became a much more
attractive option for the rural surplus labor. As more and more peasants have taken up
undesirable jobs in the cities, China has witnessed a phenomenal “floating population” of
migrant rural labor in the 100s of millions. These migrant workers in most cases are still
disadvantaged by the restrictive hukou (or huji) household registration system. While the
hukou system has been relaxed so as to permit greater geographical mobility, the
continuation of the hukou system still ties the migrating workers to their original
provinces. This means that the migrant workers encounter serious difficulties in getting
the benefits and acceptance from the cities they migrated to. Their employers have even
fewer incentives than does the urban government to provide assistance and benefits to the
migrant labors.
Another group with higher geographical mobility is the professional and
management class; many of them become expatriates sent from other cities to
metropolitan areas such as Shanghai, Shenzhen, and Beijing. With the number of migrant
workers and migrant professionals rapidly rising, residents’ committee becomes one of
the primary organizations designated to provide assistance to and management of these
people.
2.4.1C Housing Policy Reforms
Unlike in the past when housing was part of the benefits provided by the danwei,
today the government encourages urbanites to purchase their own homes. As more and
more residents become homeowners, their concerns of neighborhood and community
issues also naturally increase (this is the major topic to be discussed in Chapter 7).
55
2.4.2 From Shequ Fuwu (Community Services) to Shequ Jianshe (Community
Construction)
The immediate implication of the decline of the danwei system for urban
governance should not be underestimated. Monitoring of crime or political subversive
activities, as well as provision of welfare services, became harder. Governmental
programs such as family planning, public health, re-employment, and the census would
need reliable grassroots agents to implement. Large inflows of migrant labor would cause
serious problems if left unmanaged. Issues of local and essentially community nature,
such as neighborhood disputes, environmental concerns, or the use and management of
community public goods, required an authoritative body for mediation and deliberation
so these issues would not escalate into wider conflicts and overload the burden of city
governments. It was clear to the both central and local officials that a new urban
governance system in which state programs would be implemented and services
delivered “on the basis of residence rather than work unit”77 was needed. Residents’
committee had not been expected, much less equipped, to step into a major role in baselevel governance. But together with the street office, they were now being revitalized to
counter the social ills and governance crisis resulting from the decline of work units. This
is a two-stage process, first being the shequ fuwu (community services) policy in the
1980s and early 1990s that focused more on welfare and service provisions, and the
second being the shequ jianshe (community construction) policy beginning in the late
1990s until present, a more comprehensive policy program.
77
Lieberthal, Governing China, pg. 186.
56
2.4.2A Shequ Fuwu (Community Services)78
In 1983, the Ministry of Civil Affairs began to contemplate an overhaul of the
welfare and service delivery system. It sought ways to diversify the channel of social
service provision. Around 1986-1987, the Ministry brought forth the concept of shequ
fuwu (community services), in which shequ residents were to provide for themselves
mutually beneficial social services and solve their local problems. In 1993, 14 central
government bodies including the Ministry of Civil Affairs, the Ministry of Finance, and
the State Planning Commission issued a joint policy paper stating the nature, goals,
responsibilities, and management of community services. Community services were
categorized into three general types: (1) welfare services for the vulnerable groups of the
society (ruoshi qunti, such as the elderly, the handicapped, widows, and destitute
families) that were basically free-of-charge; (2) livelihood convenience services (bianmin
limin fuwu) that were allowed to charge for the services; and (3) the management of
workers’ social insurance.
Under this shequ fuwu policy, the residents’ committee is to become a major
coordinator for different service providers or is itself a major provider for the livelihood
convenience services. These services (such as grocery stores, barber shops, locksmiths,
health-care consultation, and repair shops) were obviously meant to improve the quality
and convenience of life for shequ residents, at the same time generating substantial
78
In addition to the articles cited in the following discussion, I also draw on these studies: Linda Wong and
Bernard Poon, “From Serving Neighbors to Recontrolling Urban Society: The Transformation of China’s
Community Policy,” China Information 19:3 (2005), pg. 413-442; Qingwen Xu, Jianguo Gao, Miu Chung
Yan, “Community Centers in Urban China: Context, Development and Limitations,” Journal of Community
Practice 13:3 (2005), pg. 73-90.
57
employment opportunities.79 The livelihood convenience services were also recognized in
an earlier policy paper as part of the service sector in the economy, making them
commercially oriented. The welfare services for the vulnerable groups would then be
partly financed by profits generated from these livelihood convenience services.80 Smallscale private enterprises that provide these services were also encouraged to develop
under the supervision of the residents’ committee.
The rationale of these policy initiatives was obvious: since the service sector in
the economy was generally less developed at that time and the government was no longer
willing to provide such services, it was hoped that locally self-reliant community services
would be the solution. In addition, with the ability to generate their own resources,
residents; committees were expected to be less dependent on the government. They
would also be able to provide job opportunities.81
However, one result of the dual nature (being welfare- and commercial-oriented at
the same time) of shequ fuwu was that many residents’ committees began turning their
understanding of shequ fuwu into a money-making venture, neglecting the welfare part of
the definition, and diverting a great deal of their energy and time from other duties and
responsibilities. They were several reasons for this development. Placing the fee-charging
livelihood convenient services in the category of service industry, which the government
was promoting, naturally encouraged the residents’ committee to maximize profits out of
79
“Bianmin limin fuwu (Livelihood Convenience Services),” & “Shequ mianmin fuwu (Community
Convenience Services),” in Shequ cidian (A Dictionary of Community), edited by Hu Shensheng, Shanghai:
Shanghai guji chubanshe (2006), pg. 266 & 294.
80
Tian Hua, “Lun zhongguo shequ fuwu qianshinian de fazhan guiji (On the Track of Development of
Community Service for the First 10 Years),” Lilun yuekan (Theory Monthly) 11 (2007), pg. 89. See also
Qingwen Xu & John F. Jones, “Community Welfare Services in Urban China: A Public-Private
Experiment,” Journal of Chinese Political Science 9:2 (2004).
81
Zhang Guixing, “Guanyu juweihui de diwei zuoyong he cunzai wenti (About the Status and Problems of
the Residents’ Committee),” Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems) 4 (1992), pg. 65.
58
these commercially-oriented services. Inadequate funding on the part of the government
and unwillingness to contribute to the operation of the residents’ committee on the part of
the ordinary residents also meant that most residents’ committee would have to rely on
their own commercial ventures to generate resources.82
Such commercialization of the shequ fuwu policy seriously undermined the policy
goal of providing welfare services to the vulnerable groups. A study of community
service implementation in Beijing reveals that fee-charging services had proliferated over
the years, while welfare services for the vulnerable groups were “no better than before.”83
It could also generate tensions with between the residents’ committee and residents, since
the economic interests of the residents’ committee did not necessarily coincide with the
interest of the residents, to whom the residents’ committees are supposed to be
accountable to.84
Even if the residents committees were to devote themselves to the welfare aspect
of shequ fuwu, it was clear that the issues emerging from the rapidly transforming and
diversifying urban population necessitated a larger, and more fundamental, change of the
methods and institutions of urban governance. Dissatisfied residents, including the
unemployed, laid-off workers, and migrants, were potential recruits for organizations that
the party would see as subversive. That Falun Gong, a complex urban-based quasireligious organization, could emerge and grow to the extent that it challenged the
authorities by posting a mass protest in Tiananmen Square in 1999, only heightened and
confirmed the central leadership’s concerns that urban grassroots governance had to be
82
Xinping Guan & Julian Chow, “The Development of Urban Community Welfare Services in China,”
Social Development Issues 25:3 (2003/2004), pg. 58-60.
83
Xu & Jones, “Community Welfare Services,” pg. 52.
84
Wang et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 347.
59
rigorously strengthened under a more comprehensive, long-term, and strategic paradigm,
which is the shequ jianshe policy.85
2.4.2B Shequ Jianshe (Community Construction)
In 1991, the then Minister of Civil Affairs, Cui Naifu, began to articulate the idea
of shequ jianshe (community construction). In 1992 the first nationwide conference on
shequ jianshe was held in Hangzhou, Zhejiang province. In 1994, the then Chinese leader
Jiang Zemin, in a speech addressed to the deputies to NPC, suggested the strengthening
of base-level institutions such as the street office and the residents’ committee in urban
governance, as well as the need for shequ jianshe (community building), making this
speech one of the earliest calls by the central leadership to make shequ jianshe a major
policy.86 In his report to Sixteenth Party Congress in 2002, in the passage regarding
political development and restructuring, Jiang maintained that “extending democracy at
the grassroots level is the groundwork for developing socialist democracy,” which
includes “[improving] self-governance among urban residents and [building] new-type
and well-managed [shequs] featuring civility and harmony.”87
In a Central Party School forum on building a harmonious society (hexie shehui)
in 2005, the present Chinese leader Hu Jintao pointed out that the shequ plays the crucial
roles of bridging the relationship between the mass and the party and maintaining social
85
The connection between the challenges of Falungong and shequ jianshe is acknowledged in a number of
Chinese publications. For example, see Chen & Dai, Shequ jianshe lilun yu shijian tansuo), pg. 3. A
Chinese expert on grassroots democracy also noted that the Falun Gong movement was the immediate
factor of the shequ jianshe policy. See Li Fan, “Zhongguo dalu chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu fazhan
beijing (The Background of the Development of Community Grassroots Democracy in China’s Cities)” in
Zhongguo dalu chengshi jiceng minzhu yanjiu (A Study of Urban Grassroots Democracy in Mainland
China), edited by Chu Shin-Min, Taipei: Yuanjing jijinhui (2004), pg. 29-30.
86
“Jiang Zemin tongzhi zai bajie quanguo renda sici huiyi shang de jianghua(jiexuan)”, in Zhongguo shequ
jianshe nianjian 2003, pg. 7.
87
Appendix 1 in Lieberthal, Governing China, pg. 370.
60
stability. In a speech at the same forum, the then director of the party’s Organization
Department Zeng Qinghong also said, “shequ is the cell of society, and constructing
harmonious shequ is the basis of building a harmonious society.” In the same speech, he
also emphasized social stability, service to the people, residents’ self-governance, cultural
advancement and the leadership of the party as the crucial elements of making the shequ
a harmonious living community for different social groups.88
In July 1998, during a restructuring of the State Council, the Bureau of BaseLevel Government of the Ministry of Civil Affairs was renamed the Bureau of BaseLevel Government and Community Construction (jiceng zhengquan yu shehui jianshe si),
underscoring the increasing significance of shequ jianshe. In 1999, the Ministry issued
the policy document “On the Setting up of Experimental Sites of Shequ Construction
Nationwide.” It first selected 11 urban districts (qu), later adding another 15 districts
from 21 cities as the experimental sites of shequ jianshe.89 As experimental sites, these
district and city governments were given greater autonomy to initiate reforms “without
explicit authorization from the central government.”90 This document explicitly states
that the experimental sites should embrace greater democracy and residents’ selfgovernance. It also maintains that the residents’ committees should continue to be the
88
Quoted in Zhang Baofeng, Xiandai chengshi shequ zhili jiegou yanjiu (A Study in the Governance
Structure of Modern Urban Communities), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 4.
89
These cities are: Beijing, Shanghai, Chongqing, Nanjing, Hangzhou, Qingdao, Shijiazhuang, Haikou,
Shenyang, Tianjin, Hefei, Harbin, Benxi, Xi’an, Wuhan, Jinan, Foshan, Shenzhen, Kelamayi, Luohe,
Xiamen, Changchun.
90
James Derleth and Daniel R. Koldyk, “The Shequ Experiment: Grassroots Political Reform in Urban
China,” Journal of Contemporary China, 13:41 (2004), pg. 751. The authors of this article erred in stating
that the selected sites were shequs. In fact, these sites are districts. It has to come from the district
government to initiate shequ jianshe, not shequ, which is not a level of government.
61
principal self-governance body in whatever reforms that might be undertaken by the
experimental sites.91
Before these actions taken by central government, in the mid 1990s some cities,
such as Qingdao, Shanghai, and Shenyang, had already been experimenting with different
ways to restructure and reform their grassroots governance system. Encouragement and
endorsements from the Ministry of Civil Affairs meant the central government not only
approved the work of these cities but also shared their assessment that grassroots
governance in urban China needed an overhaul. With the central government’s support,
more cities took up the task to reconstitute their grassroots urban governance system. The
institutional innovations and experiences of the more successful cities and districts come
to be known as different models of shequ jianshe. Appendix 2.1 presents a brief
discussion of some of these models.
After examining the characteristics, strengths and weaknesses of these models and
their experiences, the Ministry of Civil Affairs in 2000 issued the “Opinion of the
Ministry of Civil Affairs on Promoting Shequ jianshe Nationwide.” I should note here
that this policy document, while undoubtedly the most important document on shequ
jianshe coming from the central government, is not a law.
This document defines the nature, goals, basic principles and contents of shequ
jianshe. It is meant to provide certain standardizations and serve as guidance. In this
document the Ministry of Civil Affairs agrees to the policy of consolidating the existing
residents’ committee into a larger residents’ committee, and defines the boundary of
91
Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi (Community Residents’ Self-governance in Urban
China), Shenyang: Liaoning renmin chubanshe (2004), pg. 46.
62
shequ as the jurisdiction of this enlarged residents’ committee.92 This new residents’
committee should then be renamed as the shequ residents’ committee.93 In the rest of this
dissertation I will refer to this institution as the shequ residents’ committee or the
residents’ committee interchangeably, with the understanding that these are all residents’
committees that have been consolidated under this policy.
Shequ jianshe is defined as “under the guidance of the party and government, a
[community construction] process in which the strengths and resources of the shequ
would be relied upon and utilized to strengthen shequ functions, solve shequ problems,
promote the political, economic, cultural, environmental, and healthy development of the
shequ, and increase the quality of life for shequ residents.” The document also lays out
the five basic principles in which the different local shequ reform projects should adhere
to:
(1) people-based (yiren weiben) and serving the residents as the core ideas;
(2) sharing of resources between different shequ organizations, and between
shequ organizations and danwei organizations stationed in shequs;
(3) restructuring of the shequ management system to make it more efficient,
orderly, and has the legal authority to accommodate its increased responsibilities;
(4) expanding shequ democracy and residents’ self-governance; and
92
The demarcation of shequ is not without disagreements. Shanghai and Qingdao continue to defy the
Ministry of Civil Affairs and defines shequ at both the street office level at the residents’ committee level.
Some scholars also voice their support for Shanghai’s method. See Wei Kenan, “Lun shequ zizhi (On
Community Self-Governance),” Sichuan daxue xuebao (Journal of Sichuan University) 5 (2003), pg. 50. A
minority view also argues that shequ should be even smaller than the pre-reform Residents’ Committee.
See Xu Chongde (ed.) Chengshi zhengzhi xue (Urban Politics), Beijing: Guangming ribao chubanshe
(1988), pg. 256.
93
In 2000 there were a total of 108424 residents’ committees, and by 2003 this number went down to
77431, because of the consolidation policy. See 2006 Zhongguo shehui tongji nianjian (2006 China Social
Statistical Yearbook), Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe (2006), pg. 291.
63
(5) allowing for local variety and being flexible and pragmatic in designing a
shequ jianshe policy.
Shequ fuwu (community services) is retained as a key component of shequ
jianshe, but the contents of shequ jianshe are now expanded to include environment
(cleanliness, expansion and maintenance of “green” areas, etc.), health administration
(prevention measures, health and sanitary inspections, family planning, etc.), public
security (legal education and community correction, management of migrant population,
ensuring social stability, etc.), cultural development (“spiritual civilization” building,
ideological-political work, exercises, science education, etc.), grassroots democracy,
party-building, and any other contents that are deemed to be relevant. The policy
document also recommends that shequ jianshe be incorporated into national, provincial,
and local economic and social development plans.94
It is clear that from shequ fuwu to shequ jianshe, the major driving force comes
from both the central and local (especially the city level) authorities. With the decline of
the danwei system, they are justified to be worried about the negative effects, not just in
terms of service delivery failures, but wider social disintegration and alienation as well.
The developing market cannot pretend to be an integrative force when it is actually
creating more inequality and marginalizing vulnerable groups in the society. Shequ
jianshe was proposed to be the solution that can reshape and re-integrate the society.95
2.4.2C Comprehending Shequ Jianshe
94
“Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijing chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian (Opinion of the Ministry of
Civil Affairs on Promoting Community Construction Nationwide” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian
2003, pg. 135-138.
95
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (Residents’
Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee in Urban
Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 271, 306.
64
A Chinese scholar argues that from the perspectives of both the central and local
authorities, there are three different expectations or conceptualizations of what shequ
jianshe essentially imply: (1) replacement of danwei; (2) social foundation of party rule;
(3) a partner of the state.96
Replacement of Danwei
The first conceptualization is to treat the shequ as spatial units of governance. The
shequ is designed to replace the danwei as a new platform for policy implementation,
services delivery, and control and management. In this sense, it is no different from the
danwei: both are parts of a huge state machinery of social management. Under this
conceptualization, the shequs should be built in a way that minimizes variety and
promotes homogenization and standardization.
Social Foundation of Party Rule
The second conceptualization is to regard the shequ as the social foundation of the
ruling party. With the demise of the danwei, the party finds itself losing its grassroots
connection and penetration. The shequ jianshe policy highlights the critical task of reenergizing and bolstering shequ party building. Through this policy the party will become
more active and invigorated at the grassroots level to re-affirm its leadership, to recruit
the grassroots elite, to re-organize base-level party organizations, and therefore to prevent
politically challenging forces from emerging (more discussion on this theme in Chapter
6).
A Partner of the State
96
Peng Bo, Lujing yilai yu zhili xuanze: dangdai Zhongguo chengshi shequ biange (Path Dependence and
Governance Choice: Changes in Contemporary Urban Communities in China) Bejing: Zhongguo shehui
chubanshe (2007) pg. 16-18.
65
The third conceptualization envisions the shequ as an eventually well-developed
community that can partner with the state in present era of great social transformation in
the cities. Unlike in the past, the Chinese government today recognizes the role of
autonomous social forces. A mature, autonomous, trustful, and cooperative society
reduces the costs and burdens of governance, diffuses grievances, and most importantly,
provides the scope and space for a modernizing state to engage in its efforts of
transforming and rebuilding its functions and institutions. Under this conception, the
shequ is the basis of not just modernization but of a civil society (to be discussed more in
Chapter 7).
In addition to these three conceptualizations, I would say that there is a fourth
conceptualization: A Testing and Training Ground for National Democratization. As
such, the shequ can also be conceptualized as the testing and training ground and the
base-level foundation of national democratic politics. In the 2000 Ministry of Civil
Affairs policy document, speeches by China’s leaders, government and party’s reports,
and a government white paper on democracy, the shequ is consistently designated as part
of China’s grassroots democracy, which in turn is a component of the official socialist
democracy with Chinese characteristics. Under this conception, the institutional
innovations to democratize the shequ could offer valuable lessons of how
democratization might (or might not) be done on a larger scale. This, of course, is the
overall theme of this dissertation.
All these conceptualizations translate into concrete tasks and responsibilities to be
fulfilled by the shequ. They also contribute to both its increasing significance and
problems. Different levels or departments of the government might be visualizing the
66
shequ with a particular conceptual emphasis. For example, promoting democracy and
elections usually receives greater support from higher levels of government (typically the
forerunners in, and designers of, shequ democratization are district governments, such as
Haishu district in Ningbo, Luwan district in Shanghai, Yantian district in Shenzhen)
rather than from local cadres, especially the street office officials. The party and public
security officials might be more enthusiastic in emphasizing the security aspect of shequ
jianshe, while other departments have their own focus in mind. Since the shequ jianshe
policy is such a comprehensive program, the shequs are now made responsible for so
many tasks that some scholars are worried that the emphasis on autonomy and selfgovernance might be weakened considerably.
A Chinese scholar speaks of the two contradictory trends or orientations emerging
from the experiences of various shequ jianshe programs in the country: (1) an
administrative steering or guidance orientation (xingzheng daoxiang), in which the
government plays a larger and stronger role, with weak autonomous development of
shequ organizations; and (2) self-governing orientation (zizhi daoxiang), in which the
government devolves more power to increasingly autonomous and democratic shequ
organizations.97 He argues that shequ jianshe should be kept on the track of making the
shequs more autonomous and democratic. The following chapters thus investigate the
issues and achievements of shequ democracy and self-governance.
2.5 The State of Shequ Jianshe (Community Construction)
97
Xu Yong, “Lun chengshi shequ jianshe zhong de shequ jumin zizhi (On Residents’ Self-Governance in
Community Construction) Huazhong shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Central China Normal University)
40:3 (2001), pg. 7-9.
67
As of 2005, the total number of residents’ committees in China was 79947, an
increase of 2.65% from 2004. With the policy of consolidating smaller residents’
committees into a shequ residents’ committee, the number of residents’ committee should
gradually become smaller. The reason that the number is growing points to the trend of
urbanization, and the conversion of villagers’ committees into residents’ committees.
Thus, while the number of residents’ committees was increasing, from 2004 to 2005, the
number of villagers’ committees decreased by 2.34%. A majority of these consolidated
residents’ committees contain 1000 to 3000 households.
According to a report prepared by Zhan Chengfu, the head of the Bureau of BaseLevel Governance and Community Construction of the Ministry of Civil Affairs, as of
2005, 99% of shequs have a residents’ committee, 93% have a party organization, and
89% establish a residents’ representative’ assembly. Traditional mass organizations also
have their local branches established in shequ, among which are the communist youth
leagues (69%), trade unions (57%), committees on the elderly (72%) and the disabled
(68%), and women’s groups (78%).
The total number of the members of residents’ committees in 2005 was 453,543,
of which more than half of them (240,890) were women. This was in accordance with the
historical pattern of women playing a larger role in the residents’ committee, especially in
comparison to villagers’ committees. However, today residents’ committee members are
generally younger as well. While the retirees were a major source of residents’ committee
members in the past, today many of them are in the age category of 31-50.
Many shequs did appear to be on the right track of building up the infrastructure
for community services, culture, education, public safety, social security, and welfare and
68
health provision. In general 80-90% of the shequs have community service centers,
public security offices and health inspection stations, and 60-70% of them have library
and other recreational public facilities. More than 20 million destitute families are
covered by the social safety net provided through shequ residents’ committees. In terms
of building up grassroots democracy, in 2004 and 2005, the numbers of residents’
committees that organized elections were 43053 and 29689 respectively, covering about
90% of all the residents’ committees.98 Of course these elections are not necessarily up to
the standards of democracy (to be discussed in Chapter 4), but compared to the past when
most residents’ committee members were simply appointed, this also represented an
improvement.
Conclusion
In this chapter, I explain the differences between the concepts of shequ and
community. In China, the term shequ has a policy dimension. It is officially demarcated
with officially supported (self-) governing institutions. The main body, the residents’
committee, has a long history dating back to the early years of the Peoples’ Republic.
Nevertheless, the residents’ committee was marginalized in the years of Maoist years of
central planning as the work units were the more important organizations in the urban
social, economic and political life. It was revitalized after the gradual destruction of
“work unit socialism” in the reform era. The government introduced the shequ jianshe
(community construction) policy in the late 1990s as the main urban governance system.
98
The above statistics come from Zhan Chengfu (ed) Shequ jianshe gongzuo jinzhan baogao (The Report
on the Progress of the Work of Community Construction) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg.
4-6 and 2006 Zhongguo shehui tongji nianjian (2006 China Social Statistical Yearbook) Beijing: Zhongguo
tongji chubanshe (2006), pg. 290-291.
69
This chapter also discusses the relevant laws and documents on the residents’
committee, its official functions, and its organizational structure. The residents’
committee handles many works in addition to the responsibilities, and remains an
important organization for policy implementation, popular mobilization and political
surveillance. With strong government involvement, there are some doubts among some
scholars and observers whether the shequ jianshe policy will be able to achieve the stated
goals of democratic self-governance. Nevertheless, the government remains officially
committed to the democratic self-governance of shequ.
70
Figure 2.1 Administrative Structure in China
1. Central Level
2. Province Level
3. Prefecture Level (Municipal/City Government)
4. County Level
Urban Areas
District Government
5. Town Level
Street Office
Rural Areas
County Government
Town/Township Government
6. Self-Governance Level (Shequ) Residents’ Committee Villagers’ Committee
Notes:
The Street Office is technically not a level of government (yiji zhengquan), but a field
office or dispatch agency of the district government (quzhengfu de paichu jiguan),
sometimes also referred to as a subdistrict government. Town or township
government in the rural areas is a level of government. The difference is that as a
level of government, the township has a township level people’s congress and has
more decision making powers.
At the self-governance level, both the residents’ committee and villagers’ committee
are technically not part of the state structure.
Shequ residents’ committee is the consolidated body of several original, smaller
residents’ committees.
Underneath the self-governance level, there are residents’ small groups, homeowners’
committees, and villagers’ small groups.
71
Figure 2.2 General Organizational Structure of the Residents’ Committee
Residents’ Committee Chair
Security
Mediation
Health
Family Planning
Welfare Women
Residents’ Committe
Security
Committee
Mediation
Committee
Health
Committee
Residents’ Small Group
Residents’ Small Group
Group
Residents’ Small Group
Residents’ Small
Notes:
1. A residents’ committee chair could also assume one of the portfolios.
2. One of the committee members could also be a vice-chairperson of the residents’
committee.
3. A committee member could be in charge of more than one portfolios.
72
Chapter 3 The Background of Shequ Democratization
As pointed out in the previous chapter, the Ministry of Civil Affairs 2000 policy
document affirms shequ democracy and residents’ self-governance as one of the
principles of the shequ jianshe (community construction) policy. A further elaboration of
this principle contains the following passage:
Shequ should be delineated scientifically and reasonably based on factors such as
locality and common identity. Democratic elections, democratic decision-making,
democratic management and democratic supervision should be implemented in
the shequ, and steps should be taken to realize shequ residents’ self-management,
self-education, self-service, and self-supervision.99
In 2005 the State Council issued a White Paper “Building of Political Democracy in
China”, which spells out the strategy of political reform and democratization preferred by
the party leadership. Chapter 6 of this White Paper is devoted to “grassroots democracy,”
which states that
China has now established a grassroots democratic self-government system,
which mainly includes the rural villagers’ committee, urban neighborhood
committee and the conference of workers and staff in enterprises. In these
grassroots mass organizations of self-government in urban and rural areas, the
Chinese people directly exercise their legal rights of democratic election,
democratic decision-making, democratic management and democratic
supervision, so that they can manage the public affairs and welfare undertakings
of their grassroots organizations and [shequs] by themselves. This has become the
most direct and broadest practice of democracy in China today.100
Election, decision-making, management and supervision thus are the four principal
elements in the official discourse of democracy. The latter three elements are meant
to make public administration and governance more democratic, rule-based, and
transparent. Following these two documents, we could make the argument that there
are three aspects of shequ democratization: (1) election, (2) democratic governance
(the other three elements in the official discourse), and (3) shequ self-governance
99
“Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijing chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian (Opinion of the Ministry of Civil Affairs
on Promoting Community Construction Nationwide),” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s Community
Construction Yearbook 2003), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 136-137.
100
“China's 2005 White Paper: ‘Building of Political Democracy in China’,” Asian Affairs: An American Review 33:1
(2006), pg. 18-19.
73
Election and democratic governance will be discussed in Chapters 4 and 5
respectively, while I will discuss the third aspect (self-governance) in the first section
of this chapter. In the rest of this chapter I will also discuss the theoretical causes of
official promotion of shequ democratization, and then briefly compare the advantages
and disadvantages of urban shequ democratic development and village democracy in
China.
3.1 Shequ Democracy and Shequ Self-Governance
Some Chinese scholars argue that the idea of residents’ self-governance under a
socialist political system can be traced back to Marx’s writings on the Paris Commune,101
in which he wrote “[once the] communal regime[s] were established in Paris and
secondary centers, the old centralized government would…have to give way to the selfgovernment of the producers.”102 But the influence of the ideas of Peng Zhen, the party
leader in charge of legal work in much of his public career, on the development of
grassroots self-governance and democracy, was probably more profound than Marx. In a
1987 speech, he answered the theoretical question “How can a billion people exercise
democracy and become their own masters?” by saying that
one way is to exercise the power of the state through the people’s congresses at
various levels, and the other way is to exercise mass self-governance at the
grassroots level, [and] let the people to take care of their own matters...Without
mass self-governance, without grassroots direct democracy, villagers and
residents cannot take care of their own public affairs. Our socialist democracy still
lacks a solid and comprehensive mass base. As for the ability to govern
themselves, through practices the people’s governing skills can be trained and
enhanced.103
Here Peng Zhen in fact laid out the foundation of the concept of two “spheres of
democracy”: (1) the “state” form of democracy embodied by the various levels of the
people’s congresses, which are the constitutionally recognized as the supreme power
101
Zhang Ji & Zhao Jie, “Makesi difangzizhi lilun yu 21 shiji Zhongguo de shequ zizhi (Marxist Theory of Local SelfGovernance and Community Self-Governance in 21th Century China),” Zhonggong Yunnan shengwei dangxiao xuebao
(The Journal of Yunnan Provincial Committee School of the CPC) 3 (2001), pg. 16-20.
102
Karl Marx, The Civil War in France, New York, NY: International Publishers (1940), pg. 58.
103
Peng Zhen, Peng Zhen wenxuan (Selected Works of Peng Zhen) Beijing: Renmin chubanshe (1991): pg. 608.
74
organs of the state (not party); and (2) the “social” sphere of democracy, which is the
system of grassroots mass self-governance (in both rural and urban areas), with the
“masses taking care of their own affairs”. This is recognized and promoted as a form of
socialist democratic practice, embodied particularly in the institutions of residents’
committees, villagers’ committees, and conferences of workers’ representatives in work
units.
Shequ democracy is thus inseparable from having an autonomous sphere of shequ
self-governance. In short, shequ democracy will be essentially meaningless if the selfgoverning institutions (shequ residents’ committees) are still nothing more than the
grassroots agents of, and controlled by, the government. Strengthening of shequ selfgovernance therefore means a reform of the relationship between the street office and the
residents’ committee.
3.1.2 The Relationship between the Street Office and the Residents’ Committee
In the previous chapter it was noted that both the constitution and the 1989
Residents’ Committee Law designate the residents’ committee as a self-governance
organization, and that the only national law for the street office, the 1954 “Organic Rules
on the Street Office”, specifies a limited amount of responsibilities. However, as the most
immediate government body that interacts with resident’ committees, the street office has
in fact always been, according to a Chinese scholar, “the central nexus of political power
in urban shequs; it fundamentally determines shequ socio-political life.”104
104
Zhou Ping, “Jiedao banshichu de dingwei: chengshi shequ zhengzhi de yige genben wenti (The Status of the Street
Office: A Fundamental Issue in Urban Community Politics),” Zhengzhixue yanjiu (CASS Journal of Political Science)
2 (2001), pg. 76.
75
A typical street office covers around 60,000 people and generally contains more
than 100 staff105, overseeing 3 to 10 residents’ committees. In a recent study carried out
in Shanghai, the researchers concluded that that under the existing administrative
arrangement, street offices have almost complete control over residents’ committees,
including appointments, dismissal, performance evaluation, and duties of the members of
residents’ committees, effectively turning them into “pseudo-administrative cadres.” The
residents’ committee, instead of being a “mass self-governance organization”, in fact
functions more like the executor of “administrative and management functions at the
urban grassroots level.” “From the street office’s point of view, residents’ committees are
their tentacles reaching out to the grass-roots.”106 Another study likewise concludes that
we see strong domination by the street office not only in personnel matters, but also in
other areas such as daily decision making, resources and spending, and the process of
drafting the self-governance charter.107 Several other empirical and theoretical studies
also confirm the patterns of a general lack of genuine autonomy of shequ residents’
committees and of a strong tendency to interfere from street offices.108
Such criticism of strong control over the residents’ committee is not limited to
academic writings. In 2000, a report of an inspection team of the Standing Committee of
105
Chen Jiaxi, Liu Jun, “Jiedao banshichu: lishi bianqian yu gaige quxiang (The Street Office: Historical Changes and
Trend of Reform),” Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems), pg. 53.
106
Yong Gui, Joseph Y.S. Cheng & Weihong Ma, “Cultivation of Grassroots Democracy: A Study of Direct Elections
of Residents’ Committees in Shanghai,” China Information 20:1 (2006), pg. 12, 24.
107
Shi Fayong, “Chengshi shequ minzhu jianshe yu zhiduxing yueshu: Shanghaishi juweihui gaige ge’an yanjiu
(Democratic Construction in Urban Communities and Institutional Constraints: A Case Study of Residents’ Committee
Reform in Shanghai),” Shehui (Society) 2 (2005), pg. 62-65.
108
Lin Shangli, (eds.) Shequ minzhu yu zhili: anli yanjiu (Community Democracy and Governance: Case Studies),
Beijing: Shehuikexue wenxian chubanshe (2003), pg. 129-131; Gui Yong, Cui Zhiyu, “Xingzhenghua jingchengzhong
de chengshi juweihui tizhi bianqian (The Changes of the Urban Residents’ Committee System in the Process of
Governmentalization),” Huazhong ligong daxue xuebao (Journal of Huazhong University of Science and Technology)
14:3 (2000), pg. 3-4; Hu Yong, “Jiedao bashichu yu shequ jumin weiyuanhui guanxi tantao (An Inquiry into the
Relationship between the Street Office and the Community Residents’ Committee),” Ningbo dangxiao xuebao (Journal
of Ningbo Party School) 5 (2005), pg. 55-58.
76
the National Peoples’ Congress on the implementation of the residents’ committee law
points out that one of the problems in the implementation of the law was that some street
offices have effectively turned residents’ committees into their own “dispatched
agencies.” The residents’ committees complained of having no power in decisionmaking, personnel and financial matters. The team regarded this practice as violating the
spirit of the residents’ committee law and urged the street offices to respect the selfgovernance status of the residents’ committees.109 Lacking essential autonomy, many
residents’ committees exhibit a strong tendency to behave more like a bureaucratic,
governmental organization, rather then the “mass self-governance” community
organization they are supposed to be.110
There are a number of factors that have contributed to the pattern of strong street
offices and weak residents’ committees. These include the socialist bureaucratic tradition
and tendency of “administrative totalism”, a weak economic base (notwithstanding the
operation of some commercial-oriented shequ fuwu [community services]) of the
residents’ committee, the inadequacies in the 1989 Residents’ Committee Law, and the
lack of community identity and spirit among shequ residents.111
109
“Quanguo renda changweihui zhifa jianchazhu guanyu jianche “Zhonghua renmin gongheguo chengshi jumin
weiyuanhui zuzhifa”shishi qingkuang de baogao (A Report on the Implementation of the “Organic Law on Urban
Residents’ Committee” by the Law Implementation Inspection Team of the Standing Committee of the National
People’s Congress)” in Jiujie quanguo renda changweihui zhifa jiancha baogao huibian (Compilation of Reports of
Law Implementation Inspection by the Standing Committee of the National People’s Congress), Beiing: Zhongguo
minzhu yu fazhi chubanshe (2003), pg. 632. This report was based research during field trips by the inspection team to
eight provinces.
110
Pan Xiaojuan, “Shequ xingzhenhua wenti tanjiu (An Inquiry into the Problem of Governmentalization of
Community),” Guojia xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of the National Institute of Administration) 3 (2007), pg. 3335.
111
Zhang Guoxiang, “Shequ zizhi yu shehui kongzhi (Community self-governance and social control)” Shehui zhuyi
yanjiu (Socialism Studies) 6 (2007), pg. 97. See also Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ
jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The Residents’ Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of
the Residents’ Committee in Urban Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 209-211; Yuan
Dayi, “Jumin zizhi yu jieju guanxi de yanjin (Residents’ Self-Governance and the Evolution of Street Office-Residents’
Committee Relations)” Fazhi lunchong (Rule of Law Forum) 20:5 (2005), pg. 15.
77
But perhaps the most important factor is the unwillingness of the street office to
grant a more autonomous space to the residents’ committee, because of its fear that this
would lead to the decline of the urban management authority and ability of the street
office.112 As noted in Chapter 2, there are two contradictory trends that have emerged
from the various practices of shequ jianshe: the administrative steering orientation
(xingzhenghua, denoting stronger governmental role and presence) and the selfgovernance orientation (zizhihua). Generally speaking, the administrative steering
orientation appears to be the more widespread trend. Despite its professed goal of
achieving shequ democracy and shequ self-governance, shequ jianshe could actually
strengthen the tendency for the government to exert stronger control over the residents’
committee, at least for a time period after immediate implementation. Given its strong
social engineering character, the policy of shequ jianshe requires city governments invest
considerable resources to create and sustain shequs so that they have the capability of
taking care of their own environment, healthcare, community services, cultural activities,
and democratic governance. Such heavy investment in resources also naturally comes
with a stronger urge to control.
Therefore, in order to increase the space for self-governance, it is necessary for
the street office to be less controlling and interfering, but not to the point of total
irrelevance; the question is how to achieve a balance between societal autonomy and
official control.
112
Yang Hui, Zhang Genfu, “Lun chengshi jiceng zhengquan yu jumin zizhi de youji xianjie (On Organically
Connecting the Urban Base-Level Government and Residents’ Self-Governance)” Zhejiang shifan daxue xuebao
(Journal of Zhejiang Normal University) 3 (2003), pg. 11. In Chapter 4 I will discuss various ways in which the street
office could exercise control in the electoral process of the residents’ committee.
78
A civil affairs official in Sichuan province argued that the contents of shequ selfgovernance should include self-governance in “social affairs” such as personnel
administration of the residents’ committee, financial resources, property of the residents’
committee, cultural and educational activities, and operation of shequ fuwu, as well as in
areas of work that are generally considered “governmental affairs”, such as public
security, family planning, and hygiene and sanitary administration.113 Most Chinese
scholars and officials, however, argued that in order for shequ self-governance to be
meaningful, a clear differentiation of the governmental/administrative affairs (zhengfu
shiwu) and social affairs (shehui shiwu) is necessary. The shequ residents’ committee
would then be in charge of the social affairs; while governmental affairs would be
undertaken by professional community workers hired and monitored by the street office
or by the specialized officers sent to the shequs by the district government departments.
Nevertheless, until today, there is still no consensus or standardization of the
exact content of shequ self-governance. Different cities have implemented different
policies in this regard. For example, in the city of Changsha, shequs are nominally
guaranteed several rights, including the free election of its own members of the residents’
committee, control of its own finance and resources, autonomous decision-making, selfsupervision and self-management.114 In Hangzhou, there are eight formal rights being
promised to shequs, including the right to refuse unreasonable or illegal request for work
113
Xu Kaiming, “Shequ zizhi de jiben neirong (Basic Contents of Community Self-Governance)” Shequ (Community)
3 (2003), pg. 22.
114
Zhang Suhui, Zeng Gang, “Wanshan Changsha shequ zizhi de tanjiu (An Inquiry into the Perfecting of Community
Self-Governance in Changsha)” Hunan xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Hunan Administration Institute) 5
(2005), pg. 49.
79
and fees imposed by the street office.115 Despite the fact that most residents’ committees
are still obliged to assist the street office in the areas of work that are considered
governmental affairs, the formulation of a set of formal rights of shequ self-governance
has increasingly become prevalent across China’s cities. This is an encouraging step
toward realizing the goal of shequ self-governance.116
3.2 Why Shequ Democracy?
As with any other major nationwide policy initiatives, it would not be possible to
speak of shequ democracy without the backing, or at least the tacit approval, from the
central party-state leadership. 2000 seems to be year in which the central leaders took
some actions. In that year, in addition to the issuance of the Ministry of Civil Affairs
document on shequ jianshe, the “Proposal of Formulating the 10th Five-Year Plan (20012005) for National Economic and Social Development,” the party’s major document on
development planning, also for the first time recognized the promotion of shequ
democracy as a major policy goal of the party.117 This documents calls for the
strengthening of the construction of base-level government and grassroots mass selfgovernment, the expansion of “orderly citizens’ political participation” (youxu gongmin
canyu), and the guiding of the people to take care of their own affairs based on the rule of
law.118 Thus, beginning in 2000, the promotion of shequ democracy had established itself
in the nation’s policy agenda.
115
Lu Jimin, “Youle shequ zizhuquan, dangjia jiuneng zuozhu le (With Self-Governance Right, Residents can Become
True Masters of Their Own)” Shequ (Community) 12 (2001), pg. 19-20.
116
Zhang Junfang, “Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi chuyi (Opinions on the Self-Governance of Urban
Communities” Tianjin shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Tianjin Normal University) 5 (2001), pg. 27-28.
117
Li Lianyong, “Shequ minzhu heyi keneng (How Community Democracy is Possible)” Zhonggong Zhejiang
shengwei dangxiao xuebao (Journal Zhejiang Provincial Party School) 6 (2003), pg. 94.
118
“Zhonggong zhongyang guanyu zhiding guomin jihua he shehui fazhan de dishige wunian jihua de jianyi
(Suggestions by the Central Committee of the CCP in Formulating the Tenth Five-Year Plan on National Economy and
Social Development) Renmin ribao October 19, 2000.
80
But this does not mean that the central leadership suddenly came to appreciate the
intrinsic value of democracy. A number of factors are crucial in the central government’s
decision to allow more democratic experiments in grassroots urban areas. There are: (1)
the social-economic changes in the cities, (2) government’s considerations, and (3) the
impact of village democracy.
3.2.1 Social-Economic Changes in the Cities
In Chapter 2, I discussed the pre-dominance of work units (danwei) in urban areas
in Mao’s era and the early years of the reform era. Residents’ committees were only
revitalized after economic reforms reached the cities in the mid-1990s, causing stateowned enterprises and other work units to undergo drastic transformations. The
possibility of shequ democracy and self-governance can be understood only in this same
context: the forces of socio-economic changes constituted the first push factor for
grassroots self-governance. The dismantlement of the totalistic institutions, the reform of
danweis, and economic liberalization freed up and expanded the social sphere for citizens
to pursue individual interests and identities. Civil society growth was possible when
individuals were released from the all-embracing functions of the danwei. The general
political implications of this were the increasing demand for more political participation
and the awareness of citizens’ rights.119 Urban grassroots self-governance thus offers a
channel to meet this demand.
In addition, for retirees and laid-off workers, shequs have become increasingly
more important to their daily life and interests than their former danweis. As a former
119
Lin Shangli, “Jiceng qunzhong zizhi: Zhongguo minzhu zhengzhi jianshe de shijian (Grassroots Mass SelfGovernance: The Practice of Building Democratic Politics in China)” in Haixia liangan difang zhengfu yu zhengzhi
(Cross-straits Local Government and Politics), edited by Chen Wen-chun, Kaohsiung: Graduate Institute of Political
Science, National Sun Yat-sen University (1999), pg. 200-201.
81
hospital doctor noted in respect a recent residents’ committee election, “Shequ residents’
committees are the bridge in which the party and government connect with the residents.
We the retirees now have less connection to our danweis, and spend more time in the
shequ. It could be said that we have become ‘social people’ from ‘danwei people’. We
are really serious about this election. Only when we elect good people who take a good
care of our shequ, can we then be at ease!”120
3.2.2 Government’s Considerations: Stability and Legitimacy
From the government perspective, by encouraging self-governance at the
grassroots level for local affairs unrelated to larger national concerns, the political
leadership hopes to unload some burdens and to create a buffer between the state and
citizenry. In truth, however, local affairs can have a profound effect on urban stability,
and urban stability also partly depends on harmony in the shequs. As socio-economic
reforms deepen in the cities, shequs have increasingly become the sites of various types
of conflicts (between local dwellers and migrant workers, rich and poor, property
management companies and homeowners, developers and homeowners).121 The 1989
Tiananmen crisis and the 1999 Falun Gong crisis, the two challenges to the party-state
rising from urban discontents, prompted the party to use (some) democracy in shequs to
better deal with some local issues and affairs. In short, shequ democratic development is
believed by the political leadership to be a force for social stability; it alleviates the
negative effects of social disintegration in the economically volatile environment by
120
Gao Xiushu, “Renxin shi hanping: Anhuisheng shouci shequ juweihui huanjie zhixuan ceji (The heart is the
measurer: Notes to the first direct election of residents’ committee in Anhui province” Zhongguo shehuibao November
2, 2002.
121
Liu Feng & Chang Jun, “Lun shehui zhuanxingqi shequ renmin neibu maodun de chansheng yuanyin he tedian (On
the Characteristics and Reasons of Peoples’ Conflicts in Communities during the Social Transitional Period)” Shanghai
shehui kexueyuan xueshu jikan (Quarterly Journal of the Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences) 3 (2000), pg. 57-64.
82
offering channels of social mobilization and integration through the self-governing
institution of residents’ committees.122 Shequ democratic building is therefore consistent
with the goal of constructing a “harmonious society” by the present leadership. It
provides a good platform for orderly political participation and for articulating and
protecting residents’ interests while not threatening political status quo and social
stability.
Another calculated benefit is the increase of legitimacy for the party-state. The
party was anxious to rebuild a closer link to the urban population after the loss of some
legitimacy associated with Tiananmen suppression.123 The purpose of introducing shequ
self-governance and democracy, therefore “was not to introduce forces capable of
opposing the authorities, but to transform and limit governmental functions…With the
government supportive of shequ self-governance and democracy and playing a less
meddling role in shequ affairs, the government enjoys higher support and reputation, and
the interaction between the government and the [shequs] will turn out to be much more
positive.”124 The increasingly supportive attitude toward shequ direct elections by the
central leadership also points to the instrumental value of creating “trust and legitimacy”
for the regime.125
The experience of gaining legitimacy and consolidation of the party’s rule
through democracy in the countryside (discussed below) also strengthens the leadership’s
confidence in grassroots democracy’s ability to generate similar support and legitimacy
122
Wang et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 44.
David Bray, “Building ‘Community’: New Strategies of Governance in Urban China,” Economy and Society, 35:4
(2006), pg. 535.
124
Li Lianyong, “Shequ minzhu heyi keneng”, pg. 95.
125
Thomas Heberer, “Institutional Change and Legitimacy via Urban Elections? People’s Awareness of Elections and
Participation in Urban Neighborhoods (Shequ)” in Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China: Institutional Change
and Stability, edited by Thomas Heberer, and Gunter Schubert, New York, NY: Routledge (2009), pg. 96.
123
83
to the regime and the party in the cities. The central leadership also expects an
improvement of cadre-mass relationship, stronger accountability and transparency, and
an increase of residents’ participations in shequ affairs through shequ democratic
development. If bad and incompetent officials can be rooted out, and instead competent,
clean and loyal (at least non-confrontational toward the regime) people are elected into
the residents’ committees and other institutions of governance, the legitimacy of the
regime and the party will be strongly enhanced.
3.2.3 The Impact of Village Democracy
Finally, perhaps the most important factor contributing to the development of
urban shequ democracy is the diffusion impact of village democracy. In late 1980s and
early 1990s, in response to the authority vacuum resulting from the dissolution of the
people’s communes in the countryside, the central government encouraged the election of
villagers’ committees.
The diffusion impact of village democracy that began more than 20 years ago has
been both vertical and lateral. Vertically, the impact of village democracy has led to the
election of officials at a higher level, particularly the town and township level
(xiangzheng), which is the logical step to further extend village democracy and to
complete political reforms in the rural areas.126 Laterally, village democracy also diffuses
to the urban shequs. This diffusion is sometimes popularly referred to as the third
126
Fearing a possible drastic consequence, the authorities have prevented this vertical diffusion of democracy, barring a
few towns/townships that were bold enough to undertake democratic elections to their mayors. Since town/township
level constitute a formal level of state administration, elections of town/township mayor has a legal and political
consequence of altering the existing authority structure of the state, and the authorities have been far more cautious and
conservative in this regard.
84
“encirclement of cities by villages” (nongcun baowei chengshi).127 Although far from
being an unqualified success, villager democratization may have opened “a window of
opportunity for the party to gain new legitimacy and political leeway for solving the
many problems that rural China faces, thereby securing its political survival.”128 Despite
having a different dynamic in place, urban shequ democracy may have similar stabilizing
and legitimizing effects.
From the perspective of the law too, both the villages’ committee and the urban
residents’ committee are essentially organizations with the same “self-governance”
nature under the constitution. There is no particular legal reason why members of the
residents’ committee should not be subject to popular vote, just as members of the
villagers’ committee are. If the regime is sincere in promoting more rule of law, as it
often proclaims, then giving the same voting right to the urbanites as it did to the
villagers is also on the path of following the true spirit of the constitution and the
residents’ committee law.
3.3 Village Democracy and Shequ Democracy: A Brief Comparison of Advantages
and Disadvantages
In comparison to village democracy, urban residents have a lower level of interest
in the activities and functions of shequ residents’ committees. They are reluctant to
participate in shequ affairs and to become members of the residents’ committee.
Although some residents’ committees have sizable assets and operate profitable shequ
127
Li Huan, “Guanyu woguo chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu jianshe de jidian sikao (Several Thoughts on the Grassroots
Democratic Construction in China’s Urban Communities)” Shaanxi shifan daxue jixu jiaoyu xuebao (Journal of
Further Education of Shaanxi Normal University) 21:2 (2004), pg. 59. The first encirclement refers to Mao’s strategy
of encircling KMT-ruled cities with revolutionary rural areas under the communist party leadership during the 19451949 Civil War, and the second encirclement refers Deng’s rural household responsibility system, which preceded
economic reforms in cities.
128
Gunter Schubert, “Village Elections, Citizenship and Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary Rural China” in Regime
Legitimacy in Contemporary China, pg. 70.
85
fuwu enterprises, in general residents’ committees have far fewer economic power and
control fewer resources than do villagers’ committees. A member of the residents’
committee has many thankless tasks, but the prestige and income is considered low by
urban standards. The urban danwei system, although in the process of slow decline, still
has significant influence over the life of many urban residents, especially employees of
the publicly owned enterprises and the service units still operated by the government. So,
they have few incentives and interests to participate in the residents’ committee.
Furthermore, the socio-economic ties of urban residents extend beyond their residential
areas. They are generally less tied into, and less interested in, the local neighborhood
affairs. Urban residents therefore tend to be more outward-looking than the villagers, who
have higher stakes in village administration and governance.
A survey conducted in a midlevel city in the northwestern autonomous region of
Xinjiang shows that close to a quarter of the interviewees expressed no knowledge of, or
interest in, the residents’ committee.129 A study of shequ participation in northeastern
Heilongjiang province likewise shows that shequ residents generally have less interest
participating in shequ affairs, especially politics and governance.130 Another study
conducted in a coastal area city cited the lack of a direct interest relationship as the main
factor contributing to the residents’ low level of enthusiasm for participating in residents’
committee elections.131 Numerous other studies point to the similar pattern.
129
Men Hongli, “Ni qu guo juweihui ma –dui shequ shenghuozhong juweihui zuoyong de diaocha (Have You been to
the Residents’ Committee –An Investigation of the Role of Residents’ Committee in Community Life)” Shequ
(Community), 8 (2007), pg. 12.
130
Hu Yongqin, “Heilongjiangsheng chengshi shequ jumin canyu wenti yanjiu (A Study of the Problems of
Participation by Urban Community Residents in Heilongjiang)” Haerbin shiwei dangxiao xuebao (Journal of Harbin
Committee School of the CCP) 52:4 (2007), pg. 42.
131
Chen Yu, “Chengshi shequ juweihui xuanju jumin canyu shixiao de diaocha shikao (Investigation and Thought on
the Effects of Residents’ Participation in Elections of Community Residents’ Committees) Guangdong xingzheng
xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Guangdong Institute of Public Administration) 18:4 (2006), pg. 37; see also Wu Wei,
86
On the other hand, due to the sensitivity and higher risk associated with urbanbased political challenge, political experimentations in the cities also tend to be more
tightly controlled and cautious.132 In short, there are obstacles to shequ democratic
development that are usually not present in village democratization.
Nevertheless, democracy in shequs enjoys several advantages in comparison to
village democracy. First, similar to what Huntington notes as the “demonstration effect”
in his Third Wave, in which “people in the follow-on society … [learn] ... the techniques
and the methods used to bring about the earlier democratizations,”133 shequ democracy
can also learn from the mistakes, lessons and institutional innovations of village
democracy. The residents’ self-governance charter (jumin zizhi zhangcheng), the practice
of disclosure and openness concerning public affairs by residents’ committees (juwu
gongkai), and the democratic mechanisms used to resolve the potential conflict between
the residents’ committee and the shequ party organization are some of the key democratic
institutions introduced to the urban shequs that can be traced back to village practices
resulting from their experiences in improving democratic governance. The demonstration
effect can also been seen in residents’ committee elections. Many techniques to improve
the democratic character of a residents’ committee election derive directly from villages’
electoral experiences, such as opening the nomination process to ordinary residents, a
“primary” election to winnow down the number of candidates appearing on the ballot, the
“Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi canyu buzhu de yuanyin yu duice (The Reasons of and Counter-Measures for
the Low Level of Participation in Residents’ Self-Governance in Urban Communities)” Fujian xingzheng xueyuan
Fujian jingji guanli ganbu xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Fujian Institute of Administration and Fujian Institute of
Economics and Management) 3 (2004), pg. 34.
132
Li Fan, “Zhongguo dalu chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu fazhan beijing”, pg. 36-45.
133
Samuel P. Huntington, The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century, Norman and London:
University of Oklahoma Press (1991), pg. 101.
87
roving ballot box,134 secret ballot, the open counting of ballots, etc.135 Lessons are also
learned from the mistakes and problems in rural elections. In the short history of
implementing urban shequ elections, some researchers have found surprisingly that it is
not necessarily the more developed cities (such as Shanghai or Beijing) that are at the
forefront of establishing democratic electoral institutions. Rather, it is areas (such as the
small and middle town-level cities in the far poorer province of Guangxi) with a
somewhat stronger rural character that have tended to be more innovative and
progressive. Indeed, the more developed cities only picked up their pace of democratizing
residents’ committee elections later.136
A second advantage that urban elections have is that urban residents tend to be
more educated, more exposed to the effects of modernization, and to have more
interaction with the external world. Classical modernization theorists would argue that
urban residents should, therefore, have a stronger social foundation for democratic
politics. As a result, once urban shequ elections are fully implemented, although they
started later than village, their campaign and vote-canvassing activities, candidates’
speeches and debates, use of legally available channels for political advertisement and
promotion, should surpass the standards reached by their rural counterparts.137
134
The roving ballot box is not considered to be a very democratic voting method because it can be easily manipulated
and misused, and indeed is being strongly criticized for its negative impact in rural elections. Nonetheless, urban
election committees probably still regard this as a good method for it provides voting opportunities to the handicapped
and elderly people who have difficulties being present at the voting stations.
135
Zhang Tao, Wang Xiangmin, Chen Wenxin, Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju yanjiu (A Study of Direct
Elections in Grassroots Urban China), Chongqin: Chongqin chubanshe (2008), pg. 187-188.
136
Zhang, Wang & Chen, Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju yanjiu, pg. 186-187; see also Li Fan, “Zhongguo
chengshi shequ juweihui zhijie xuanju gaige de qidong: 1998-2003 (Introducing Direct Election Reform in China’s
Urban Communities: 1998-2003), in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige (Direct Election Reform in China’s
Urban Communities), edited by Li Fan, Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe (2003), pg. 6-7.
137
Li Fan, “Zhongguo dalu chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu fazhan beijing (The Background to the Development of
Grassroots Democracy in China's Urban Communities)” Zhongguo chengshi jiceng minzhu yanjiu (A Study of
Grassroots Democracy in the Cities of Mainland China), edited by Shin-min Chu, Taipei: Yuanjin jijinhui (2004), pg.
41.
88
Third, with the shequ jianshe policy now being promoted by the government and
the continuing reform of the danwei system, shequs will increasingly become more and
more important in residents’ social and economic life, and they would become more
motivated to participate in elections of the residents’ committee. Meanwhile, the attention
of civil affairs officials at different levels of government in recent years has shifted from
village democratization, which presumably is well-established, to democratization in
urban shequs.
Fourth, there is a greater resistance at town/township level of authorities in the
countryside to further village democratization because so much is at stake. The town
government still relies on the villagers’ committee to extract rural resources, so there is a
stronger will to exert control over and interfere in village democracy. In the cities, there
is also some resistance to grassroots democratization by the street office, largely because
of concerns for administrative necessity or efficiency. Otherwise, there is no other strong
incentive for the street office to exert strong control over shequ democracy.138
Conclusion
This chapter focuses on the theoretical background of shequ democratization and
its relationship with village democratization. I discuss the meaning of shequ selfgovernance, especially within the context of the relationship between the street office and
the residents’ committee. The thought of Peng Zhen is also an important theoretical
foundation for shequ self-governance. There are three main causes of shequ
democratization. The first is the socio-economic changes in the cities, in which more and
more urban residents are demanding a say in how their neighborhoods are governed. The
138
Luo Feng, “Jiceng minzhu cong xiangcun dao chengshi (Grassroots Democracy from Countryside to Cities)”
Tansuo yu zhengming (Exploration and Free Views) 4 (2001), pg. 23.
89
second is the government’s calculation of the benefits of legitimacy and stability. With
stronger democratic foundation, the ruling party expects to be rewarded with higher
legitimacy for the regime and greater social stability. The third is the impact of village
democracy. The legitimizing and stabilizing effects of village democratization lead to the
greater confidence among officials that similar effects could also result from shequ
democratization.
Nevertheless, there are some obstacles in urban shequ democratization. In contrast
to villages, urban residents generally do not have much interest to participate in residents’
committee elections. But there are also some advantages too. Shequ democratization can
learn from the experiences, techniques, innovations, mistakes and lessons of village
democratization. Urban residents are generally more educated. The government has
increasingly paid more attention to shequ democratization. Finally, the resistance to
democratization by the street office is lower in comparison to the town or township
government in the rural areas.
90
Chapter 4: Institutionalizing and Reforming Elections in Shequ139
Among the four official democratic institutions (election, decision-making,
management, and supervision), democratic election is generally regarded as the
foundational one.140 Many pilot sites selected by Ministry of Civil Affairs for shequ
jianshe initially did not focus much on electoral reforms, but instead attempted to build
up “democratic management” and “democratic supervision” as the way of building up
“democratic politics.” However, without democratic elections being firmly established,
without the residents having at least some control over the personnel of the organization
(the residents’ committee) that is supposed to represent and articulate their interests,
experiences showed that the other three elements of shequ democratic governance could
easily become hollow and “democratic” participation by residents was not sustainable.141
In China, different laws govern different types of election. A national election
law142 governs the national and local people’s congresses elections. The 1987 Villagers’
Committee Law governs village elections and the 1989 Residents’ Committee Law
governs residents’ committee elections. Throughout this chapter I will, when it is
139
Within a shequ, there are several major organizations in which elections take place: the residents’ committee,
residents’ small groups, the leadership of the shequ party organization, and homeowners’ associations. But when we
speak of shequ elections we mainly and generally refer to the elections of members of the residents’ committee, since
the residents’ committee is the principal shequ organization responsible for shequ self-governance.
140
Li Fan, “Zhongguo chengshi shequ juweihui zhijie xuanju gaige de qidong: 1998-2003 (Introducing Direct Election
Reform in China’s Urban Communities: 1998-2003),” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige (Direct
Election Reform in China’s Urban Communities), edited by Li Fan, Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe (2003), pg. 15. See
also “Quanguo renda changweihui zhifa jianchazhu guanyu jianche ‘Zhonghua renmin gongheguo chengshi jumin
weiyuanhui zuzhifa’ shishi qingkuang de baogao (A Report on the Implementation of the ‘Organic Law of the Urban
Residents’ Committee Law’ by the Law Implementation Inspection Team of the Standing Committee of the Ninth
National Peoples’ Congress)” in Jiujie quanguo renda changweihui zhifa jiancha baogao huibian (Compilation of
Reports of Law Implementation Inspection by the Standing Committee of the National Peoples’ Congress), Bejing:
Zhongguo minzhu yu fazhi chubanshe (2003), pg. 627.
141
Li Fan (ed.) Zhongguo xuanju zhidu gaige (Reform of the Electoral System in China) Shanghai: Shanghai jiaotong
daxue chubanshe (2005), pg. 43.
142
The full title of this law is The Election Law of the National People’s Congress and Local People’s Congresses of
the People’s Republic of China. There is also an Organic Law of the Local People’s Congress and Local People’s
Government of the Peoples’ Republic of China, enacted in 1979 and amended several times, that supplements the
Election Law regarding the elections of local people’s congresses. Since it is cumbersome to cite the full title, I will
basically refer them as the national election law.
91
necessary, discuss the national election law and villagers’ committee law. Although
residents’ committee elections are not governed by these laws, they are significantly
influenced by them. In designing or reforming electoral system for the residents’
committee, many local officials in fact do look at how elections are carried out in
people’s congress elections and village elections, and try to copy and improve from these
electoral ideas and practices.
In this chapter, I will first discuss the evolution of the official view toward
election. This section is not about residents’ committee elections per se but it provides the
overall context and historical background and gives us an understanding of the general
political meaning of election in China. I will then proceed to discuss ten aspects and
issues in residents’ committee elections. In the last section I will briefly discuss an
election rule formulated by the Ministry of Civil Affairs.
4.1 Evolution of the Official View of Election:
The views on and practices of elections in China had changed considerably from
time to time. Today, elections are widely and officially accepted in China today as the
key institution that embodies democracy. However, in earlier periods the Chinese
communists had a very different conceptualization of elections. In the following section I
will discuss the Marxist influences, the early practices of elections, the general
conception of elections in China today, and how it differs from the western conception.
4.1.1 Marxist Influences
For many years, the attitudes toward election by the Chinese communists were
influenced by the Marxian conception that elections, as part of the superstructure, have a
class nature; that democratic-parliamentary institutions (including elections) were merely
92
the “bourgeois” tools of class oppression and subjugation. As Lenin once paraphrased
Marx, “to decide once every few years which member of the ruling class is to
misrepresent the people in parliament is the real essence of bourgeois
parliamentarism.”143 Engels was equally critical of “the modern representative state,”
which accordingly is nothing more than “an instrument for exploiting wage labor by
capital” and “an organization for the protection of the possessing class against the nonpossessing class.” The possessing class “rules directly by means of universal suffrage. As
long as the oppressed class [the proletariat] is not yet ripe for its self-liberation, so long
will, it in its majority, recognize the existing order of society as the only possible one and
remain politically the tail of the capitalist class, its extreme left wing.”144
However, it would be simplistic to assume Marx and Engels did not see the
“internal contradiction” of these “bourgeois” political institutions. Marx recognized that
“bourgeois” constitution also “deprives the bourgeoisie, the class whose old social power
it sanctions, of the political guarantee of this power. It imposes on the political rule of the
bourgeoisie democratic conditions which constantly help its enemies toward victory and
endanger the very basis of bourgeois society.”145 Engels, immediately following the quote
above, writes
But in the measure in which it matures toward its self-emancipation, in the same
measure it constitutes itself as its own party and votes for its own representatives,
not those of the capitalists. Universal suffrage is thus the gauge of the maturity of
the working class. It cannot and never will be anything more in the modern state;
but that is enough. On the day when the thermometer of universal suffrage shows
143
Annotated note quoting Lenin in Karl Marx, The Civil War in France, New York, NY: International Publishers
(1940), pg. 93. Marx’s original passage is on page 59.
144
Friedrich Engels, The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State, New York, NY: Penguin Books (1985),
pg. 210-211.
145
Karl Marx, Political Writings, Volume II: Surveys from Exile, edited by David Fernbach, New York, NY: Random
House (1973), pg. 71.
93
boiling point among the workers, they as well as the capitalists will know where
they stand.146
Furthermore, socialist system also embraces genuine, democratic elections to
embody the democratic character of such system. In describing the Paris Commune, the
only form of “proletarian state” realized and highly praised by Marx, he wrote that “the
Commune was formed of the municipal councilors, chosen by universal suffrage in the
various wards of the town, responsible and revocable at short terms,” “the magistrates
and judges (of the Commune government) were to be elective, responsible and
revocable,” each delegate of the rural commune to the National Delegation in Paris was
“to be at any time revocable and bound by the mandat imperatif (formal instructions) of
his constituents” and finally, “nothing could be more foreign to the spirit of the
Commune than to supersede universal suffrage by hierarchic investiture.”147
The theoretical legacy of Marxism thus provides ammunition to opposing camps
of implementing democratic election reforms in China. Although Marxism no longer
serves as an important guide in the party’s formulation of policies, it could still
strengthen the legitimacy of new policies. Party conservatives cite Marx’ hostility toward
“bourgeois” institutions as proof that these are tools to subvert “the dictatorship of the
proletariat,” whereas democratically inclined reformers cite Marx’s other passages to
push for democratic and electoral reforms.
4.1.2 Practices of Election by the Chinese Communist Party: from the Revolutionary Era
to the Present
In 1933, the Chinese communist leader Mao Zedong wrote in a work report:
146
147
Engels, The Origin of the Family, pg. 211-212.
Marx, The Civil War in France, pg. 57-59. Italicized by the present author.
94
The forces of counter-revolution fight vehemently against the revolutionary forces
for the purpose of protecting their own political power. The masses of workers
and peasants in the soviet area have successfully wrested control of this political
power. We have to safeguard this political power all the time and develop it,
therefore making it able to attack the counter-revolutionary forces to the best of
its abilities and to improve the welfare of the workers and peasants. In order to
fulfill these tasks, we must use elections to elect the most progressive and active
people to the soviet, to flush out the useless people from the past. This is the most
important task.148
And later, he wrote:
We have to be careful of the class composition of the nomination list. Not only do
we have to make sure the appropriate number of workers and peasants are elected
according to the election law, we have also to adhere to the directive to ensure at
least 25% of the working women candidates are elected. We should pay attention
to political performance [of the candidates]. We must ensure that those who are
corrupt and lazy, and those who have compromised with the landlords, rich
peasants and capitalists, are not elected. Those elected must have correct view
and good work performance.149
The above passages by Mao illustrate that for a long time the communist
revolutionaries treated election as an instrument of class mobilization, rather than valued
it intrinsically as an essential component of a democratic polity. A 1951 speech by Liu
Shaoqi, the then vice president and later president of China, illustrated the highly
instrumental view on election. He argued that the struggle for universal and equal
suffrage and anonymous ballot made sense under the dictatorial and reactionary KMT
regime. But now under the rule of “peoples’ democratic dictatorship” led by the
communists, implementing these institutional guarantees for the procedural fairness of
elections was no longer a priority. In fact, these institutional rules were merely
“formality” that would hinder the real, substantial and enthusiastic participation of the
148
Cited in Wang Ying, Xinminzhu zhuyi geming shiqi xuanju zhidu yanjiu (A Study of the Electoral System during the
New Democratic Revolutionary Era), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe (2005), pg. 52. Present author’s
italicization.
149
Cited in ibid, pg. 57. Present author’s italicization.
95
mass.150 The first election law of the People’s Republic was promulgated in 1953.
Reflecting the views toward election among Chinese leaders at that time, the law
contained several flaws, such as limited suffrage with class background restrictions, no
guarantee of anonymous ballots, and limited nomination rights.151
The 1953 “Directive by the Central Election Commission on Base-Level Election
Work” is an important document with long-lasting influence. This document first
established the principle of “corresponding” elections (deng’e xuanju),152 which was
subsequently to be widely practiced throughout China and became an essential
component of the system of nomenclature of the communist party during the Maoist era.
Another principle from this document that left an enduring impact on China’s electoral
practices was the requirement of high voter-turnout rate.153 The Chinese obsession of
obtaining high turnout rate reflects the logic that “socialist” political system is more
democratic than the “bourgeois” election, which generally has lower turnout rate and
therefore is supposedly less reflective of the will of the people and more reflective of the
dominance of the ruling class and the interests allied with this class. High turnout rate
thus becomes an indicator for “more democracy”154 under the “peoples’ democratic
dictatorship”.
150
See Cai Dingjian, “Xin Zhongguo xuanju zhidu de lishi yu xianzhuang (The History and Current Condition of the
Electoral System of New China)” in Zhongguo xuanju zhuangkuang baogao (A Report on the Situation of Elections in
China), edited by Cai Dingjian, Beijing: Falu chubanshe (2002), pg. 3.
151
Ibid, pg. 5-6.
152
“Corresponding election” means that the number of candidate corresponds to the number of elective post, thus in
effect an election without choice. See Appendix 4.1 for the use of this translation.
153
Zhang Tao, Wang Xiangmin, Chen Wenxin, Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju yanjiu (A Study of Direct
Elections in Grassroots Urban China), Chongqin: Chongqin chubanshe (2008), pg. 107-109.
154
Wang Tiemin, “Xuanmin xuanju xinli he xingwei de diaocha fenxi (Investigation and Analysis of Voters’
Psychology and Behavior)” in Zhongguo xuanju zhuangkuang baogao (A Report on the Situation of Elections in
China), edited by Cai Dingjian, Beijing: Falu chubanshe (2002), pg. 156.
96
In 1979, the National Peoples’ Congress promulgated a new election law to
replace the 1953 election law. Under the 1979 law, “unreformed landlords”, “antirevolutionaries”, and “convicted criminals”, hitherto the three categories of people
stripped of the voting right, were replaced by a single category “people stripped of
political right in accordance to law” (yifa buodo zhengzhi quanli de ren).155 Direct
elections are to be held at the county level’s people congresses. “Differential” elections
(cha’e xuanju)156 were introduced, and anonymous voting should be the standard voting
process. Nomination was open to individual suggestions, primary elections were
introduced, and some campaign activities were now allowed. As a result of the 1979
election law, in 1980, China witnessed several unusually democratic and competitive
elections, especially in constituencies that included college campuses, which attracted
domestic and foreign attention. Some of the student candidates later became prominent
intellectuals supportive of the Tiananmen movement in 1989.157 The authorities were
wary of these competitive elections being too “far ahead of the time” and placed certain
restrictions in the 1982 amendment to the 1979 law. Subsequent amendments in 1986,
1995 and 2004 also removed a number of these restrictions (not all), and in general
signaled the attempt to improve the democratic character of the law, albeit in cautious
steps.158
4.1.3 Contemporary Views on Elections
155
Zhang Tao, et al, Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju yanjiu, pg. 113.
“Differential election” refers to the election in which the number of candidate exceeds the number of contested
positions. See Appendix 4.1 for the use of this term.
157
For the 1980 elections and the students’ involvement, see Andrew Nathan, Chinese Democracy, New York, NY:
Alfred Knopf (1985), pg. 193-223.
158
Pu Xingzu (ed.) Zhonghua renming gongheguo zhengzhi zhidu (The Political System of the Peoples’ Republic of
China) Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2005), pg. 153-155. See also Cai Dingjian, “Xin Zhongguo xuanju
zhidu de lishi yu xianzhuang,” pg. 8-31.
156
97
Contemporary discourses on election are generally much more appreciative of the
Western writings as well. The conception of the class nature of elections is much less
accepted today among officials and scholars.159 They now tend to see elections as having
universal and general, rather than class, nature, and as the embodiment of a genuinely
democratic system. An authoritative Chinese textbook on the government and politics of
China asserts that “elections are…associated with democratic politics. The essence of
democratic politics is to reflect and carry out the ‘common will of the people’ (quanti
renmin de gongtong yizhi)…Voters must vote in a way that fully expresses their
preference…without which the election will become meaningless.”160 The 2005 State
Council’s White Paper on democracy in China does not have a separate section on
election, however maintains that the National People’s Congress and the local people’s
congresses, whose members are elected, are “responsible to the people and subject to
their supervision.”161
However, the White Paper also states that “the [Chinese Communist Party’s]
leadership and rule is an objective requirement of the country’s development and
progress.”162 Thus, embracing democratic elections within a political system in which
there can be no alternation of the ruling party seems to be illogical and self-defeating in
the eyes of the critics of the Chinese political system, and can be easily dismissed as mere
propaganda. Mainstream Western political science will also not recognize an election as
sufficiently democratic if it restricts the “organized contestation” of different political
159
This statement might seem contradicting to my earlier argument about Marxist influences. But Marx and Engels also
talk about elections being more than “tools of the bourgeoisie”, thus warrant the pro-reform officials and scholars to
justify the argument that elections could be “class-neutral” while not contradicting what Marx had said.
160
Pu Xingzu, Zhonghua renming gongheguo zhengzhi zhidu, pg. 149.
161
“China’s 2005 White Paper: ‘Building of Political Democracy in China’,” Asian Affairs: An American Review 33:1
(2006), pg. 9.
162
Ibid, pg. 7.
98
organizations. Underpinning this emphasis on organized political contestation (thus the
importance of political opposition in a democracy) is the political theory of pluralism.
The logic of pluralism conceives that society is by nature diverse and filled with different
interests, which inevitably lead to the formation of political organizations articulating and
aggregating these different interests, resulting in a multiparty system. The fundamental
function of a democratic election is to provide a neutral platform for different interest
groupings (aggregated into political parties) to contest fairly in the game of democracy
governed by well-established procedural rules, rather than the ability of elections to serve
as a mechanism to express the common will of the people.163
Chinese scholars and officials could easily dismiss as merely “Western” concerns
that do not affect the way “democratic elections” are interpreted and carried out in China
with “Chinese characteristics.” Nevertheless, the importance of procedures in securing a
“free, fair and democratic election” is being increasingly recognized by the Chinese
academia and policymakers alike. The report of the 16th party congress emphasized the
“institutionalization, standardization, and proceduralization” of “socialist democratic
politics.” There have been some serious efforts by the government to improve the
electoral rules and procedures in order to reduce and prevent electoral manipulations and
abuses by local officials. A robust procedural democracy is recognized to be able to
strengthen the orderliness and predictability of politics, and to restrain the excesses in the
name of substantive democracy.164 Universal suffrage, one-person-one-vote with more-
163
Robert Dahl, Polyarchy: Opposition and Participation, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press (1971). Although
western political science has many traditions, Robert Dahl undoubtedly remains the most influential democratic
theorist, and his pluralism remains the mainstream paradigm in understanding concepts such as election and
democracy.
164
Ban Baosheng, “Chengxu minzhu de hanyi, tezheng he gongneng (The Meaning, Features and Functions of
Procedural Democracy),” Heilongjiang shehui kexue (Heilongjiang Social Sciences) 6 (2006), pg. 145, 147.
99
or-less equal weighting of the vote, direct election, differential election, and secret ballot
are the general principles of election that are nominally and generally accepted (but not
universally practiced) in today’s China.165
Chinese officials and scholars also argue that competitive and democratic
elections can be accommodated in a one-party system, in spite of the fact that such
political contestation will not come from organized opposition forces. For example, an
influential Central Party School scholar argues that a party can offer multiple candidates
in an election, and this can be as competitive as a multiparty-election:
Although the presence of multiple parties implies multiple candidates in an
election, but the presence of multiple candidates does not inevitably mean the
presence of multiple parties. One party can field several candidates.
He also argues,
The leadership of the party (dangde lingdao) and the people being in the masters
in their own country (renmin dangjia zuozhu –a generic Chinese term for
democracy) are not irreconcilable… In the history of political parties…the parties
have always performed the functions of training political leaders, recommending
these political elite to the public, and convincing the public to choose qualified
politicians. In fact, political parties have always influenced, and frequently
determined, the people’s choice of political leaders. However, there is also a clear
limit of this influence, in which the political power of a party can never grow so
large to replace the people’s right to choose.166
4.1.4 “One-Party Competitive Election” and Multiparty Election
This “one-party competitive election” hence has a very different logic from the
theory of political pluralism. The Chinese leaders today acknowledge the increasing
diversity of their society. They allow and legitimize the formation of many formal or
165
Pu Xingzu (ed.) Zhonghua renming gongheguo zhengzhi zhidu), pg. 155-160; Cui Guoqiang, Zhou Jing, “Dui
woguo xuanju zhidu yuanze de shikao (Thoughts about the Principles of Election in China),” Renda yanjiu (People’s
Congress Study) 1 (2003), pg. 17-20.
166
Wang Changjiang, “Zhengque renshi xuanju: meiyou xuanjiu, jiumeiyou minzhu (Correctly learning elections:
Without elections, there is no democracy),” in Zhongguo jiceng minzhu fazhan baogao 2006/2007(A Report on the
Grassroots Democracy in China 2006/2007), edited by Li Fan, Beijing: Zhishi chanquan chubanshe (2007), pg. 146,
148-149.
100
informal groups and associations representing different societal interests and sectors. But
this does not mean that they accept the logic of interest pluralism in the political system.
The party has coped with this increased societal plurality by expanding its social base to
encompass and to co-opt more interests (such as the discourse of “three represents” that
justifies and permits individual capitalist-entrepreneurs joining the communist party), not
by opening up the political system to allow other political organizations representing
different social strata and interests to emerge.167 The Leninist party logic dictates that
theoretically speaking, the party can only articulate the interests of the working class and
its allied classes. The party thus has had re-define class workers as including members of
the middle-class, entrepreneurs, professionals and intellectuals, who are called “workers
in the era of information and knowledge economy.”168 In such a way, it precludes the
emergence of any other political organization from claiming to represent the interests of
these classes.
Thus, the logic of one-party competitive elections means that in general,
candidates compete on a platform that highlight their skills, competence, access to
resources, abilities, viewpoints, and personalities. Sometimes they may want to
emphasize in their campaign that there are some issues they want to resolve once elected,
and that these issues tend to affect certain groups in the society. They will not, at least not
ostensibly, compete based on rival political programs that reflect articulations of different
167
Zheng Yongnian, “Interest Representation and the Transformation of the Chinese Communist Party,” in Bringing
the Party Back In: How China is Governed, edited by Kjeld Erik Brodsgaard & Zheng Yongnian, Singapore: Eastern
Universities Press (2004), pg. 269-301.
168
Guo Daohui, “Cong gemingdang dao zhizheng dang: lun zhongguo congchandang de dangjian yu zhizheng
guannian de yushi jujin (From Revolutionary Party to Governing Party: On the Progressive Adaptation of Party
Building and Governing Ideals of the Chinese Communist Party),” in Fazhi yu dang de zhizheng fangshi yanjiu (The
Rule of Law and Studies of the Governing Methods of the Party), edited by Zhang Hengshan et al., Beijing: Zhongguo
falu chubanshe (2004), pg. 98.
101
interests in the society. In a one-party competitive election, the competitive campaigns by
the competing candidates basically focus on different ways to achieve a set of more or
less similar policy goals, rather than focus on systematically different policy goals.
This model of “one-party competitive elections” governed by fair electoral
principles and rules thus seems to be clearest type of “democratic election” that the
Chinese political leadership is willing to offer in the foreseeable future. The Western
liberal mode of multiparty election would reject this model as insufficiently
“democratic.” But China does not have to follow the models and theories of liberal
democracy in formulating a model of election that it deems to be more fitting to its
present political-economic-social configurations. Furthermore, even if we are to assert
that this model is essentially not democratic and should only be viewed as a stepping
stone toward the truly democratic multiparty election, this does not prevent its usefulness
to serve as an ideal to improve the quality and standards of the many types of elections in
China.
First, if we apply the principle of “external critique”, which uses international
standards as bases of evaluation, the general principles of elections in China today are
basically also universally accepted as the minimum standards of democratic elections.
The willingness to embrace these principles should be taken as a positive sign to make
the electoral process in China more democratic. The detailed electoral rules and
procedures could then be evaluated based on the criteria of whether they could achieve
the standards set by these general principles. The effectiveness of the “one-party”
electoral system could in several aspects also be evaluated on the basis of international
standards. For example, if one of the universal and primary goals of election is to secure
102
the “vertical accountability of the rulers to the ruled,”169 the “one-party competitive
election” could also be evaluated based on its effectiveness in ensuring that individual
leaders (but not the ruling party as a whole) are accountable to the electorate.170
Second, if we apply the principle of “internal critique” in which a society judges
itself by its own standards,171 then elections in China can also be measured against a set
of standards that are not “imposed by Westerners” but are acceptable in the official
discourse in China. Genuine implementation of, and adherence to, these electoral
principles, rules and procedures can be used as the basis to evaluate the democratic
quality of elections in China.
4.2 The Conduct of Shequ Elections: Issues and Reforms
Shequ residents’ committee elections exhibit a strong localized character:
Different provinces, cities, districts, street offices, and even different shequ within the
jurisdiction of the same street office have different designs of residents’ committee
elections. In comparison to its rural counterpart, the 1989 Residents’ Committee Law is
notably deficient in terms of provisions governing electoral conduct. The 1998 Villagers’
Committee Law contains 6 articles (Articles 11 to 16) on elections, specifying such
election rules and procedures as direct and differential election, anonymous ballot and
open counting of votes, the organization and functions of the election committee, open
169
Larry Diamond, Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press
(1999), pg. 10.
170
“One-party competitive elections” is not a unique Chinese invention. Tanzania under the rule of TANU had a
similar system, in which unpopular but powerful incumbents and party leaders were actually voted out of office,
showing the ability to secure vertical accountability of this system of “one-party competitive election”. See William
Tordoff, “Tanzania: Democracy and the One-Party State,” Government and Opposition, 2:4 (1967), pg. 605; John
Samoff, “Single-Party Competitive Elections in Tanzania,” in Elections in Independent Africa, edited by Fred M.
Hayward, Boulder, CO: Westview Press (1987), pg. 151.
171
The idea of using “external critique” and “internal critique” to evaluate government performance in China comes
from Suzanne Ogden, “Governance in China,” in China in the Twenty-first Century: Challenges and Opportunities,
edited by Shiping Hua and Sujian Guo, New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan (2007), pg.57-58.
103
nomination by voters, and the voters’ recall process. Although universal compliance of
all these provisions in all of China’s villages is hard to verify, at least the law is clear
about what is permissible. Violations by rural officials can now be appealed by villagers
with legal protection and may result in legal sanctions.
By contrast, the Residents’ Committee Law, contains only one article (Article 8).
It stipulates the terms of office of the committee members, the methods of residents’
committee election, and residents’ qualifications as voters. The lack of legal clarification
means that each level of the government is able to clarify (and thereby design) the
electoral process and system for its residents’ committees (see Figure 4.1),172 sometimes
with genuine institutional innovations and reforms to improve the procedural fairness and
democratic quality of the elections, but sometimes also with loopholes or ambiguity for
local officials (especially street level) to manipulate the electoral process.
In the following sections I will discuss ten aspects or issues in the elections of
shequ residents’ committees in China: The functions and organization of the election
committee, the mode of election (indirect vs. direct), elections of residents’
representatives and leaders of residents’ small groups, suffrage, voters’ registration,
nomination, corresponding vs. differential election, regulation of campaign activities, the
secret ballot, and residents’ recall right. I select these issues not only because they are
crucial in the efforts to improve, institutionalize and democratize the shequ election
process, but also because they could be evaluated and reformed in accordance with the
accepted general principles of election in China. Through an analysis of these issues, we
172
Despite being a unitary state, Chinese governance is actually quite decentralized. Some scholars argue that China in
fact practices de facto federalism. See Yongnian Zheng, “Explaining the Sources of de facto Federalism in China:
Intergovernmental Decentralization, Globalization, and Central-Local Relations” Japanese Journal of Political
Science, 7:2 (2006), pg. 101-126.
104
will see how the model of “one-party competitive elections” operates, and look at the
ways in which the Chinese are thinking to improve it.
4.2.1 Pre-Election Phase: Organizing Election and the Election Committee
The preparatory work of shequ residents’ committee elections usually involves
officials at the higher levels. At both the city and district levels, “shequ election work
leadership small groups” (or groups with a similar name) are established in preparing for
upcoming residents’ committee elections. The group generally includes officials from
departments of civil affairs and public security, people’s congress deputies, and the
party’s organization and propaganda officials. The civil affairs officials usually are the
main coordinating officials, but nominally the group is led by important party and
government leaders (such as district mayor or district party secretary).173 The major
functions of the small group are to draw up implementation measures and general rules of
elections and to provide ideological and political “direction.” As repeatedly emphasized
in official discourse, grassroots elections could become too “unorganized” and “anarchic”
without the supervision and leadership from the party and government.174
At the street office level, the “shequ election work guidance small group” is in
charge of several more specific responsibilities. For instance, the main tasks of the streetlevel election small group in Beijing include drafting a working plan and implementation
measures for shequ elections, publicizing the relevant laws and election rules, setting up
173
The organization of the group thus can be summarized as “dangwei lingdao (leadership of the party committee),
renda jiandu (supervision by people’s congress), zhengfu shishi (implementation by government), minzheng yunzuo
(operation by civil affairs), bumen peihe (cooperation by departments).” See Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui
xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of Election Work of Community Residents’ Committee)
Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 110.
174
See, for example, “Shenyangshi Hepingqu 202 Yiyuan shequ zhijie xuanju gongzuo baogao (Report on the Election
Work of 202 Yiyuan Community in Heping District, Shenyang),” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige
(Direct Election Reform in China’s Urban Communities), edited by Li Fan, Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe (2003), pg.
320.
105
an election date, training election workers, and receiving petitions and complaints
relating to shequ elections.175 The responsibilities of street-level election small groups
reported elsewhere are basically the same.
Presiding over the implementation of elections at the shequ level is the shequ
election committee.176 The election committee consists of 9 to 11 members. In general,
many functions and responsibilities of the shequ election committee overlap with those of
the street-level election group. But the shequ election committee is generally also
assigned the responsibilities for registering voters, examining candidates’ speech,
convening meetings between candidates and residents, and designing and printing ballot
papers. Some of them are actively involved in the nomination process.177 In all the
election documents that I have read, the relationship between the street-level election
small group and the shequ election committee is generally left unspecified, summarized
in one ambiguous word: zhidao (guidance). Such ambiguity tends to make it easier for
the street-level election group to dominate the shequ election committee.
The residents’ committee law also does not stipulate how the election committee
is organized. Without legal standardization, the composition of shequ election committee
and the way committee members are selected vary considerably from place to place.
4.2.1A Composition of the Election Committee
175
“Beijingshi jumin weiyuanhui xuanju gongzuo guicheng (shixing) Procedure of Residents’ Committee Election
Work of Beijing (Trial)” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s Community Construction Yearbook 2003),
Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 149.
176
Sometimes this committee is also called “the shequ election leading small group.” However, to maintain uniformity
I will use the terms election committee or shequ election committee throughout this project, unless otherwise noted.
177
See the election documents collected in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 339-417. An exception is
the election measures of Wuming Town in Guangxi, which provides clear differentiation of the functions and
responsibilities between shequ election committee and the election small groups at the upper levels of government. On
the election committee’s role in the nomination process, see the discussion in the section “Nomination” below.
106
A Ministry of Civil Affairs handbook proposes that the election committee should
consist of members of the outgoing residents’ committee, leaders of residents’ small
groups, and residents’ representatives.178 Nevertheless, this is not an authoritative or
binding policy. Strong party presence and domination in the election committee is in fact
more common in many shequ.179 The election implementation plan of a city in the
province of Guangxi states that potential candidates of the shequ election committee have
to come from the party, traditional “mass groups” such as communist youth league and
women’s association, and residents’ representatives.180 The election implementation plan
for a shequ in Beijing specifies that the election committee consists of cadres sent from
the street office, retired members of residents’ committee, and some volunteers.181
In a Guangzhou shequ, the entire election committee is staffed by a local NGO.182
In the Haishu district in the city of Ningbo, the shequ election office (as it is called in this
district) is staffed by community workers recruited by the street office. Representatives
from danweis stationed in the shequ, community police officers (shequ minjing),
delegates of property management companies and homeowners’ committees, and eminent
persons within shequ are also reportedly selected as members of the election committee.
Sometimes members of residents’ committee of the expiring term also are also drawn
178
Wang Zhenyao, Bai Yihua (ed.) Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe (The Work of Street Office and the
Construction of Residents’ Committee), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (1996), pg. 208.
179
Yong Gui, Joseph Y.S. Cheng & Weihong Ma, “Cultivation of Grassroots Democracy: A Study of Direct Elections
of Residents Committees in Shanghai,” China Information 20:1 (2006), pg. 20-22. A report on Shanghai shequ
elections in 2003 notes that all shequ election committees were chaired by party secretaries. See Zhan Chengfu, Shequ
juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 85
180
“Guangxi Wumingxian shequ jumin weiyuanhui xuanju zanxing banfa (Trial Measures of Community Residents’
Committee Elections in Wuming Town, Guangxi),” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 385.
181
“Beijingshi Bajiao jiedao Yuanbei juweihui zhixuan gongzuo fangan (Implementation Plan of Direct Election for
Yuanbei Residents’ Committee in Bajiao Street in Beijing),” in ibid, pg. 377.
182
He Yanling, “Gongtong xingdong de dacheng he shequ guangxi geju de chonggou (Accomplishment of Common
Actions and Re-organization of Community Relational Structure),” in ibid, pg. 100.
107
into the shequ election committee, despite obvious conflicts of interests when members
of the residents’ committee are re-running for another term.
4.2.1B Selecting Members of the Election Committee
Another issue is how members of the election committee are selected. The
Ministry of Civil Affairs identifies several methods of selecting members of the election
committee that are in practice in China: (1) appointment by the residents’ committee, (2)
nomination by the street office and confirmation by the residents’ committee, (3)
discussion and consultation among residents’ small groups, (4) “election” by the
residents’ assembly or by residents’ small groups.183 Among the four methods, “election”
appears to be the “right” way. Perhaps because its rural counterpart, the village election
committee, is stipulated to be “elected” by the villagers’ assembly or villagers’ small
groups in Article 13 of the Villager’s Committee Law, many local election documents in
fact stipulate “election” as the preferred method of selecting the committee members.
There is a reason why I put the quotation marks to cover the word “election” here.
While xuanju is the standard Chinese term for “election,” there is also another Chinese
term tuixian which could be translated as “election” in English. The official English
version of the Villagers’ Committee Law uses “election” in translating the term tuixuan.
In many election documents, when describing the “election” of the election committee,
the word in use is tuixuan. In contrast to xuanju, tuixuan in Chinese language indicates a
more informal, casual, consultative process. The inexact nature of this term thus allows
the authorities (for instances, the shequ party organization, the residents’ committee, or
183
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 4-5.
108
the street office) to play a more directing role in the tuixuan of members of election
committee (see Appendix 4.2 for an account of the tuixuan process).
The issue of reforming the shequ election committee is critical to how shequ
elections can be carried out fairly and impartially. An election committee that is tightly
controlled by the authorities tends to be much more restrictive of democratic competition
and be biased toward certain “preferred” candidates.184 Reforming the institution of the
election committee, however, has not received enough official attention, which tends to
focus on achieving direct election, differential election, and open nomination. This issue
is also not unique to residents’ committee elections; it has its roots in the decentralized
nature of all types of election organizing in China, in which different bodies of local
governments are in charge of organizing different types of election.185 Election
organizing bodies are set up on a temporary basis, making the accumulation of election
expertise and knowledge difficult. They contribute to the lack of consistency and
institutionalization of the whole electoral system. They also tend to dissolve after
elections, making it harder for voters to file appeals or complaints. Because of the
decentralized nature of election organizing, local powerful officials tend to exert great
control and could manipulate the process and outcome if they choose to.
4.2.2 Mode of Election: From Indirect Voting to Direct Voting
The Residents’ Committee Law permits three modes of election: indirect election
in the form of (1) election by residents’ representatives and (2) election by household
representatives, and (3) direct election by all eligible adult residents. Haixuan, or “sea
184
For a vivid example, see the story in Appendix 4.3.
For instances, people’s congresses elections are organized by the officials in the offices of the people’s congresses,
residents’ committee elections and villagers’ committee elections are organized by the civil affairs officials.
185
109
election”, a peculiar mode of election originated from some village experiences, will be
discussed separately in the section on “Nomination” below.
Until today, indirect election by residents’ representatives is still the predominant
mode of residents’ committee elections in most of Chinese cities. This mode of election
is considered deeply flawed. The Washington Post reported in 2000 that these elections
were “highly restricted, dominated by the Communist Party and generally limited to a
few participants.”186 Although they are also nominally “elected” by residents, in practice
it is more likely that residents’ representatives are appointed by the residents’ committee
or the street office (see more discussion below on the “election” of residents’
representatives) in tuixuan type of election. Genuine residents’ involvement in the
“elections” of these representatives, if there are any, is limited to only informal
consultation and confirmation.187 In this mode of election, residents’ representatives tend
to vote for the residents’ committee nominees selected by the authorities. The residents’
committee “election” thus has nothing to do with voters’ choice and participation; instead
it is merely a formality to confirm official selection.188
Indirect election by household representatives is considered more democratic than
indirect election by residents’ representatives. First, this mode of election involves a
larger number of voters (each household will send one representative, compared to one
residents’ representative for several households), increasing the level of direct
186
John Pomfret, “China Tiptoe Toward the Vote: Some Residents, in Some Cities, May Choose from Among Limited
Candidates” The Washington Post February 20, 2000.
187
Thomas Heberer, “Institutional Change and Legitimacy via Urban Elections? People’s Awareness of Elections and
Participation in Urban Neighborhoods (Shequ)” in Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China: Institutional Change
and Stability, edited by Thomas Heberer, and Gunter Schubert, New York, NY: Routledge (2009), pg. 86.
188
Zhou Qinghua, “Shequ zhixuan: jiceng minzhu jianshe de lishixing zai kuayue (Community Direct Elections: The
Historical Leap in Grassroots Democratic Construction”) Qianyan (Forward Position) 5 (2006), pg. 225; Li Hongmei,
“Lun cunmin weiyuanhui xuanju yu jumin weiyuanhui xuanju de qubie yu jingji chengying (On the Differences
between Villagers’ Committee Elections and Residents’ Committee Elections and the Economic Causes)” Honghe
xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Honghe College) 2:3 (2004), pg. 19.
110
participation among the residents. Second, household representatives are selected within
each household. The authorities basically have no control over their selection. Thus,
household representatives also tend to be more autonomous in their voice choice and
reflect better the opinions and preferences of the residents.
Direct election is undoubtedly the most democratic mode out of the three modes
of election. It expands suffrage, increases the level of political participation, and is
consistent with the vision of the “masses taking care of their own affairs” in a “socialist
democracy.” Direct election is also stipulated as the only mode of election in the
Villagers’ Committee Law. Logically, as the comparable organization in the cities, the
residents’ committee should also be directly elected.
According to the data provided by the Ministry of Civil Affairs, around 60% of
the residents’ committees in China held elections in 2004, among them 22% were direct
elections, 29% were indirect elections by household representatives, and 49% were
indirect elections by residents’ representatives.189 This is the most recent data on the
distribution of the use of these three modes of election I am able to obtain.
There is a consensus among scholars and officials alike that indirect election by
residents’ representatives is deficient and should be replaced by the other two modes. The
Ministry of Civil Affairs in a report criticizes the mode of indirect election by residents’
representatives. It points out that many of these representatives were in fact appointed by
street office, and could not in effect claim to “represent” the residents.190 However, there
is some debate about whether to replace this mode with indirect election by household
189
Zhan Chengfu,Shequ jianshe gongzuo jinzhan baogao (A Report on the Progress of the Work of Community
Construction) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 6. For provincial data, see Zhan Chengfu, Shequ
juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao), pg. 13-15.
190
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 24.
111
representatives or with direct election. The arguments for and against these two modes
are presented below.
4.2.2A Arguments against Direct Election and for Indirect Election by Household
Representatives
Many officials at the street-office level are not happy to implement direct
elections. The most common objections are (1) direct election could result in social and
political instability, (2) the high costs of implementing direct election, and (3) residents
are not interested in direct election.191
Some officials have expressed concerns that “unlawful elements” could use the
opportunity offered by direct election to consolidate their position (as in the case in some
villages in which black societies and clan organizations become more entrenched and
dominant after elections). They are also worried that residents could turn against the
street office when they are unsatisfied with some local issues (such as land expropriation
for development projects and pollution).192
On the other hand, the Ministry of Civil Affairs also recognizes that election costs
and the lack of institutionalized funding for elections are critical problems impeding the
introduction of direct election.193 Table 4.1 provides some data on average election costs,
ranging from a few thousand yuan to as high as 50,000 yuan per residents’ committee
election. As indirect election switches to direct election, it is generally assumed that
191
In his study of shequ elections in three Chinese cities, Thomas Heberer reports that among the reasons given by
those officials who were against the implementation of direct elections were “low interest among residents” (27.3%),
“lack of material conditions” (18.2%), “situation could get out of control” (18.2%), “too complicated” (13.6%), among
others. See Thomas Heberer, “Institutional Change and Legitimacy via Urban Elections? People’s Awareness of
Elections and Participation in Urban Neighborhoods (Shequ),” in Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China:
Institutional Change and Stability, pg. 95.
192
Guo Bo, “Shequ Zhixuan xuyao jiejue de jige wenti (Several Issues of Community Direct Election that need to be
Taken Care of),” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 113.
193
Zheng Quan, “Shequ juweihui xuanju huodong de xianzhuang, wenti ji duice (The Present Situation, Problems, and
Countermeasures of Community Residents’ Committee Elections)” Shequ (Community) 7 (2006), pg. 36.
112
election expenses also increase. As the number of participants in an election increases,
expenses covering election materials (ballot papers and ballot boxes), publicity materials,
remunerations and compensation (such as food and gifts) to election workers also
increase.194 Since Chinese officials generally are obsessed in the attainment of high voter
turnout rate, a direct election will multiply the resources needed to mobilize and persuade
all the eligible voters to vote in order to obtain a high turnout rate.195 Many shequ also
hand out small souvenirs as material incentives to voters.196 Direct election, in short, is
too costly to implement on a wide scale.
But the strongest official argument against direct election is simply that residents
are not interested. For these officials, despite doing their best to mobilize the residents,
the general lack of interest among residents197 could still result in their failure to obtain
high voter turnout rate. In the eyes of their superiors, this failure could imply (1) their
weak mobilization capacity, and (2) they enjoy low public support. This in turn could
dampen their bureaucratic career and interests. In short, direct election is considered a
“risk” in the sense that these officials have to get the job (implementing direct election)
done and done well, but not necessary considered a serious “threat”, as in the case among
rural town and township officials who oppose village direct elections in which the control
over vital interests and resources is at stake.
This official argument is not necessary unfounded. When Shanghai began its
shequ election reforms in 1999, a poll was conducted to ask the residents of these pilot
194
Heberer, “Institutional Change,” pg. 94.
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 112.
196
The first major direct and competitive shequ election in Beijing, the Jiudaowan election in 2002, cost a staggering
amount of 100,000 yuan. If all of Beijing’s approximate 1,000 shequs were to conduct direct elections, the election
costs for the whole city was calculated as more than a hundred million yuan. See “Gei shequ xuanmin suan yibizhang
(Calculating the Costs of Community Election)” in Shequ (Community) 11-22 (2002), pg. 8.
197
I have discussed some of the factors causing this lack of interest in Chapter 3.
195
113
sites to decide which mode of election was their preference. Overwhelmingly they opted
for indirect election by residents’ representatives.198
In those cases in which direct elections are implemented, studies show that there
is widespread apathy among the electorate toward the elections. The party and
government had to spend a considerable amount of efforts and energy to mobilize the
residents to participate in the elections. Therefore, residents’ demand for greater shequ
self-governance and democracy, to a certain extent, is overblown by optimistic media
portrayal and unfounded analysis. The implication for democracy of shequ direct
elections, these studies conclude, was unsubstantial.199
Official arguments against expansion of direct elections are thus not necessarily
based on the ground that democracy is intrinsically undesirable, but that conditions are
not yet ripe for greater democracy. Residents, in short, should develop stronger ties with
their shequ before they have the interest and civic-mindedness to participate in the
elections and activities of the residents’ committee. Indirect election by household
representatives is therefore recommended as a more feasible and logical next step, rather
than the unrealistic “great leap” of direct elections at the present moment.200
4.2.2B Arguments against Indirect Election by Household Representatives and For
Direct Election
198
Lin Shangli (eds), Shequ minzhu yu shili: anli yanjiu (Community Democracy and Governance: Case Studies)
Beijing: Shehui kexue wenxian chubanshe (2003), pg. 73-74.
199
Gui et al, “Cultivation of Grassroots Democracy”; Gui Yong, “Linli zhengzhi: chengshi jiceng de quanli caozuo
celue yu guojia-shehui de zhanlian moshi (Neighborhood Politics: Power Manipulation Tactics and the AdhesiveConnective Model of State and Society in Urban Grassroots)” Shehui (Society), 6 (2007), 102-126; Tu Longke,
“Shanghaishi S jiedao jiceng shequ zhijie xuanju de diaocha (An Investigation into the Community Grassroots Direct
Elections in the S Street of Shanghai)” Huadong ligong daxue xuebao (Journal of East China University of Science and
Technology), 3 (2005), pg. 14-18; Gui Yong et al. “Zhixuan: shi shehui ziben kaifa haishi xingzheng tuixiao minzhu
(Direct Election: Utilization of Social Capital or Official Promotion of Democracy)?” Shanghai chengshi guanli zhiye
jishu xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Shanghai Polytechnic College Urban Management) 6 (2003), 22-25.
200
Zhang Xiaogan, “Quanmian tuijin zhequ zhixuan weishi shangzao (It is Still Early to Comprehensively Promote
Direct Elections in Communities), Zhonguo shehui bao April 22, 2004.; see also Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju
gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 113.
114
Unsurprisingly, the above view is contested by the promoters of direct election.
First, indirect election by household representatives still does not fully reflect the will of
the residents. If differences of opinion are present within a household, then there is bound
to be dissenting voice inside the household being suppressed.201
Furthermore, residents’ lack of interests in shequ affairs and in residents’
committee elections could also be the effect, rather than the cause, of an indirect electoral
system that fails to vigorously engage with and involve the residents. Some scholars also
point out that this pattern of disinterestedness is not necessarily universal in China.
Residents in cities that have experienced painful bankruptcies or massive layoffs by
danweis are generally eager to participate in residents’ committee elections. In some
small and mid-size cities in which there are fewer dominating danwei but more migrant
workers, residents are also found to be genuinely enthusiastic in shequ elections.202
The cost argument is flawed to a certain extent as well. While it is true that costs
of direct election in certain shequ were quite high, the benefits that come with direct
election should not be ignore. With direct election also come greater legitimacy,
accountability, responsibility and transparency of the work of residents’ committee. This
could generate the confidence, trust, support, and the “social capital” of the residents.
Some Chinese scholars argue that there is an inverse relationship between the level of
shequ self-organization (social capital) and the costs of direct election. As the level of
social capital increases, the costs of direct election decrease.203 Also, as direct elections
201
Li Fan, “Zhongguo chengshi shequ juweihui zhijie xuanju gaige de qidong: 1998-2003,” pg. 10.
Ibid, pg. 25-36.
203
Chen Weidong & Wu Meng, “Shequ zizuzhi yu zhixuan chengben (Community Self-Organization and Costs of
Direct Election)” Dangdai shehui shijie shehui zhuyi wenti (Issues of Contemporary World Socialism) 2 (2005), pg. 1118.
202
115
become routinized, the material incentives offered to residents will become unnecessary,
lowering the costs of direct election.204
The Ministry of Civil Affairs has in recent years been supportive of direct
election. In a recent report the Ministry acknowledges that those shequ that have
implemented direct election have had far fewer cases of receiving voters’ complaints and
petition than those shequ that continue to use indirect election by residents’
representatives.205 In 2008, the Ministry officially set a target in which by 2010, at least
50% of all shequ elections shall be direct elections.206
4.2.3 Electing Residents’ Representatives and Leaders of Residents’ Small Groups
On the organizational chart (Figure 2.1), the shequ residents’ committee is the
lowest level of administration. But below this level, there is yet another level: An
informal, flexible level consisting of residents’ small groups, the equivalent of villagers’
small groups in the countryside.207 Residents’ small groups are established generally on
the basis of residential blocks. A residents’ small group covers about 20 to 50
households, but sometimes it could be as large as 100 households. There are no official
duties of these residents’ small groups. They mainly help organize and mobilize residents
for a variety of activities, help implement policies, and convey residents’ opinions and
demands to the residents’ committee or other relevant authorities.208
204
Zhou Hongling, “Chengshi shequ zhixuan nengbuneng tuguang (Can Community Direct Elections be Promoted)?”
Zhongguo shehuibao August 31, 2002; see also Xiong Chunmao, “Juweihui xuanju wei shequ guanli gouzu lige pingtai
(Residents’ Community Elections Establish Six Platforms for Community Management)” Zhongguo shehuibao
December 2, 2004.
205
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 24.
206
Li Huizhi et al., “Minzhengbu: chengshi shequ zhixuan fugaimian 2010 nianqian jiangda 50% (Ministry of Civil
Affairs: Direct Elections for Urban Community Residents’ Committee to Expand to 50% before 2010)” Zhongguo
gaigebao August 5, 2008.
207
The villagers’ small groups are established on the basis of “natural village” (ziran cun), which then form the larger
“administrative village” (xingzheng cun) that the villagers’ committee governs.
208
Wang & Bai, Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe, pg. 229.
116
4.2.3A Network of Activists: Block Leaders, Group Leaders, Residents’ Representatives
Each small group has a leader (or sometimes a leader and a deputy leader). The
leader is either directly “elected” by the eligible residents, or by the household
representatives. A large residents’ small group might cover more than one residential
block. Each block will also have to “elect” a “block leader.” Typically a group leader is
also a block leader. In a smaller residents’ small group, in which it covers only one
residential block, the block leader and the group leader is typically the same person.
Collectively they are referred to “louzuzhang” (block and group leaders) in China.
The small group meets once or twice a month. The meeting is attended by
household representatives, block leaders, or any other interested residents and activists
(again, there is no institutionalization of these small group meetings). Each small group is
also responsible for “electing” 2 to 3 residents’ representatives (or 4 to 5 representatives
for larger small groups), usually through a vote by show of hands or discussion in a small
group meeting. In this sense, residents’ small groups are also akin to small electoral
districts in a shequ, and the residents’ representatives akin to the representatives of these
electoral districts. Typically the small group leader is one of the representatives, though
this is not always the case. The term of office for the representatives is same with the
term of office for members of the residents’ committee. The “elections” of the leaders of
residents’ small groups and residents representatives generally precede residents’
committee election. The “elections” tend to be the informal tuixuan process (see
Appendix 4.2).209 Block leaders, residents’ small group leaders, and residents’
209
In Lin Shangli & Ma Yili, Shequ zuzhi yu juweihui jianshe, Shanghai shequ jianshe yanjiu baogao chongshu zhiqi
(Community Organization and Residents’ Committee Construction, Volume 7 of Shanghai Community Development
Report Series), Shanghai: Shanghai daxue chubanshe (2000), pg. 190.
117
representatives form an informal, but critically important, network of shequ activists
(shequ jiji fenzi). In the administration of the shequ, the role played by these activists is
significant (see Appendix 4.4).
The reason to discuss these activists in the context of residents’ committee
election is that a significant number of these activists (residents’ representatives and
group leaders) are themselves in the elected positions as well. For residents’ committees
that are still elected indirectly by residents’ representatives, improving the election of
these representatives could be the first step of making these elections more democratic.
Even if all residents’ committees are to adopt the mode of direct election, residents’
representatives are still important. They are the participants in the residents’
representatives’ assembly (jumin daibiao huiyi), an important decision-making body in
shequ.
The informal tuixuan process therefore is inadequate to guarantee the democratic
election of these representatives. There is, however, very little attention paid to the
reform of the elections of residents’ representatives and small group leaders. Almost all
of the documents on residents’ committee election stipulate the tuixuan process, with the
Beijing shequ election regulation as the only exception.210
4.2.4 Suffrage in Shequ Elections
Article 8 of the Residents’ Committee Law stipulates that “any resident of a
residential area who has reached the age of 18 shall have the right to elect and stand for
election, regardless of his ethnic status, race, sex, occupation, family background,
religious belief, education, property status and length of residence, with the exception of
210
For example, see the laws collected in Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 207,
212, 237, 244; for the Beijing document, see pg. 350-352.
118
persons who have been deprived of political rights in accordance with the law.”
Nevertheless, in practice, the right to vote is not as straight forward as it seems. The
voting right of three groups of people sometimes generate some controversies. They are:
(1) the danwei people, (2) migrant workers, and (3) foreign nationals.
4.2.4A The Danwei People
The first issue is the voting right of the so-called “danwei people in shequ” (shequ
li de danweiren), meaning the employees of danwei (work units) stationed inside the
shequ. This issue has generated some controversies and lawsuits. In 2003, in a residents’
committee election in Wuhan,211 the election committee pushed for the voting right of the
danwei people, but was later accused of doing so to serve the purpose of the residents’
committee members who were running for another term.212 In 2006, a lawsuit was
brought against a shequ election committee in the city of Yiwu. The election committee
denied voting rights to 11 persons. Their voting rights were disqualified on the grounds
that they were employees of the danwei in the shequ, despite the fact that these
employees were also at the same time registered residents of this shequ. The court ruled
in favor of the plaintiff, restoring the voting rights of these 11 persons, on the grounds of
their residence status. This does not necessarily indicate the affirmation of the voting
right of the danwei people.213
There is no standard policy of whether danwei people should have the right to
participate in residents’ committee elections. In many shequs, danwei leaders are usually
211
The same residents’ committee in the story of Appendix 4.3.
Liu Zhichang, Chen Weidong, “Danwei ren buyi xiangyou xuanjuquan: Wuhan shequ zhixuan gean fenxi (Unit
People Should Not Have Suffrage: A Case Analysis of a Community Election in Wuhan)” Shequ (Community), 12-24
(2004), pg. 18-19.
213
Jia Huiwen, “Xuanjuquan zenneng shuiyi boduo (Voting Rights cannot be Removed Arbitrarily)” Jinhua shibao
May 24, 2006.
212
119
invited to send representatives to various meetings. The Ministry of Civil Affairs also
encourages danwei participation in shequ jianshe.214 If the participation of danwei in
shequ jianshe (community construction) is essential for its success, then giving the
danwei people the voting rights could be justified. Opponents, however, argue that giving
voting right to the danwei people would violate the principle of “one person, one vote.”
Since the danwei employees are also residents of their own shequ and would also
participate in the shequ elections in their own residential areas, giving them voting right
in the shequ in which they work would have made them vote twice.215
4.2.4B Migrant Workers
The second issue is about the voting right of the migrant workers. Although the
household registration system (hukou or huji) has been relaxed in recent years, it is still
quite restrictive, especially toward the people with rural registration who are working in
cities. Basically, a person (including professional-expatriates) without the official
household registration of his/her present living place will face a lot of difficulties to be
recognized as an official resident of that place. This limits his/her access to certain
benefits, and in shequ elections, the rights to vote and stand for elections.
Urbanites tend to view migrant workers with disdain. They perceive these
workers as uneducated, uncultured and feudalistic who cause rising crimes and other
problems in their neighborhoods. Urban residents thus quite strongly object to giving
214
The 2000 Ministry of Civil Affairs document states that “government organs, mass organizations, troop units,
enterprises, service units and other [danweis] [should be mobilized] to participate in shequ jianshe and to [share] shequ
resources, thus bringing forward the good environment of shequ ‘co-station and co-construction’ (gongzhu gongjian)”
See “Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijing chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian (Opinion of the Ministry of Civil
Affairs on Promoting Community Construction Nationwide” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s
Community Construction Yearbook 2003), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 136.
215
Liu Zhichang, Chen Weidong, “Danwei ren buyi xiangyou xuanjuquan: Wuhan shequ zhixuan gean fenxi (Unit
People Should Not Have Suffrage: A Case Analysis of a Community Election in Wuhan)” Shequ (Community), 12-24
(2004), pg. 18-19.
120
voting rights to migrant workers. On the other hand, the presence of a large number of
migrant workers is also inevitable in many big and developing cities.216 In many shequ,
the “migrant” workers have actually settled down, purchased property and maintained a
stable job. They are as “urban” as other residents except their registration. Regulation and
management of migrant workers are also often cited as key reason for the shequ jianshe
policy. Excluding the electoral participation of migrant workers thus contradicts the
purpose of shequ jianshe and shequ democracy.
Thus, most shequ do give migrant workers the voting rights, but with certain
qualifications. Length of residency requirement is the most common one. More
controversial ones are the rules that would require these people to provide evidence that
they have a valid and stable income, and have purchased property in the shequ they are
living in. A migrant worker also has to secure a written statement from the villagers’
committee where he/she is registered. The statement testifies that the concerned person is
no longer a voter in his/her original villagers’ committee, so as to prevent the situation in
which a migrant worker could vote in his/her hometown village and in the shequ he/she is
living in.217
4.2.4C Foreign Nationals
There are some shequ in China in which there is a large presence of foreign
nationals (with long-term residency), who are also an integral part of the neighborhood.
The question then is whether these foreign nationals have the right to vote and stand for
216
For instance, more than half of the people in Shenzhen, one of the largest cities in China, do not hold Shenzhen
household registration.
217
Zhang Fang, “Cong ‘Jiang Shan shijian’ kan Shenzhen shequ juweihui xuanju xuanmin zige de wenti (Looking at
the Problem of Voter’s Qualification in Shenzhen Community Residents’ Committee Elections from the ‘Jiang Shan
Incident’) in Zhongguo jiceng minzhu fazhan baogao 2005 (A Report on the Grassroots Democracy in China 2005),
edited by Li Fan, Beijing: Zhishi chanquan chubanshe (2006), pg. 247-248.
121
residents’ committee elections. One opinion is that since the residents’ committee is not
strictly a state or governmental organization, and since foreign nationals are a significant
part of the shequ they live in, they should be included in the electorate. Including foreign
nationals in the residents’ committee and having them participated in elections serve to
facilitate cooperation between Chinese and foreign nationals and to enlarge the social
basis of the authority of the residents’ committee. In a shequ in Shanghai, not only do
foreign nationals have the voting right, but some of them actually stood for and won
elections.218
The opposing view point argues that although the residents’ committee is not
strictly a state or governmental organization, it has nevertheless always served political
and policy purposes. Therefore, its election should be open only to Chinese citizens. This
was the reason cited to deny the voting rights of overseas Chinese with foreign
citizenship (despite their long-term residency and significant community contribution) in
a shequ election in Guangzhou.219
The essence of these issues is the interpretation of the nature of the residents’
committee and the Residents’ Committee Law. Some scholars argue that since the
residents’ committee is essentially mass self-governance organization, its election is
therefore fundamentally different from elections of state institutions. Its election is more
akin to elections in a social organization (for example, a lawyers’ association), in which
case members of the organization are free to participate in other elections. The “one
218
Liu Bo, “Waiji jumin ruxuan juweihui de xuanju luoji yu shequ zhengzhi kongjian zhuanhuan (The Electoral Logic
and Transformation of Community Political Space the in the Election of Foreign Citizens into the Residents’
Committee)” Shehui kexue (Journal of Social Sciences) 7 (2007), pg. 124-131.
219
He Yanling, “Gongtong xingdong de dacheng he shequ guangxi geju de chonggou (Accomplishment of Common
Actions and Re-organization of Community Relational Structure)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg.
101
122
person, one vote” principle thus is not applicable.220 Following this interpretation, the
danwei people, migrant workers, and foreign nationals should all be given the voting
rights.
On the other hand, neither citizenship, nor household registration nor
employment, are established as the basis of voting rights in the Residents’ Committee
law. The only condition is residency. A strict interpretation of Article 8 of the Law will
dismiss the voting right of the danwei people on the one hand, and affirm the voting right
of migrant workers and even foreign nationals on the other hand. The property and
income qualifications imposed on migrant workers are also clearly against the text and
spirit of the law, and are in fact illegal.
Although it does not receive much attention as a serious issue in the reform of the
electoral process, the issue of voting right is nonetheless important. Especially for the
migrant workers, securing them the voting right would be the necessary first step to
guarantee their equal citizenship rights with urban residents. The long-term implication
could be even an overhaul of the problematic household registration system. In this case,
the present Residents’ Committee Law is quite adequate since the voting right is
established on the basis of residence, not household registration. The problem, of course,
is the imposition of property or income qualifications on the migrant workers by the local
governments.
4.2.5 Voters’ Registration
Like suffrage, voters’ registration appears to be a rather straightforward and noncontroversial issue. After all, it is a universal practice to register voters in order to
220
Zhang Fang, “Cong ‘Jiang Shan shijian’ kan Shenzhen shequ juweihui xuanju xuanmin zige de wenti,” pg. 250.
123
differentiate those who possess suffrage from those who do not, to ensure each voter
receives only one ballot paper in elections, and to prevent voters from voting in
constituencies other than their own. Both the Villagers’ Committee law and the
Residents’ Committee law mention nothing about voters’ registration. The national
election law ascertains those who have voting rights shall be registered, but it is vague in
terms of how they should be registered. In residents’ committee elections, they are two
principal methods: dengji xuanmin and xuanmin dengji.
4.2.5A Dengji Xuanmin
The prevalent practice in shequ elections in China is “dengji xuanmin”
(registering voters), in which the election committee takes a pro-active role in the process
of registering voters. Typically, the election committee first compiles a list of voters
based on the household registration (huji) book kept by the shequ residents’ committee.
The next step is the tiresome process of verifying the voters in each household on the list,
usually through repeated visits in person to these households by members of the election
committee, election workers, and shequ activists.221 Residents whose political rights are
restricted and not yet restored (such as prisoners who are just released) or with mental
illness will be removed from the voters’ roll, while those who qualify but have not been
included will now be added to the roll.222
4.2.5B Xuanmin Dengji
221
Li Xiuqin, “Jiamenkou de minzhu (Democracy outside of Home)” Shequ (Community), 8-15 (2003), pg. 21.
Tang Zhengfang, “You shui zaihu shequ zhixuan? (Who Care About Community Direct Elections?)” Shequ
(Community) 8-16 (2004), pg. 13.
222
124
Some shequ elections also began to experiment with another practice of
registering voters –xuanmin dengji (voters’ registration).223 Xuanmin dengji simply
means that non-registered residents should voluntarily register with the election
committee to be on the voters’ roll. Because it requires the residents to take the initiative
to ascertain their voting rights, xuanmin dengji is thought to be a better method that can
raise residents’ awareness of democratic rights. Those who fail to register in a sense
exercise their democratic right by choosing not to become voters. Residents who take the
initiative to register tend to pay more attention to the procedure, candidates and issues of
the elections. In contrast, under dengji xuanmin, residents as political actors are more
passive. Their voting rights are imposed from above (obligation) rather than ascertained
through their own initiative (right). Voters registered under dengji xuanmin tend to be
passively mobilized during elections.
In 2000, Pudong New District in Shanghai experimented with xuanmin dengji in
some residents’ committee elections.224 This is probably the earliest reported cases of
xuanmin dengji. Under the advice of some foreign election experts (including experts
from the Carter Center), the city of Nanning in Guangxi province became the first city to
implement xuanmin dengji on large scale in its shequ elections in 2004.225 Another city
that has focused on xuanmin dengji in reforming residents’ committee elections is Xi’an.
A poll conducted among Xi’an residents in 2006 shocked the city officials in which 40%
of the residents reported no knowledge of who were their residents’ committee chairs.
223
It might appear that the two terms (dengji xuanmin and xuanmin dengji, or literal English translations
“registering voters” and “voters’ registration”) are unnecessary semantics referring to the same thing,
especially for general readers who are unfamiliar with the different meaning of the terms.
224
“2000nian Pudong xinqu juweihui xuanju gongzuo zongjie (Concluding the Election Work of Pudong New
District’s Residents’ Committee in 2000)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 244.
225
Tang Zhengfang, “You shui zaihu shequ zhixuan?” pg. 12-14.
125
After some considerations and analysis, the city civil affairs officials decided to promote
xuanmin dengji, rather than direct election, in the coming shequ elections in 2007.
Reportedly 50% of all shequ were to use xuanmin dengji and 10% would go for direct
election.226 Xuanmin dengji, for some election reformers, could be the tentative first step
toward the more democratic mode of direct election.
Xuanmin dengji is not without problems. From the perspective of local
government officials, the main worry is too few residents care to register. Failure to
secure a high turnout rate, as mentioned before, is perceived to be damaging to their
bureaucratic career. Another potential downside of xuanmin dengji is that with voluntary
registration, only those activists (and their family and friends) will be drawn into
participating elections. Governance of shequ affairs will then be dominated by a group of
shequ activists rather than having a majority of the residents engaged in a democratic
process.227 Dengji xuanmin, although a much more cumbersome process, is more reliable
to secure higher voter turnout rate. It requires more work, but it posts lower risk. Thus,
many officials are still uneasy about the use and implementation of xuanmin dengji.
Some shequ experimented with the combination of both methods. For instance, in
a 2004 shequ election in the city of Wuxi, the election committee prepared a three-phase
registration process. The first phase was voluntary registration by the residents (xuanmin
dengji). The second phase was the traditional dengji xuanmin, in which election workers
would go door-to-door to register the unregistered residents. The final phase is “makeup” registration. Those who failed to register (or be registered) during the first two phases
226
Yang Binglong, “Xuanmin ziyuan dengji: ‘bi’ chulai de chuangxin (Voters’ Voluntary Registration: A ‘Forced’
Innovation” Zhongguo shehui bao October 30, 2007.
227
Tang Zhengfang, “You shui zaihu shequ zhixuan?” pg. 14.
126
could register during this phase, and do so voluntarily. The first phase drew 36.1% of the
eligible residents to register as voters. This indicates a substantial portion of the residents
who were interested in the election and took the initiative to ascertain their democratic
rights. Interestingly, this number was actually higher than the number in the second phase
(27.7%). However, if the registration process ended just after this phase, this election
would be an invalid one, because this would mean that less then 50% of the eligible
voters (36.1%) would cast their vote –a violation of the standard “50%” election rule in
China.228 The second phase (dengji xuanmin) therefore allowed the election committee to
almost double the number of registered voters (eventually after all phases 70.9% of all
eligible residents registered as voters).229 This combination approach is considered by
some to be appropriate for the current stage of development of shequ elections in
China.230 It is able to let residents to ascertain their democratic rights (the main virtue of
xuanmin dengji) while at the same time avoid the risk of low participation (the main
virtue of dengji xuanmin). Hence, it could be regarded as a good option for those local
government officials who want to proceed at a more cautious pace.
4.2.6 Nomination: Qualifications, Preliminary Candidates and Formal Candidates
The nomination process has been one of the major areas of election reforms in
many residents’ committees. There are three issues regarding the nomination process: (1)
nominees’ qualifications; (2) nomination of preliminary candidates, and (3) determination
of formal candidates.
4.2.6A Nominee’s Qualifications
228
About the 50% rule, I will discuss more about it in the section of “Protecting the Secret Vote” below.
Yin Donghua, “Shequ zhixuan de chengxu yanlian (The Procedural Practices of Community Direct Election) Shequ
(Community) 11-21 (2004), pg. 8-9.
230
Wang Hua, “Woguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju tanjiu (Inquiry into Urban Community Direct Elections in
China)” Sichuan xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Sichuan Administration College) 4 (2008), pg. 47.
229
127
Traditionally, the residents’ committee is staffed mostly by women. Today it is
still a major platform for women’s participation in politics.231 However, this image of
residents’ committees being run by old nannies with little education tends to discourage
capable people from considering running for residents’ committee elections. The
Ministry of Civil Affairs has made recruitment of young, capable and energetic people an
important foundation for the success of the shequ jianshe policy. In order to increase the
overall quality of residents’ committee members, many local governments have instituted
certain regulations regarding nominees’ qualifications, the most common being age
qualification (nominees have to be below the age of 55) and education (at least a college
degree). They also reserve the authority to disqualify nominees who fail to meet such
qualifications.
These qualification requirements do have the real effect of making residents’
committee members younger and more educated. However, these qualification
requirements are by nature discriminatory and have actually violated Article 8 of the
Residents’ Committee law.232 Many old and experienced residents’ committee members
are forced to retire. Despite their senior age and low level of education, many of these old
members have been immersed in their residential neighborhoods for years. They are also
dedicated to and enthusiastic about their work. Their disqualification thus also is a loss of
some genuinely capable people to run shequ residents’ committees.
4.2.6B Nomination of Preliminary Candidates
231
Yang Qiaoli, “Shequ juweihui –funu canzheng de zhongyao wutai (Community Residents’ Committee –an
Important Platform for Women’s Participation in Politics)” Zhongguo funubao, September 23, 2003. As noted in “the
State of Shequ Jianshe” in Chapter 2, more than half of the residents’ committee members are women. All the
residents’ committee members that I interviewed, except one, are women in their mid-forties or fifties.
232
Yan Xiguang, “Shequ xuanju ying huanquan yu jumin (Community Elections Should Return Powers to Residents)”
Shequ (Community) 1 (2005), pg. 19.
128
In Chinese elections (including village elections and local peoples’ congress
elections), the nomination process generally involves two sub-processes –the nomination
of preliminary candidates, and the determination of the final candidates from the list of
preliminary candidates. The Residents’ Committee Law again does not stipulate any
regulations about the nomination process, thus different localities have used different
nomination methods. Here I will discuss the first sub-process (nomination of preliminary
candidates).
Traditionally, nomination is not open. Only organizational nomination (by the
party, the street office, the residents’ committee, the election committee, or other “mass
organizations”) is accepted. Residents’ opinions sometimes are solicited and considered,
but otherwise they tend to play only insignificant role in the preliminary nomination
process.233 Reforming this sub-process has been focused on giving residents the right to
nominate. Similar to the three modes of election, several modes of residents’ nomination
have also been proposed, such as nomination by residents’ representatives/residents’
small groups, nomination by household representatives, and residents’ direct nomination.
Two common methods of resident’s direct nomination are self-nomination seconded by
fellow residents and joint nomination by a group of residents/voters (usually 10). There is
also a type of nomination called “sea election” which I will discuss later in this section.
Giving residents’ nomination rights, however, do not mean that organizational
nomination is no longer in use. Most election committees accept both organizational
nomination and residents’ nomination. Table 4.2 contains the data collected by the
Ministry of Civil Affairs on the use of different nomination modes and methods during
233
Li Fan, Zhongguo xuanju zhidu gaige, pg. 47.
129
the shequ election cycle in 2003-2004. The data shows that nationally, nomination by
residents’ small groups was the most common mode of nomination used in the 20032004 residents’ committee elections, followed by joint nomination, nomination by the
street office, and self-nomination.234
Many shequ election committees are active in this preliminary nomination
process. As mentioned before, some election committees can nominate candidates. In
some cities the election committee is responsible for accepting and rejecting preliminary
nominees. Even if it is not responsible for nominating, accepting, rejecting candidates, it
could play a “directing” role to ensure the list of preliminary candidates shows adequate
“representation” of different social groups. For example, during a 1999 shequ election in
Shanghai, the election committee felt that there were not enough party members in the
list of preliminary candidates nominated by the residents’ representatives. It therefore
sought to “encourage” or “guide” the nomination of party members by several residents’
representatives who had not yet decided.235
Unsurprisingly, those nominees on organizational tickets are understood to be the
“official” candidates in elections, and tend to be the formal candidates in the second subprocess. Nominees on organizational tickets generally come from three types of
background: (1) residents’ committee member of the current term, (2) cadres arranged or
sent by the street office to work in shequ, and (3) recruits from the public through a
policy known as jiepin minxuan (the street office hires, the residents elect) or xuanpin
234
Apparently the Ministry relied on information provided by provincial or local authorities in compiling
the data (some numbers are quite specific and others are general; the 100% joint nomination by voters in
Tibet was basically unverifiable, and the 100% nomination by residents’ small groups in Beijing
contradicts the known facts that some Beijing shequ have experimented with more direct nomination by
residents). This data is therefore not totally reliable. Nevertheless, it still demonstrates the diverse
nomination methods used in different localities.
235
Lin & Ma, Shequ zuzhi yu juweihui jianshe, pg. 198.
130
heyi (unity of electing and hiring). This policy is an institutional innovation in shequ
elections that has no counterpart in village elections. In the subsection following the
discussion on determination of formal candidates, I will present a more in-depth
discussion on this policy of jiepin minxuan.
4.2.6C Determination of Formal Candidates
In general, all types of election in China require an officially approved list of
formal candidates, with the number of these candidates being determined by the election
organizing bodies.236 With the opening up of the preliminary nomination to residents, it is
conceivable –in fact it is a common occurrence –that the number of preliminary
candidates exceeds the specific number of formal candidates, thus requiring this subprocess of determination of the formal candidates.
In most sheus this sub-process is done with the so-called “consultative”
(xieshang) method,237 in which several rounds of discussion and consultation between
residents, the authorities and the election committee eventually lead to a final list of
formal candidates. Despite some residents’ participations, the ultimate authority generally
resides in the street office and the election committee. They make sure certain
preliminary nominees will appear on the list of formal candidates (such as party members
and the recruits under jiepin minxuan), and reject preliminary nominees they do not like.
Partly borrowing from village election experiences, some localities have
experimented with a more democratic alternative –a primary election to determine the
236
For instance, Articles 27 and 28 of the national election law state that “the number of candidates for deputies to be
directly elected by the voters shall be from one third to 100 percent greater than the number of deputies to be elected.
Candidates…shall be nominated by the voters in the various electoral districts and by the various political parties and
people’s organizations. The election committee…shall decide, in accordance with the opinion of the majority of voters,
upon a formal list of candidates to be made public five days prior to the date of election.”
237
This is clearly included by the “consultation” process in local peoples’ congress elections. See J. Bruce Jacobs,
“Elections in China” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, 25 (1991), pg. 183-186.
131
formal candidates from the preliminary candidates. Again, three modes of primary
election exist. In this case, the electors could be residents’ representatives, household
representatives, or all eligible residents.
Primary election by residents’ representatives is the predominant mode of primary
election. Guangxi, Ningbo, Wuxi, Shanghai and Shenyang are some of the provinces and
cities that have experimented with primary election by residents’ representatives. An
example of primary election by household representatives is the election of Yousan shequ
in the city of Wuhan. Primary election by all eligible residents is called “sea nomination”
(haitui), an example of which is the election of Chang’er residents’ committee in the city
of Wuhan in 2003.238
The primary election process, however, is not immune from control and
interference, especially if is a primary election by residents’ representatives. An account
of a shequ election in Shanghai is highly informative in this regard. In this election, the
election committee asked the residents’ representatives to each nominate 5 to 9 formal
candidates from a list of 28 preliminary nominees. After tallying the nomination votes,
the first 10 preliminary candidates who obtained most nominations would then be
tentatively considered as formal candidates. However, out of these 10 candidates, 4 of
them declined to stand for election for personal or work reasons. The logical solution for
the election committee would be to take the preliminary candidates on the 11th, 12th and
13th place. But then the election committee discovered that in this case there would not be
enough party members in the list of tentative formal candidates. In the end, it decided two
238
Liu Chongshun, “Wuhanshi Changer shequ juweihui huanjie zhixuan kaocha baogao (A Report on the TermChanging Direct Election to Changer Community Residents’ Committee in Wuhan)” Shehui gongzuo (Journal of
Social Work) 5 (2004), pg. 23-24; Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 156.
132
members of the election committee (also party members) would be included as tentative
formal candidates. The representatives then were asked to determine from this list of
tentative formal candidates the formal candidates through a primary election. The two
candidates added by the election committee were unsurprisingly elected formal
candidates too.239
4.2.6D Jiepin Minxuan/Xuanpin heyi 240
This policy basically means that potential members of residents’ committees are
first recruited and hired by the street office after going through examinations and
interviews (not unlike civil service entrance examinations), before they are subject to
election. The recruits in this case need not be residents from the shequ they are running
for elections. The purpose of this policy is to recruit capable and qualified people from
the general public to run residents’ committees. Qingdao, Tianjin, Shanghai, Beijing,
Changchun, Xi’an and Nanjing are some of the cities known to have adopted jiepin
minxuan. In a shequ election in Nanjing in 2000, all candidates were in fact recruited and
hired by the street office after shequ residents failed to nominate any candidate.241
The 2000 Ministry of Civil Affairs document provides the basis for such a policy.
On the one hand it asserts that members of residents’ committees are elected. On the
other hand it encourages recruitment of capable and qualified people, especially among
college graduates and laid-off employees, to work in shequ through “lawful procedure”
(fading chengxu), which could be interpreted as elections.242 For instance, a Beijing
239
Lin & Ma, Shequ zuzhi yu juweihui jianshe,, pg. 198.
These two terms refer to the same thing, so I will use jiepin minxuan for the rest of this dissertation.
241
Li Fan, “Nanjingshi Baixiaqu Huaihailu jiedao Youfuxiejie shequ xuanju guancha (Observation of the Election in
Youfu xijie Community of Huaihailu Street in Nanjing’s Baixia district) in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju
gaige, pg. 249.
242
“Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijing chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian,” pg. 138.
240
133
policy document states that those who are recruited by the street office will be nominated
as the candidates in residents’ committee elections. After being elected, these recruits will
sign a work contract with the street office. They will also be included in the official
public personnel management system.243 This policy is credited for bringing in talented
people to work in the residents’ committee.244
There is considerable amount of debate about this policy. Jiepin minxuan is
criticized for bringing in recruits who are not the actual residents of the very shequ they
are serving. The residents do not feel close to them. This policy could further alienate
residents’ participation. It also contradicts the efforts to promote residents’ selfgovernance and community identity. Technically, jiepin minxuan is also against the
Residents’ Committee Law since the voting rights (which includes the right to stand for
elections) is established on the basis of residence.
Supporters of jiepin minxuan counter this argument by contending that the idea
that shequ can only be served by their own residents is a rather parochial view. Even
though these recruits may not necessarily be the residents of the shequ, their enthusiasm
and willingness to work for and serve the residents should not be presumed to be less
than the residents themselves. Furthermore, jiepin minxuan allows the street office to
recruit talented people through rigorous training and examination, at the same time also
allows residents to have the final choice in an election. It combines the two basic methods
of selecting officials in a modern government: the merit-based method of civil servant
243
“Beijngshi shequ shiye ganbu guanli zhidao yijian (shixing) [Guiding Opinion of Beijing on Community Cadres
Management (Trial)]” ” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s Community Construction Yearbook 2003),
Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 143.
244
Wu Guimin, “Xuanpin fenli: yichang xuanran xingqi de shequ tizhi gaige (Separation of Hiring and Electing: an
Emerging Reform of the Community System)” Zhongguo shehui bao August 20, 2003.
134
recruitment and the democratic method of electing officials. It thus has the virtues of both
methods.245
Critics again point out this is exactly the problem. They are first recruited and
hired by the street office (jiepin) and then elected by residents (minxuan). This dual
identity creates a conflicting dilemma for these recruits. One recruit asks, “We are
recruited and paid by the street office, how we are not going to listen to them? We are
also elected by the residents. We cannot ignore their interests. Well then, are we only the
employees and “legs” of government, or are we to articulate residents’ interests, to
become the “head” of the residents?”246 Since they are first and foremost hired by the
street office, in general they are more inclined to consider the interests of the street office
first. And since they are recruits of the street office, the street office has strong incentive
to make sure these recruits are elected, even through manipulation. Among the 3270
recruits nominated as formal candidates in the 2003 residents’ committee elections in
Beijing, 3204 of them managed to get elected.247 This high success rate of jiepin minxuan
nonetheless makes people suspicious that the election process was controlled to ensure
their victory.
4.2.6E Sea Election (Haixuan)
There is also a type of residents’ nomination and election called “sea election”.
The most radical type of “sea election” combines nomination and election and involves
245
Xu Yong, Chen Weidong, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Self-Governance in China's Urban Communities),
Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe (2002), pg. 129-132.
246
He Xiaoling, Yang Binglong, Xu Wei, “Jiepin minxuan, hefahu? Helihu? (Street Hires, Resident Elects, Legal?
Reasonable?)” Shequ (Community) 20 (2002), pg. 17; see also Wang Tongxu, “Zai ‘Minxuan jiepin’ zhong zhao zhun
ziji de weizhi (Finding a Correct Position in ‘Resident Elects, Street Hires’)” Shequ (Community) 13 (2006), pg. 27;
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The Residents’
Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee in Urban
Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 175-177.
247
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 68.
135
no candidates at all. All voters are given a blank ballot paper, and on the ballot paper the
voters write down the name of the persons they intend to votes for. Although there are no
formal candidates, persons interested to stand for elections and to promote themselves
can register with the election committee as “contestants” (jingxuanren). After tallying all
the ballots, the persons (might or might not be the “contestants”) who have received the
most votes will then simply be declared the winners of the election. Some districts in the
cities of Nanjing, Changsha, and Tianjin were all reported to have experimented with this
type of shequ “sea election” (or a modified version of it) before.248
The less radical type of “sea election” combines preliminary nomination and
primary election. Similar to the first type, all voters are given a blank ballot paper to write
down the name of any persons they intend to vote for. After tallying the nomination
votes, the persons with the highest nomination votes will then be chosen as the formal
candidates. The nomination of formal candidates in Beijing’s Jiudaowan election in 2002
is similar to this type of primary election.249
In the least radical type, “sea election” will be used for the preliminary
nomination process only. Again, all voters are given a blank ballot paper to write down
the name of the persons they intend to vote for. Any person whose name has appeared on
the ballot paper is considered a preliminary candidate. The determination of final
candidates from the list of preliminary candidates will then be carried out either through
248
Gu Zhaonong, “Tanfang juweihui ‘haixuan’ (Visiting the ‘Sea Election’ of Residents’ Committee)” Renmin ribao,
January 9, 2003; Liu Ping & Peng Ying “Juweihui zhuren shouci ‘haixuan’ (‘Sea Election’ of the Chairperson of
Residents’ Committee for the First Time)” Tianjin ribao, April 3, 2006; Liu Ling, “Jinbaiwan Changsha shimin
zhixuan shequ ‘dangjiaren’ (Nearly a Million Residents of Changsha Directly Elect Community ‘Heads’)” Hunan
ribao, October 26, 2006; Zhang Yirong, et al., “Shequ xuanmin yiren yipiao xuanchu ‘xiaoxiang zongli’ (Community
Residents Elect ‘Lane Primers” with One Person One Vote)” Nanjing ribao May 1, 2006.
249
Zhou Hongling, Zhang Minwei, “Jumin zenyang na xuanpiao quandian dangjiaren (How Residents Vote Their
Leaders)?” Shequ (Community) 9-17 (2002), pg. 9.
136
the traditional consultative approach or through a primary election. The Sifang shequ in
the city of Changsha is known to have used this type of “sea election” during the
preliminary nomination process.250
“Sea election” tends to be confused with direct election, or sometimes is
considered a variant of direct election.251 Although “sea election” and direct election
tends to go together, they are different. “Sea election” in fact can be combined with
indirect election, as have been the case in a 2004 shequ election in Qingdao and some
elections in Nanjing.252 The “voter” in a “sea election” could be any adult resident
(therefore combining “sea election” with direct election), a household representative
(combining “sea election” with indirect election by household representatives), or a
residents’ representative (combining “sea election” with indirect election by residents’
representatives).
The essence of “sea election” is election without formal candidates, or, if applied
at the nomination stages, nomination without the approval of the nominees. “Sea
election” is not without criticisms among election reformers and scholars. “Sea election”
is completely open –the voters can write any names they prefer –so the problem is that it
does not care whether those nominated are willing to serve as residents’ committee
members or not. Some of them would decline to be involved in the election at all.
Sometimes they would feel obliged to serve once they are actually elected, but in a way
that would be unwillingly and unenthusiastically.
250
Zhang Quan & Fen Fa, “Sifang shequ ‘haixuan’ jishi (A Record of “Sea Election” in Shifang Community)” Shequ
(Community) 9-18 (2003), pg. 19-20; Xu Yi & Wan Haihong, “Hunan shouge shequ zhixuan de liyi boyi (Interest
Interactions in the First Community Direct Election in Hunan)” Zhongguo shangbao July 18, 2003.
251
Zhang Hao, “Shilun shequ ‘haixuan’ dui zhengzhi minzhu de tixian (On the Realization of Political Democracy by
Community ‘Sea Elections’)” Shayang shifan gaodeng zhuanke xuexiao xuebao (Journal of Shayang Teachers
College) 3 (2005), pg. 26.
252
Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng, pg. 153.
137
Another problem is that “sea election” tends to favor the incumbents or those who
are already well-known in the shequ, since residents tend to nominate and vote for the
“familiar face.” It is therefore unfair to those who have not yet established a reputation.
The most radical type of “sea election”, in which the preliminary nomination process and
formal nomination process is collapsed into one direct election without candidates, offers
only limited opportunities for the less well-known to promote their name and to
campaign for votes either as preliminary candidates or formal candidates.253
4.2.7 Increasing Electoral Competition: Differential and Corresponding Elections
The meaning and difference between differential (cha’er) and corresponding
(denger) elections have been explained in Box 4.1. For much of the history of Maoist era
corresponding election was the prevalent form. However, since the reform era differential
election has been promoted and incorporated in the national election law and Villagers’
Committee Law.
This does not mean that corresponding election is no longer in use in China. The
elections of principal government officials254 are all corresponding elections. For shequ
elections, the Residents’ Committee Law again mentions nothing about differential or
corresponding elections. Most provincial laws on the residents’ committee permit both
corresponding and differential elections. Corresponding election is permitted generally if
the one of the following conditions occur: 1) after the nomination process, the number of
formal candidates is still the same with the number of elected positions; 2) after
discussion among residents in the residents’ assembly it is agreed that corresponding
253
Wang Hua, Li Fenfa, “Chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zhijie xuanju yanjiu (A Study of Direct Elections of Urban
Community Residents’ Committee)” Xiamen tequ dangxiao xuebao (Journal of the Party School of CPC Xiamen
Municipal Committee) 3 (2008), pg. 35; Li Fan, Zhongguo xuanju zhidu gaige, pg. 148-149.
254
The Chinese president, premier, the provincial governors, mayors, county magistrates, etc. are supposedly “elected”
by the people’s congress at respective levels.
138
election will be used. Among all the provinces, only Shandong and Anhui explicitly state
that elections of the residents’ committee have to be carried out according to the
differential election principle.
4.2.7A “Degree” and “Range” of Differential Election
(To make my discussion clearer, I will use a residents’ committee with five
members, with one of them being the chairperson and another being the vice-chairperson,
as a model). The differential election principle can be applied along two dimensions:
“degree” and “range”.255 The “degree” of differential election refers to whether the
election of each position (chairperson, vice-chairperson, regular committee member) of
the residents’ committee is elected based on the differential principle, or whether only the
position of regular members is subject to differential election. It also refers to whether
each position is voted separately or whether all members of the residents’ committee
elections are voted in one bloc. Thus, a differential election in which each position is
elected separately and differentially has the highest “degree.” A differential election in
which voters simply choose five names out of the six formal candidates on the ballot
paper, without indicating who is going to be the chair, vice-chairperson, and regular
committee member, is a differential election with the lowest “degree.”
The “range” of differential election refers to the number of formal candidates that
is required in order to exceed the number of elected positions. This could be determined
either by a ratio, such as stating that the number of formal candidates shall be 20% or
one-thirds more than the number of elected positions, or by a number, such as stating that
the number of formal candidates shall be 1 or 2 more than the elected positions. The ratio
255
Wang & Bai, Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe, pg. 209-210.
139
or number could also be applied differently: either to all positions combined together (for
example, stating that the number of candidates shall be one more than the number of all
residents’ committee members), or to each position separately (for example, stating that
the number of candidates for the chairpersonship shall exceed the number of chairperson
of the residents’ residents’ committee).
4.2.7B Different Types of Differential Election256
Different combinations of both dimensions give us different possibilities of a
differential election. Figure 4.2 presents the different types of differential elections that
have been used or proposed so far. Under the “single plurality” election, the voters will
vote a bloc of candidates rather than vote for each elected position separately. The two
highest vote receivers become the chairperson and vice-chairperson respectively, and the
lowest vote receiver is therefore voted out, or in Chinese term, is “differenced out” (bei
cha’e). Alternatively, the five elected members could decide on their own who are going
to be the chair and vice-chairperson. An example of this type of differential election is the
Nanjing shequ election in Baixia district in 2000.
A “limited differential” election is a combination of differential and
corresponding elections. The elections of the two leadership positions are corresponding
elections (only one formal candidate for the chairpersonship and one formal candidate for
the vice-chairpersonship), while the elections of the regular membership positions are
differential elections (four candidates contesting for three positions). Xuanwu district in
Nanjing and Luwan district in Shanghai had used this type of differential election before.
256
Unless otherwise noted, the actual examples provided in the following discussion come from my analysis of the
election documents collected in Zhan Chengfu, Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao. Thus, I will not cite
them separately.
140
An alternative “limited differential” election is when it is the leadership positions, rather
than the regular membership positions, that are elected differentially. A modified form of
this type of election was proposed as an experiment for the Beijing’s Jiudaowan election
in 2002, but was never used and I have so far not encountered any actual case of this type
of election.
A “separate voting” differential election means that all three positions are elected
separately and differentially. Under the “transferable separate voting” system, the losing
candidate of the election of the chairperson position will be transferred as a candidate of
the election of the vice-chairpersonship position. The losing candidate of the election of
the vice-chairpersonship will again become a candidate of the elections of the regular
membership position. Shanghai257 and Wuhan had used this type of differential election
before.
Finally, the “nontransferable separate voting system” is actually the most
common type for those shequ that have implemented electoral reforms. In this case, the
election will feature two contestants for each of the two leadership posts (chairperson and
vice-chairperson), and one or two persons more than the number of regular members of
the committee (for example, four candidates for three regular membership positions),
making all positions differential, but without the transferability of the losing candidates.
We can evaluate the competitiveness of these differential electoral systems based
on the two dimensions mentioned above. Assuming that the higher “degree” (each
position elected separately and differentially) and “range” (more formal candidates, thus
allowing residents more choice) of a differential election, the more competitive the
257
Wang et al., Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 140-141.
141
election is, the “simple plurality” election is the least competitive and the
“nontransferable separate voting” system is the most competitive. The “simple plurality”
restricts both the “degree” and “range” of an election, with none of the positions
separately voted at and the number of candidates is only one more than the number of
elected positions. Both “limited differential” electoral systems have a moderate “degree”
of differential elections, with some of the positions (leadership or regular membership)
being contested while others not.
The “degree” of the “transferable separate voting” system is high, with each
position being contested differentially, but the “range” is generally restricted to one more
candidate than the number of elected positions. Finally, the “nontransferable separate
voting” system naturally increases the “degree” and “range” of elections. For a fivemember residents’ committee, it must have at least have 8 formal candidates (2 for each
of the two leadership positions and 4 for the 3 regular membership positions). Table 4.3
summarizes the argument made above. Theoretically speaking, the “range” of each type
of differential election could be enlarged (increasing the number of candidates), but only
the “nontransferable separate voting” system will ensure at least a moderate “range”.
Each of these systems has its strengths and weaknesses. “Simple plurality”
elections provide simplicity and “controllability” from the perspective of the authorities
(meaning higher chance for “official candidates” being elected). The same can be said
about “limited differential” elections without leadership positions. The “nontransferable
separate voting” system appears to be the most “democratic” since is provides more
choices to the residents. However, one criticism against the “nontransferable separate
voting” system is that since the losing candidates will not be able to contest in the next
142
round, this could result in the loss of some talented people eager to serve the residents.
There could be cases in which two equally competent candidates are running for the
chairpersonship. The losing candidate of the election of chairpersonship is actually more
qualified and preferred by the residents than the two candidates for the vicechairpersonship. Under the “transferable separate voting” system, residents could get
their wish of having two competent persons serving as chairperson and vice-chairperson
respectively. However, the “transferable separate voting” system still generally provides
limited choice, and is easily more “controllable” than the “nontransferable separate
voting” system.
4.2.7C Competitive Corresponding Election and Uncompetitive Differential Election
Simply adopting a differential system does not mean the electoral process will
automatically become more competitive. The electoral process can still be easily
manipulated, especially through the nomination process, to ensure the victory of the
candidates favored by the authorities. Through controlling the nomination process, the
authorities can simply disqualify some potential rivals to their preferred candidates. They
can field “weak candidates” together with capable “official” candidates in a differential
election. Residents in this case have only a limited choice between a capable “official
candidate” and a “weak candidate.” The role of the “weak candidates” in this is nothing
more then to make the election appear to be a competitive, differential election.258
On the other hand, a corresponding election can be competitive. A corresponding
election can be competitive at the stage of nomination of formal candidates rather than
258
Zhang Honggang, “Jumin zizhi yun zhixuan er shengdong (Residents’ Self-Governance is Vitalized Because of
Direct Election)” Shequ (Community) 5 (2005), pg. 18; Cui Guoqiang, Zhou Jing, “Dui woguo xuanju zhidu yuanze de
shikao (Thoughts about the Principles of Election in China)” Renda yanjiu (People’s Congress Study) 1 (2003), pg. 1819.
143
the actual election stage. There are cases in which the “transferable separate voting” and
the “nontransferable separate voting” are used in the process of determining formal
candidates, such as some of the residents’ committee elections in the city of Wuhan in
2000.259
4.2.8 Increasing Electoral Competition: Candidates’ Campaigns
For voters to make a meaningful choice between contesting candidates, it is
vitally essential that basic information about the candidates be made available and
accessible to the voters. Introducing the differential principle is only the first step toward
creating an effectively competitive election.260 A blind vote is hardly a democratic
choice.
Securing the voters’ right to know candidates’ information, and the candidates’
right to campaign, however, has not been a top priority on the agenda of electoral reforms
in many shequ, and not particularly encouraged by the authorities. Overt self-promotion
and attacking rivals’ point of view are viewed as not particularly “suitable” to Chinese
culture or “national conditions.” The cultural argument has some validity. The traditional
cultural emphasis on humility and on unassuming modesty does make some candidates
rather shy about self-promotion and fearful of the public perception of being “powerhungry.”261
259
Xu Yong, Chen Weidong, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Self-Governance in China's Urban Communities),
Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe (2002), pg. 311.
260
As an eminent Chinese legal scholar once said, “An election that is not differential is not truly an election; a
differential election without competitive campaigning is not truly a differential election.” Wu Jialin, Wu Jialin zixuanji
(Collected Essays of Wu Jialin), Yinchuan: Ningxia renmin chubanshe (1996), pg. 474.
261
Liu Chongshun, “Wuhanshi Changer shequ juweihui huanjie zhixuan kaocha baogao (A Report on the TermChanging Direct Election to Changer Community Residents’ Committee in Wuhan)” Shehui gongzuo (Journal of
Social Work) 5 (2004), pg. 17; see also Li Fan, “Guangxi Liuzhoushi xin’er shequ zhixuan guangcha (Observation of
the Direct Election in Xin’er Community in Liuzhou, Guangxi)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju, pg. 286. J.
Bruce Jacobs also noted the influence of the cultural factor in his analysis of Chinese people’s congress elections when
144
Both the Villagers’ Committee law and Residents’ Committee Law have no
provisions regarding promotion of the candidates and their meeting with voters. Before
the residents’ committee election reforms in the late 1990s, most elections were
thoroughly controlled by street offices. It was unnecessary for any introduction of the
candidates, not to mention campaign activities. With the introduction of direct,
differential and other election reform measures, provisions similar to the 2004
amendments to the national election law regarding candidates-voters meetings (including
questions-and-answers sessions) and introduction of the candidates by the election
committee have also been incorporated in many local election regulations. The
importance of competitive campaigning, the availability of candidates’ information to the
voters, and voters-candidates interaction, is increasingly being recognized in shequ
elections.262 A government official who was instrumental in the introduction of direct
elections of the residents’ committee in the city of Ningbo admits that high turnout rate is
meaningless if there was “information asymmetry” between candidates and voters. Only
when the electors fully possess adequate information of the elected would the electors be
able to vote meaningfully and rationally, and to supervise the elected effectively.263 A
government survey in district in the city of Wuhan shows that adding the procedure of
organizing meetings between voters and (preliminary) candidates increases shequ
he cites a saying by a provincial vice-governor that people will feel that “any campaigning candidate [only] wants to be
an official.” See J. Bruce Jacobs, “Elections in China” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, 25 (1991), pg. 191.
262
Pu Wanhong, “Lun shequ xuanju zhong xuanmin de zhiqingquan yiji shixian (On the Voters’ Right to Information
and Its Realization in Community Election)” Yunnan xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Yunnan Institute of
Administration) 1 (2004), pg. 49.
263
Xu Yiping, “Duiyu sheu zhixuan de jige wenti de kanfa (My Opinions on Some Issues of Community Direct
Election)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 58-60; see also Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui
xuanju gongzuo jingcheng, pg. 157.
145
residents’ knowledge of the candidates and is thus helpful for them to make a more
meaningful choice.264
Generally there are two types of candidates’ introduction and promotion:
organizational introduction and self-introduction. Traditionally organizational
introduction is the only method, but increasingly many residents’ committee elections
permit both organizational introduction and self-introduction.265
4.2.8A Organizational Introduction
In organizational introductions, candidates are basically passive actors. The
election committee is the main actor to introduce and publicize candidates. It is
responsible for printing and distributing flyers containing candidates’ information and
pictures, putting candidates’ information and pictures on propaganda boards or banners
that would be visible around the shequ, and using other mediums (such as loudspeakers
and posters) to introduce all candidates, all in a supposedly neutral and fair way. The
election committee also organizes meetings of residents to introduce the candidates
personally. Candidates’ initiatives are limited to have the election committee publicize on
their behalf some of their work-plan and work targets. In the 2003 residents’ committee
elections in Haishu district of Ningbo, the local election committees had some novel
ideas. They paraded the candidates on shequ streets in celebrity style, and organized
performances and shows to attract voters to meet with the candidates.266
Although an organizational introduction does not generally advance very much
the competitiveness of elections, it does have its useful purpose in situations in which
264
Ibid, pg. 161.
For an example, see Liu Chongshun, “Wuhanshi Changer shequ juweihui huanjie zhixuan kaocha baogao,” pg. 24.
266
Li Fan, “Guifanhua chengshi shequ xuanju de chenggong changshi (A Successful Attempt to Standardize Urban
Community Elections)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 202-205.
265
146
candidates are unwilling to overtly publicize themselves. In this case, an organizational
introduction becomes the only channel of effective communication between voters and
candidates.
4.2.8B Self-Introduction
Self-introduction requires more candidates’ initiatives to attract voters support.
An election that permits self-introduction will at least allow candidates to give speeches
and answer voters’ questions in meetings with the residents. Self-introduction thus could
be viewed as the basis of candidates’ campaign activities, albeit to be strictly regulated by
the election committee as well.267
For example, Guangxi has issued a regulation about competitive campaign
speeches in residents’ committee elections (jingxuan shizhi yanshuo guize). The
regulation states that the speech of the candidates has to be submitted to the election
committee. The speech shall include basic information (age, political affiliation, working
experience, education, etc.), a three-year work plan and work targets, special abilities or
strong points, and promises to shequ residents once elected. The speech shall not have
contents that (1) violate national policies and laws, (2) attack, vilify, slander the rival
candidates, and (3) make unrealistic and deceiving promises. The election committee is
responsible for scrutinizing, censoring and approving all campaign speeches. It generally
would not alter the text of the speech, but shall do so when “politically incorrect views”
(zhengzhi cuowu guandian) are contained in the speech. The election committee shall not
leak candidates’ speech to their rivals. Voters have the right to question the candidates
267
See the Beijing shequ election regulations contained in Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo
jingcheng baogao, pg. 357.
147
after their speech, and the candidates should answer voters’ questions unless they are
related to national policies and personal privacy.268
While in most elections direct interaction between candidates and residents
generally is confined to the meetings of residents’ assembly and residents’ small groups,
organized and supervised by the election committee, some local governments allow more
opportunities for candidates to be more pro-active in the courting of votes. Haishu district
in the city of Ningbo was novel in its approach to election campaigning. Article 15 of its
shequ election regulations stipulates that candidates can “meet voters according to their
own ways.”269 Some candidates took this opportunity to introduce some innovative
practices, such as door-to-door canvassing for votes, a rarity in Chinese elections. More
interestingly was the emergence of election campaign teams (xuanju houyuantuan or
xuanju zhinangtuan). These teams were organized by the candidates. They recommended
campaign strategies, remade the image of their candidates, and served as election
observers during elections.270 The campaign teams in a way resemble the political
consultants that are common in democratic countries. Not only did these election
campaign teams raise the level and quality of electoral competition, absent competitive
party politics, they could be the only form of organized political contestation that is
tolerated and acceptable in China.
268
“Guangxi shequ jumin weiyuanhui jingxuan shizhi yanshuo guize (Regulation on Campaign Speech of Community
Residents’ Committee of Guangxi)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg. 366-368; The Beijing shequ
election regulations also have similar provisions governing the rules of candidates’ speech, see Zhan Chengfu (ed.),
Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 357-358.
269
“Ningboshi Haishuqu shequ jumin weiyuanhui xuanju banfa (shixing) [Election Law of Community Residents’
Committee of Haishu District, Ningbo (Trial)]” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige (Direct Election
Reform in China’s Urban Communities, pg. 195.
270
Li Fan, “Shequ juweihui xuanju shouci dachu chuangxinpai (Innovative Ideas in Residents’ Committee Elections)
Shequ (Community) 6-12 (2003), pg. 20; Li Fan, “Guifanhua chengshi shequ xuanju de chenggong changshi (A
Successful Attempt to Standardize Urban Community Elections)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige, pg.
202-205.
148
Another important issue in self-introduction is the election debate. As mentioned
in the first section of this chapter, the logic of “one-party competitive election” is that in
general, elections are not about competition between rival political proposals or programs
that are based on different interest demands, representation, and aggregation. Rather, they
are a competition based on candidates’ competence, character, and access to resources.
As a result, most election debates are also rather timid and insubstantial. The candidates’
speeches in residents’ committee elections reported in Chinese media and publications
generally conform to this pattern: they are mostly apolitical and service-oriented. Even in
Haishu district of Ningbo, a “star” district in shequ democratization, anecdotic collection
of campaign speeches shows that all candidates were making general and vague promises
to serve the residents better.271
Some scholars consider elections without substantial competitive policy programs
as democratically deficient. Instead of being the foundation for further political
democratization, shequ elections become an “element of depoliticization”272 This
assessment is a bit harsh, considering that local elections in liberal democratic systems
generally also emphasize non-political and daily-life issues, as well as the competence
and ability (rather than the ideological stand) of the candidates.273 Nevertheless, the
criticism that candidates should not just focus on advertising and promoting their service
capabilities is valid.
271
Xu Yiping, “Duiyu sheu zhixuan de jige wenti de kanfa (My Opinions on Some Issues of Community Direct
Election)” in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju, pg. 51.
272
Yong Gui, Joseph Y.S. Cheng & Weihong Ma, “Cultivation of Grassroots Democracy: A Study of Direct Elections
of Residents Committees in Shanghai” China Information 20:1 (2006), pg. 27.
273
There is a case in which a candidate in a residents’ committee election vowed to fight for the interest of laid-off
workers (himself a layoff worker) in the city of Dalian. See “Dalian ‘xiaoxiang zongli’ shouchang zhixuan (Direct
elections for ‘Lane Managers’ in Dalian)” Liaoning ribao, January 20, 2005. This will contradict the logic of “oneparty competitive elections.” Nonetheless, this is so far the only example of an interest-based approach to election
campaigning I have seen.
149
Allowing more substantial debate between candidates, or to put it more bluntly,
allowing candidates to attack their rivals during the campaign period (as indicated in the
Guangxi regulations above, attacking rivals is not allowed), brings forth a number of
benefits, such as forcing the candidates to be more specific about their work plan and
targets, clarifying the choice the voters have, and training both the candidates and the
voters the “game of democratic election.” During Beijing’s Jiudaowan shequ election,
there was an unusual fierce debate between the candidates for the vice-chairpersonship.
The election committee permitted the candidates to attack their rival’s speech, as long as
it was not personal attack. The debate, together with some critical and penetrating
questions from the voters during the questions-and-answers session, forced each
candidate to be more responsive. It also generated an atmosphere of candidates’
responsibility and accountability to the residents.274
4.2.9 In the Act of Voting: How to Protect the Secret Vote
The secret vote is essential to the exercise of free choice by the voters. Without
the choice being fully protected by the secret vote, voters might feel obliged, threatened,
or be coerced to vote for certain candidates. In the past, China has not placed much
emphasis on the importance of secret voting. Citing the large number of illiterate in the
society, the government argued that the secret vote was impractical. However, in recent
years, the principle of the secret vote has been basically accepted. Article 33 of the
national election law and Article 14 of the Villagers’ Committee Law both stipulate that
elections shall be by “anonymous vote.”
274
Zhao Yi, “Zhengfu wei gongzhong de minzhu quanli ‘maidan’ zhibuzhi (Is it Worth for the Government to Pay for
the Democratic Rights of the People)” Shequ (Community), 11-22 (2002), pg. 6-7.
150
The “anonymous vote” (wujiming toupiao) is still not yet a fully secret vote (mimi
toupiao). It is only the first step, although in China these two terms are sometimes
misinterpreted as synonymous.275 An anonymous vote simply means that ballot papers
are not traceable and identifiable, whereas the secret vote requires a more complicated
design and regulation of the voting process that would protect the identity of the voters
and the choice they make.
4.2.9A Centralized Voting and Decentralized Voting
The first issue here is the organization of the actual voting process. The prevalent
method of organizing voters to cast their ballot in shequ elections is the so-called
“centralized voting” (jizhong toupiao) method, which means voters are to assemble at
one major location on the polling day. There, voters listen to candidates’ speech and
approve the appointments of ballot counters and ballot supervisors. After this, they
collect, write and then cast their ballots.
There are both spatial and temporal problems. Since voters first have to go
through a number of things (candidates’ speech, etc.) before proceeding to vote, there is
generally a sense of impatience among voters. They want to finish the business as soon as
possible. Then there is the issue of limited space. Many election committees complain
about not having a location that could accommodate the large number of voters. They
also complain there is not enough space for the installation of secret ballot booths on that
location. Few secret ballot booths also make voters to wait in a long queue.
275
The official English translations of national election law and Villagers’ Committee Law use the term “secret vote,”
which is not exactly correct. Even an authoritative textbook on Chinese government also makes such mistake. See Pu
Xingzu (ed.) Zhonghua renming gongheguo zhengzhi zhidu, pg. 159.
151
Election committees generally also give voters the option to write their ballot in
public or to do so in secret ballot booths. Out of convenience, impatience, and unwilling
to stand in a long queue, many voters choose to write their ballot in public. Sometimes
they even have discussions with fellow voters about the vote choice.276 Some voters also
might feel that they should not write their ballot in secret ballot booths, since this could
be interpreted (by the voters themselves and by the officials) as making the statement of
voting against the candidates favored by the authorities. Only those who intend not to
vote for the “official candidates” have the incentive to hide the identity of their vote
choice.
The use of secret ballot booths tends to be ignored as an important procedural
step. Many election organizers simply interpret the anonymous vote as a secret vote and
have not viewed this is an important issue. However, in recent years, increasingly
election committees have begun to grasp the difference between the anonymous vote and
the secret vote, and have taken a number of procedural reforms in the voting process to
protect the secret vote. Instead of convening a voters’ assembly to go through candidates’
speech, appointment of vote-counters, and other technical issues are on the polling day,
these issues are now to be settled before the polling day. On that day more secret ballot
booths and voting stations are established at many locations in the shequ and open for the
whole day –the so-called method of “decentralized voting” (fenshan toupiao).277 More
importantly, writing the ballot inside secret ballot booths is to be mandatory. In such a
way, voters do not feel that their vote choice will be implied by their preference of voting
276
Zheng Wen, “Mimi xiepiaojian zheshe minzhu jinbu (Secret Ballot Booth Reflects Democratic Progress)” Renmin
daibiaobao April 27, 2006.
277
Yi Yan, “Fenshan toupiao: gengfuhe dangqian shequ de xianshi xuyao (Decentralized Voting: Meeting the Demand
of Present Community Situation)” Zhongguo shehuibao October 30, 2007.
152
in the secret ballot booth. The residents’ committee elections in the province of Guangxi
are pioneers in this regard.278
4.2.9B Proxy Voters, Scribes for the Illiterate, Roving Ballot Boxes
Another issue is the use of several practices known (from rural election
experiences) to have compromised the integrity of the secret vote: the use of proxy
voters, scribes for illiterate voters, and roving ballot boxes. All these practices essentially
will result in the vote choice of a voter being exposed to, and influenced by, another
person. Election officials have abused these practices to either influence voters to vote for
their preferred candidates, or to artificially inflate voter turnout rate. Nevertheless, these
practices are still justified in China on the ground that China, especially in rural areas,
still has large numbers of illiterate voters. Many voters also live in villages faraway from
town centers. Without proxy voters, scribes for the illiterate, and roving ballot boxes,
large number of voters may actually be deprived of their franchise. They are necessary
for a more inclusive electoral participation in China.
In general, the urban literacy rate is much higher. Shequ residents also live in
more compact residential areas. Scribes for illiterate voters and the use of roving ballot
boxes are therefore less common (but not totally absent). The use of proxy voters in
shequ elections, however, is widespread. As we have seen before, many shequ residents
are not interested in elections. They are therefore happy to entrust a proxy to vote on their
behalf. The obsessive belief among officials in the value of high turnout rate is also a
fundamental reason in the widespread use of proxy voters.
278
Li Ji, Gu Yizhong, “Zheli de canxuanlu weishenme gao (Why the Turnout Rate is High Here)” Shequ (Community),
11-21 (2001), pg. 26; Li Fan, “Yige cong nongcun xuanju xiang chengshi xuanju guodu de chenggong shili (A
Succesful Case of Transition From Rural Elections to Urban Elections)” Shequ (Community) 6-11 (2002), pg. 25.
153
Legally, Chinese elections are not required to have a high turnout rate. But they
are bounded by two “50% rules”, which are stipulated in Article 38 of the national
election law and Article 14 of the Villagers’ Committee Law. The Residents’ Committee
Law has no similar provisions, but almost all local election regulations for residents’
committees have such provisions. These rules state that: 1) for an election to be valid it
has to obtain the ballots of at least 50 percent of all registered voters; 2) for a candidate to
be elected he or she has to obtain at least 50 percent of the votes.
Theoretically, these two rules can be powerful weapons for the voters to vote out
the candidates they dislike, even if these candidates are supported and approved by the
authorities. Voters could choose not to turn up for an election and therefore make the
election invalid, and the authorities would have to reconsider the choices of candidates.
Voters could abstain or vote against all formal candidates. This will result in all
candidates receiving less then 50% of the vote, thus none would be elected.279 Indeed,
there are cases of shequ elections in which all candidates failed to fulfill either one of the
“50% rules,” making it necessary for second-round elections. The candidates then were
replaced or had to work harder to gain support voters’ support, enhancing democratic
accountability between the electors and elected.280
Notwithstanding these positive effects, these two rules are also the institutional
incentives for local officials and election committees to manipulate the election process
to secure the requirement of these rules. Especially for officials at the street office, failing
279
Robert Weatherly, Politics in China since 1949: Legitimizing Authoritarian Rule, New York, NY: Routledge
(2006), pg. 117.
280
Ni Yan, Nie Yonghong, “Xuanpiao buguoban, shequ quweihui zhuren huanjie chongxin xuanju (Fewer than Half,
the Re-election of the Chairperson of Community Residents’ Committee)” Nanjing ribao April 26, 2006; “2000nian
Pudong xinqu juweihui xuanju gongzuo zongjie (Residents’ Committee Election Work Conclusion of Pudong New
District, 2000) in Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige (Direct Election Reform in China’s Urban
Communities), edited by Li Fan, Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe (2003), pg. 240.
154
to fulfill either one of these rules is an indication of their weak work performance. These
institutional incentives, together with the bureaucratic mentality of equaling success with
impressive numbers, create an environment in which high turnout rate is normal
expectation by local officials and election organizers. Electoral mobilization through
networks of activists and party members, the use of proxy voters and the use of roving
ballot box, thus have become standard tactics for officials to inflate the turnout rate in
shequ elections. In using these practices, the principle of the secret vote also tends to be
brushed aside.
I have mentioned briefly the role played by shequ activists during elections in
Appendix 4.4. In electoral mobilization, activists often try to persuade residents (to vote)
by resorting to personal ties (guanxi) or by asking residents “to give them face” (gei
mianzi).281 With their good relationship with the residents, many activists are also
entrusted to vote on their behalf. When entrusting the activists to vote on their behalf,
residents also often let activists to decide for them whom to vote for. It is not uncommon
for an activist to actually dictate the vote choice of more than 20 residents, even though
many election regulations clearly stipulate that a proxy can only vote on behalf of a
maximum of three other voters.282 Thus, many residents’ committee elections with a high
turnout rate actually have very low level of participation. They are democratically flawed
and deficient elections, but unfortunately many local officials still consider the result of
high turnout more important than an election process that protects the integrity of the
secret vote.
281
Gui Yong, “Linli zhengzhi: chengshi jiceng de quanli caozuo celue yu guojia-shehui de zhanlian moshi
(Neighborhood Politics: Power Manipulation Tactics and the Adhesive-Connective Model of State and Society in
Urban Grassroots)” Shehui (Society), 6 (2007), 102-126.
282
Xiong Yihan, “ Shequ xuanju: zai zhengzhi lengmo yu gao toupiaolu zhijian (Community Elections: Between
Political Indifference and High Turnout Rate)” Shehui (Society), 28:3 (2008), pg. 180-204.
155
Some scholars have suggested the elimination of all these practices (roving ballot
boxes, scribes, proxy voters), but this will certainly be opposed by most officials. The
next best answer to these problems is restricting and regulating these practices, such as
certification of proxy voters before the polling day. Beijing’s Jiudaowan election in 2002
was particularly strict about the use of the roving ballot box, restricting its use to
accommodate the disabled and elderly residents only. Nevertheless, the problem of
inadequate protection of the secret vote is not as much an institutional and technical
problem as it is a cultural problem –the obsession to obtain high turnout rate.
4.2.10 Removing Members of the Residents’ Committee: The Right to Recall and the
Right to Dismiss
The last issue in this section is the process of removing members of the shequ
residents’ committee. Some scholars argue that theoretically and constitutionally the
voting rights include the right to recall. Since it is through election that the elector
mandates the elected to exercise power on the elector’s behalf, the elector thus also has
the right to recall this mandate.283
4.2.10A Residents’ Right to Recall
Article 10 of the Residents’ Committee Law stipulates that the residents’
assembly has the right to recall members of the residents’ committee and the right to hold
by-elections, without providing the mechanism and procedure to initiate a recall process.
Local laws and regulations are more specific. Provincial law on the residents’ committee
of Henan and Beijing shequ election regulations both state that the recall of a member of
283
Li Fan (ed.) Zhongguo xuanju zhidu gaige, pg. 231. This right is still enshrined in Article 40 of the national election
law and Article 16 of the Villagers’ Committee law. In 2003 there is a case of voters attempting to recall an elected
deputy to the district people’s congress (who is also chair of a residents’ committee) in Shenzhen. The case received
extensive media attention, chiefly because of the rarity of such situation. Li Nanling, Wu Huanqing, Shen Lutao,
“Bamian, shi quanli yeshi jiandu (Recall, it is a Right also a Supervision)” Renmin ribao July 2, 2007.
156
the residents’ committee has to be jointly proposed by one-fifth of the residents who have
the voting right. In the case of Beijing, one-fifth of the household representatives or onethird of the residents’ representatives can also propose to recall a residents’ committee
member. The recall proposal can only be submitted three months after an election, to the
residents’ committee, the street office, and the district government. On the recall
proposal, residents have to state the reason(s) for recalling this particular member. Upon
receiving the recall proposal, the residents’ committee then has to convene the residents’
assembly (or residents’ representatives’ assembly) with the approval of the street office.
In the meeting of the assembly, the concerned member of the residents’ committee is
given a chance to defend himself/herself. The recall is confirmed if more than half of the
residents (or residents’ representatives) attending the assembly vote to recall this
particular member. After the member is recalled, a by-election shall be organized as soon
as possible. Other local election documents generally have similar provisions regarding
the process of recall.284
However, successfully recalling a member of the residents’ committee is, not
surprisingly, extremely rare. In 2007, in the city of Chengdu, there was a case in which
52 residents’ representatives (out of a total of 72) in a shequ in Qingyang district
successfully convened a residents’ representatives assembly and voted to remove an
unpopular member of the residents’ committee (she was given 5 minutes to defend
herself in the assembly). This committee member already received poor evaluation from
the residents in the street office’s assessment of her performance. The street office
284
Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao, pg. 211,422.
157
attempted to persuade her to resign but to no avail, and it was the residents (through
residents’ representatives) who were successfully able to remove her from office.285
This was indeed an exercise of the recall power of the residents over the officeholders. That the recall was successful also enhanced the democratic accountability of the
residents’ committee to the residents. However, this case has to be qualified as well, since
the street office was also supportive of the removal of this member. The street office in
this case proceeded carefully and was supportive of the residents. But what if the
residents were attempting to remove a member who had the support of the street office?
In an earlier case in 2006 in which residents in a shequ attempted to remove the whole
residents’ committee in Beijing was unsuccessful. Residents suspected election
irregularities after a residents’ committee election, and proposed to convene a meeting of
the residents’ assembly to initiate the recall process. The proposal, however, was
consistently rejected by the street office, which apparently had decided to support the
residents’ committee.286
4.2.10B Street Office’s Power to Dismiss and Transfer
The removal of a member of the residents’ committee is very unlikely to be the
result of a successful recall. It is more likely the case of being dismissed or transferred by
the street office. The legal basis for the street office to exercise this power is unclear. The
Residents’ Committee Law and most election documents basically state that members of
285
Liu Feng, “Chengdu jumin bamian ‘buchengzhi’ shequ ganbu (Chengdu Residents Recall an ‘Underperforming’
Community Cadre)” Renmin daibiaobao April 12, 2007; Li Dequan, Wang Jing, “Woshi shouci jumin daibiao xi “ba”
quan, “chao” diao juweihui weiyuan (For the First Time Residents’ Representatives Exercise the Right to Recall, Firing
a Member of Residents’ Committee in Our City)” Chengdu ribao April 7, 2007.
286
“Tianxin jiayuan 639hu jumin lianming bamian juweihui (Residents from 639 Houesholds Jointly Propose to Recall
Residents’ Committee in Tianxin Jiayuan Community)” Huaxia shibao May 26, 2006.
158
the residents’ committee be removed through the recall process initiated by residents, but
do not state whether this is the only way of removal.
The street office’s power to dismiss and transfer members of the residents’
committee, however, defeats the purposes of residents’ self-governance and electoral
accountability. Residents’ committee members will feel less accountable to residents and
more responsible to the street office. In the above case of a successful recall in Chengdu,
the street office acted with prudence. Instead of dismissing an unpopular member of the
residents’ committee, it let the residents do the job of removing this person. Nevertheless,
most street offices consider themselves to have this power, especially if a residents’
committee member is a recruit of the street office under the policy of jiepin minxuan (see
Box 4.5). From the point of view of the street office, these recruits are basically hired
under a contract to do jobs for the street office in shequ. Therefore they can be fired and
transferred at will.287
4.3 The Rules of Shequ Residents’ Committee Direct Elections
In 2003, the Bureau of Base-Level Government and Community Construction of
the Ministry and Civil Affairs, an election study center at Duke University, and the China
Elections Project at the Carter Center established a joint task force to study and draft a set
of rules and regulations of shequ elections. The result was the “Rules of Shequ Residents’
Committee Direct Elections” (Shequ jumin weiyuanhui zhijie xuanju guicheng), issued in
2004.
287
In fact, this is the precise argument made by an official in Beijing. See He Xiaoling, Yang Binglong, Xu Wei,
“Jiepin minxuan, hefahu? Helihu? (Street Hires, Resident Elects, Legal? Reasonable?)” Shequ (Community) 20 (2002),
pg. 17.
159
The “Rules” states that all members of the election committee are elected by
residents, with only the chair and deputy chairperson of the election committee are
“elected” by the tuixuan process internally. All residents’ committee elections are direct
elections and differential elections. Registration of voters is done through xuanmin
dengji. Suffrage of migrant workers is guaranteed. The provisions on elections of
residents’ representatives and leaders of residents’ small groups are still inadequate, but it
states clearly these positions are to be elected by anonymous vote. There are no formal
nominee qualification requirements. The preliminary nomination process is restricted to
joint nomination, self-nomination, or “sea election” only. Primary election by residents
through the residents’ assembly provides for the determination of formal candidates.
Candidates are allowed to openly campaign for voters. Roving ballot box is prohibited,
whereas the use of proxy voters and scribes for the illiterate are restricted with stricter
regulations. Voters must write their ballot in secret ballot booths. A residents’ assembly
must convene 30 days after receiving a recall proposal supported by one-fifths of the
residents.288
The “Rules” are by far the best and most democratic election document in China.
Many of its stipulations are superior to the similar provisions in the national election law
and Villagers’ Committee Law. It is consistent with the model of “one-party competitive
elections”, and it probably represents how democratic elections could be under such a
model. However, the “Rules” are not a law. The Ministry of Civil Affairs can only
recommend the use of these “Rules” and the incorporation of some of the provisions of
the “Rules” in the election regulations of the local governments. The Ministry cannot
288
Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng, pg. 33-43.
160
enforce it. But the “Rules” still serves as a guide for reformist officials in designing,
reforming, improving, and institutionalizing the diverse shequ electoral processes.
Conclusion
This chapter first reviews the evolution of the views on elections by Chinese
communist leaders. Influenced by Marxist-Leninist critique of “bourgeois elections,”
early communist leaders tended to have an instrumental conception of elections. In recent
years, however, Chinese leaders begin to accept the idea that elections are class-neutral
and a necessary element in the construction of a socialist democratic system. The model
of “one-party competitive elections,” which combines Leninist party logic, one-party
rule, and competitive elections, is at present the type of elections that is mostly to be
accepted by the Chinese leaders today.
The electoral systems used for residents’ committee elections are very diverse. In
this chapter I look at and analyze the critical issues, as well as the institutional reforms
and flaws, in which residents’ committee elections are facing. First, how the election
committee is selected and staffed is critical to ensuring a fair election. There is still no
independent, professional election organizing body in China, and many election
committees are controlled by the authorities. Second, shifting the mode of election from
indirect election by residents’ representatives to either direct election or indirect election
by household representatives is the focus of recent election reforms in many residents’
committees. Nevertheless, there is still no consensus whether direct election is the best
institutional reform at the present moment. Third, the elections of leaders of residents’
small groups and residents’ representatives are also part of the process of residents’
committee elections. These shequ activists are important part of the network of
161
governance within a shequ. Fourth, the voting rights of migrant workers, danwei people,
and foreign nationals have been subject to considerable debate in the implementation of
residents’ committee election reforms in recent years. As the voting rights of residents’
committee elections are established on the basis of residence under the law, it is
suggested that migrant workers and even foreign nationals be given the voting rights.
Fifth, some shequ have experimented with xuanmin dengji, a reform that requires
the voluntary registration by voters, to replace or complement the old registration system
in which the voters are passive actors in the registration process. This reform, it is argued,
will increase residents’ passion and interests in the elections. Sixth, a number of
institutional reforms are focused on the complex nomination process. From the
nomination of preliminary candidates to the determination of formal candidates, election
reformers have argued for more a more open process in which voters, rather than political
parties and organizations, play the major nomination role. Seventh, different types of
differential elections have proliferated in the residents’ committee elections in recent
years, some giving more choices to the voters, some less so.
Eighth, some shequ in recent years have liberalized the regulation of campaign
activities. Organized political contestations are now possible in a number of residents’
committee elections. Some shequ also allow more direct debates between candidates. All
these reforms will increase the quality of elections. Ninth, the protection of the secret
ballot is also an important area of reform in residents’ committee elections. The major
reforms include the strict requirement of voting in secret ballot booths, and the limitation
of the use of roving ballot boxes, scribes for illiterate, and proxy voters. Here I argue that
the bureaucratic culture of securing high turnout rate is the main source of the problem,
162
rather than the institutional design of the electoral system. Finally, the removal process of
the elected residents’ committee members also requires attention from election reformers.
At present, residents’ right to recall still largely exists on paper only, while many street
offices have taken liberty to dismiss or transfer elected residents’ committee members at
will.
Finally, I conclude with a brief discussion of a new set of election rules for
residents’ committee elections drafted by the Ministry of Civil Affairs in 2005. The
election rules address many of the institutional failures of the present electoral systems,
and adopt a number of institutional innovations and reforms proposed by election
reformers. These election rules appear to be the most democratic election system
available in China today. However, the rules are not a law or decree, they have no
binding force.
163
Table 4.1: Average Election Expenses per Shequ
City/Province
City
Beijing
Tianjin
Chongqing
Province
Hainan
Sichuan
Yunnan
Heilongjiang
Guangdong
Jiangxi
Henan
Guizhou
Tibet
Ningxia
Average election expenses, per shequ, in
Chinese yuan
Direct election: 50,000
Election by household representatives:
10,000-30,000
Election by residents’ representatives:
5,000
3,000
2,500
5,000
3,900
7,500
3,000-5,000
18,000
2,000
3,000
5,000
4,000
1,000
Source: Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of Election
Work of Community Residents’ Committee) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 15-16.
164
Table 4:2 Nomination Methods
Provincial
Street
Units/Nomination Office (%)
Methods
Residents’
Small
Groups (%)
Beijing
Tianjin
Liaoning
Jilin
Heilongjiang
Shanghai
Fujian
Jiangxi
Henan
Hunan
Guangdong
Guangxi
Hainan
Chongqing
Sichuan
Guizhou
Yunnan
Tibet
Shaanxi
Qinghai
Ningxia
100
20
15.5
70
40
69
3.65
0.4
32
76
55
95.1
100
34
13
65
40.69
30.7
10
50
53.4
40
25
23
85
Joint
Nomination
by Voters
(%)
SelfNomination
(%)
5
82
34
35
4.1
5
1.5
30
20
0.8
89
7.8
20
9.76
69.3
80
20
28.5
50
38
100
1
12
38
Others (%)
1
36
3.7
5
4.07
6.5
10
41.83
10
30
3.7
10
4
14
1
3
62
Source: Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of Election
Work of Community Residents’ Committee) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 11-12.
165
Table 4.3: “Degree” and “Range” of Different Type of Differential Elections:
“Degree”
Simple Plurality
Low
Limited Differential without Moderate
Leadership Positions
Limited Differential with
Moderate
Leadership Positions
Transferable Separate
High
Voting
Nontransferable Separate
High
Voting
“Range”
Low
Low
Low/Moderate
Low
Moderate/High
166
Figure 4.1 Legal Framework of Shequ Residents’ Committee Elections
Constitution of the People’s Republic of China
The Organic Law of Urban Residents’ Committees of the People’s Republic of China
XX Provincial Law on the Implementation of “The Organic Law of Urban Residents’
Committees”
The Election Law for Urban Residents’ Committee of XX City Peoples’ Government
Implementation Act of Residents’ Committee Elections of XX District Government
Implemetation Measures of Residents’ Committee Elections of XX Street Office
Election Work Guide, XX Shequ
Notes:
1. Not all city governments have an election law for the residents’ committee.
Adapted from Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The
Residents’ Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee in Urban
Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 114.
167
Figure 4:2 Different Types of Differential Election
Type 1: Simple Plurality
(6 formal candidates, 5 elected positions)
☺
☺
☺☺☺ ☻ (6 candidates)
Chair Vice-Chair Regular Not-Elected
The highest vote receiver becomes
the chairperson
The runner-up becomes the vicechairperson
The lowest vote receiver is voted
out
Type 3: Limited Differential with
Leadership positions
(7 formal candidates, 5 elected positions)
☺
☻
(2 candidates)
Chair Not-Elected
☺
☻
(2 candidates)
Vice-Chair Not-Elected
☺☺☺
(3 candidates)
Regular
The chairperson and vicechairperson elected differentially
Type 5: Nontransferable Separate
Voting
(8 formal candidates, 5 elected positions)
☺
☻
(2 candidates)
Chair
Not-Elected
☺
☻
(2 candidates)
Vice-Chair Not-Elected
☺☺☺ ☻
(4 candidates)
Regular Not-Elected
Type 2: Limited Differential without
Leadership Positions
(6 formal candidates, 5 elected positions)
☺ (1 candidate)
Chair
☺ (1 candidate)
Vice-Chairperson
☺☺☺
☻
(4 candidates)
Regular
Not-Elected
The chairperson and vicechairperson elected correspondingly
Type 4: Transferable Separate Voting
(6 formal candidates, 5 elected positions)
☺
☺
(2 candidates)
Chair Next-round candidate
☺
☺
(1 candidate)
Vice-Chair Next-round candidate
☺☺☺
☻
(3 candidates)
Regular
Not-Elected
The losing candidate becomes the
next-round candidate
Each position elected differentially
168
Chapter 5 Toward Democratic Public Administration and Governance
in Shequ: Institutional Innovations
While election is undoubtedly the foundation of reforming and democratizing the
shequ residents’ committees, the other three elements of democracy (democratic
decision-making, management, and supervision) in the official discourse of “socialist
democracy with Chinese characteristics” provide the basic structure of a democratic
public administration and governance. The 2005 White Paper on democracy makes the
following argument regarding the implementation of these elements in shequ democracy:
In terms of democratic decision-making, the residents of a [shequ], as the
mainstay in this respect, exercise their decision-making power by holding
residents’ [assembly], forums, hearings and through other effective forms and
channels. In the aspect of democratic management, the [residents’ committees]
work within the framework of law, standardize their work according to the
[shequ] residents’ self-government rules and regulations, in an effort to make the
residents more conscious of being the masters of their own affairs and concerned
about public affairs in the [shequ]. In the aspect of democratic supervision, the
[residents’ committee] practices open management; all issues of public concern,
difficult problems and important matters involving the residents’ interests are
made public to the residents in a timely manner and subject to their discussions,
comments, suggestions and supervision.289
This citation from the official statement on Chinese democracy illustrates what
“democratic” elements and institutions the Chinese policymakers are looking for when
they pronounce a policy of building up democratic politics in urban shequ. If election
ensures democratic participation and accountability once in every three years, these
institutions and mechanisms are designed to ensure participation and accountability on a
more ongoing basis. In this chapter, I will discuss each of these elements/aspects of
289
“China's 2005 White Paper: ‘Building of Political Democracy in China’,” Asian Affairs: An American Review 33:1
(2006), pg. 18-19. See also Wang Yicheng & Yun Jie, “Gaige kaifangyilai de Zhongguo jiceng minzhu jianshe
(China’s Grassroots Democratic Building Since the Reform and Open Door),” Zhengzhixue yanjiu (CASS Journal of
Political Science), 2 (2004), pg. 26-33.
169
democratic governance, and in the last section, I will pay particular attention to an
institutional innovation in Shanghai’s Luwan district called the three-meeting system
(sanhui zhidu).
5.1 Democratic Decision-Making in Shequ
In accordance with the 2005 White Paper, shequ democratic decision-making
basically means the effective functioning of the shequ residents’ assembly290, the shequ
residents’ representatives’ assembly291, and/or other participatory channels (such as
hearings or forums) in the decision-making process. Among these channels, only the
residents’ assembly (or representatives’ assembly) is prescribed in the Residents’
Committee Law. The law contains two articles stipulating the composition, operation,
and functions of the residents’ assembly. Article 9 states that the assembly shall be
attended by all residents who are 18 or older, household representatives, or elected
residents’ representatives. A simple majority is required to approve the decisions of the
assembly. Article 10 states that the residents’ committee shall be responsible to the
residents’ assembly, and it shall deliver its work report to the residents’ assembly. The
residents’ committee is also responsible for convening and chairing the residents’
assembly. A residents’ assembly shall convene when proposed by one-fifth of the
residents who are at least 18, one-fifth of the households, or one-third of the number of
residents’ representatives. The residents’ assembly decides on important matters
involving the interests of all residents. It has the power to remove members of the
residents’ committee and hold a by-election.
290
Shequ huiyi, shequ jumin huiyi, and jumin huiyi are the terms used in Chinese in referring to this same body.
Shequ daibiao huiyi, shequ jumin daibiao huiyi, shequ chengyuan daibiao huiyi and jumin daibiao huiyi are the
terms used in Chinese in referring to this same body.
291
170
From the above stipulations, it can be deduced that the residents’ assembly has at
least two powers formally enshrined in the law: 1) the power of decision-making,
especially regarding “important matters involving the interests of all the residents,” and
2) the power of supervision. Since the residents’ committee is obliged to report to the
residents’ assembly, presumably the latter is empowered to examine the performance and
the work report of the residents’ committee. The work report explains the progress and
issues in implementing the decisions made by the assembly.292 Articles 15, 16 and 17 of
the Residents’ Committee Law spell out three particular instances that are considered
“important matters” and require the approval of the residents’ assembly: drafting the
residents’ agreements293, raising funds for public welfare projects, and determining the
amount of remuneration for members of the residents’ committees. However, it is
obvious that “important matters” are not limited to only these items. The law does not
stipulate the frequency for the meeting of residents’ assemblies, but commonly it is held
once a year.
The law also endorses the format of the residents’ representatives’ assembly in
place of the residents’ assembly. Since the re-organization of several residents’
committees into one shequ residents’ committee, convening a shequ residents’ assembly
attended by all eligible residents becomes extremely difficult. Instead, shequ residents’
representatives’ assemblies are much more common today. As noted in Chapter 4, the
elections of these representatives are not always up to democratic standards. Thus, we
could argue that the “democratic degree” of residents’ representatives’ assemblies is less
292
Deng Enyuan & Zhao Xuechang (ed), Shequ jianshe zhengce yu fagui (Policies and Laws of Community
Construction), Beijing: Zhongguo qinggongye chubanshe (2003), pg. 27.
293
Jumin gongyue, to be discussed under the section “Democratic Management”.
171
than residents’ assemblies. On the other hand, in many shequ the representatives’
assembly is not only attended by residents’ representatives but also by representatives
from the danwei in shequ, and by representatives of the migrant workers. These
representatives’ assemblies are more broadly representative.
Whether in the form of representatives’ assembly or residents’ representatives’
assembly294, it seems that the institutional design of this organ is that it is the designated
principal decision-maker while the residents’ committee is the implementer. A Ministry
of Civil Affairs handbook published in 1996 states that “the highest form of residents’
self-governance is the residents’ assembly… It is through the residents’ assembly that
ordinary residents become masters of their own affairs.”295 It seems that the assembly
provides an avenue of direct participation by the residents. In this regard, direct
participation by the residents in the residents’ assembly shares some similarities with the
“real democracy” of New England town meetings in some American states. The
residents’ assembly and the residents’ committee are thus the respective participatory and
electoral institutions sustaining shequ democratic development.
However, in a confusing explanation of the relationship between the assembly and
the residents’ committee, the same handbook also states that the working principle of
residents’ committee is “legislative-executive unity” (yixing heyi)296. According to this
principle, the residents’ committee is the “highest decision-making organ.” The views
294
Hereafter, unless cited from another text, I will refer to this organ as the residents’ assembly or simply the assembly.
Wang Zhenyao & Bao Yihua (ed), Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe (The Work of Street Office and the
Construction of Residents' Committee), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (1996), pg. 235.
296
The idea of “legislative-executive unity” comes from Marx’s description of the Paris Commune: “The Commune
was to be a working, not a parliamentary body, executive and legislative at the same time.” See Karl Marx, The Civil
War in France, New York, NY: International Publishers (1940), pg. 57. According to this principle, the legislative and
executive powers are united in one organ, in contrast to the “separation-of-power” doctrine more common in
democratic societies. The Chinese political theorists have insisted that the National People’s Congress operates
according to this principle. See Lin Shangli, Dandai Zhongguo zhengzhi xingtai yanjiu (A Study of China’s
Contemporary Political Formation), Tianjin: Tianjin renmin chubanshe (2000), pg. 181-188.
295
172
that the assembly is the “highest power organ,” “highest decision-making organ” or
“highest supervision organ” and that the residents’ committee is the executive organ of
the assembly is without theoretical basis and “unscientific”, the authors of this handbook
claim.297
This theoretical obscurity and the vague division of authority between the
residents’ committee and the residents’ assembly render the residents’ assembly
ineffective most of the time. Most residents’ committees only pay lip service to the
purported “decision making power” of the assembly. In an article published in the
newspaper of the Ministry of Civil Affairs, the author laments that many residents have
not heard of the residents’ assembly. Many cadres disregard this institution. There are
certain weaknesses in the traditional design of the assembly.
First, the residents’ committee enjoys substantial informational advantage and
dominates the agenda during the assembly’s meeting. Second, the residents’ assembly is
generally convened once a year and chaired by a member of the residents’ committee.
The infrequent meeting of the assembly also means the residents’ committee is the
dominant organization most of the time. Although residents can propose convening a
meeting of the residents’ assembly anytime, it is difficult to fulfill the requirements of
“one-fifth of the eligible residents”, “one-fifth of the household representatives”, or “onethird of the residents’ representatives.” The logistical costs and collective efforts tend to
deter them from doing so.
Third, the residents’ committee is in charge of the possession and use of official
stamp. The official stamp formalizes the legality of a document, transaction, contract, etc.
297
Wang & Bao, Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe, pg. 235.
173
While in theory the residents’ assembly deliberates and decides on “important matters”,
in fact the residents’ committee can make important decisions regardless of what the
residents’ assembly thinks, since it has control over the use of the official stamp. Fourth,
the street office also rarely respects the authority of the residents’ assembly. Even if the
law states that the residents’ committee is responsible to the residents’ assembly, the real
“boss” in many instances is the street office.298
5.1.1 Legislative-Executive Separation (Yixing fenshe)299
To reform the shequ democratic decision-making process, a reform known as
yixing fenshe, which translates into “separation of legislation and execution”, is being
implemented in many cities. A system of yixing fenshe is intended to create three “layers”
in a decision process. The “legislation” (yi) is divided into two parts: deliberation (yishi)
and decision (juece). Together with “execution” (zhixing or caozuo), a decision process
can be structured into three “layers” –the deliberation layer, the decision layer, and the
execution layer. Beyond this three-layered decision process there is also a “leadership”
layer (lingdaocheng), referring to the leadership position of the shequ party organization.
298
Wang Jun, “Jumin huiyi de quanli xuyao dedao zhunzhong (The Authority of the Residents’ Assembly has to be
Respected)” Zhongguo shehuibao September 21, 2006; Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ
jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu, pg. 313.
299
On general Chinese discussions on the yixing fenshe reforms, see the following sources: Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo
chengshi shequ jumin zizhi (Community Residents' Self-Governance in China), Shenyang: Liaoning renmin chubanshe
(2004), pg. 69-86; Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu, pg.
184-185, 188-192,314-315; Xu Yong, Chen Weidong, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Self-Governance in
China's Urban Communities), Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe (2002), pg. 57-60, 62-68; Tang Yalin, Chen Xianshu, “Shequ
zizhi: chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu de fugui yu zhangyang (Community Self-Governance: The Return and Expansion
of Grassroots Democracy in Urban Society),” Xueshujie (Academics in China) 6 (2003), pg. 7-22; Deng Mingfen, “Lun
shequ zizhi jincheng zhong chengshi jiceng zuzhi jianshe de xinsilu (On the New Ideas of Urban Grassroots
Organizational Construction in the Process of Community Self-Governance),” Xuexi luntan (Tribune of Study) 1
(2007), pg. 43-44. Shao Renwei, “Chengshi jumin shequ canyu de zuzhi tizhi fenxi (An Analysis of the Organizational
Structure of Community Participation by Urban Residents),” Xiandai chengshi yanjiu (Modern Urban Research) 11
(2004), pg. 22-25; Deng Quanguo & Meng Yinghui, “Nongcun cunmin minzhu juece yu chengshi jumin minzhu juece
bijiao (A Comparison of Democratic Decision-Making among Rural Villages and Democratic Decision-Making among
Urban Residents),” Guizhou shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Guizhou Normal University) 5 (2007), pg. 1-5; Shi Jun,
“Lun juweihui chongzu (On the Re-Organization of the Residents’ Committee),” Shehui kexue (Journal of Social
Sciences) 1 (2001), pg. 43-46.
174
There are two basic models of yixing fenshe. In the first model (hereafter Model
A), the residents’ committee becomes not an executive body but a deliberative body. The
execution function is now carried out by a shequ work station (shequ gongzuozhan)
staffed by professional community workers (shequ gongzuozhe). The residents’ assembly
remains the principal decision-maker. Thus in a decision process, the residents’
committee would first deliberate the matters at hand and then submit proposals to the
residents’ assembly. Once passed, direct execution of these decisions is carried out by the
community workers of the work station. Some areas in the cities of Shanghai, Harbin,
Hangzhou and Shenzhen have experimented with this model of yixing fenshe.
In the second model (hereafter Model B), the residents’ committee is designated
as an executive body and the residents’ assembly a decision making body. But there is a
new institution of “deliberative council” created to play the major role in the deliberation
process. In a decision process, the deliberative council assumes the deliberation
functions. Most of the items in a meeting of the residents’ assembly would be first
referred to the deliberative council before being voted on in the residents’ assembly. The
residents’ committee is responsible for implementing the decisions. Shenyang and
Qingdao are the cities that have used this model. The differences between the two models
are summarized in Figure 5.1.
In both models the party organization is the designated leadership core (the
subject of Chapter 6) and the residents’ assembly the principal decision-maker. I should
add two caveats here. First, in either model, yixing fenshe does not mean that the
residents’ assembly does not have some deliberation functions (rather than just decide on
things deliberated by other bodies) or that the residents’ committee does not have some
175
power in decision-making (rather than being purely an executive or deliberative organ).
Second, the two new institutions (shequ work station and deliberative council) are not
mutually exclusive. It is incorrect to think that that the work station and the deliberative
council are the defining features of Models A and B respectively. For instances, there are
examples of a Model A that also has a deliberative council that shares the deliberation
functions with the residents’ committee, and of a Model B that also has a work station to
aid the residents’ committee in the performance of the execution functions. The different
role played by the residents’ committee (deliberation or execution) is the principal
difference between the two models.
The work station and the deliberative council however are the institutional
innovations in urban grassroots democratic development that have no counterparts in
China’s rural democracy and deserve further discussion. Neither of them are anywhere to
be found in the Residents’ Committee Law. In this respect, the reforms of yixing fenshe
are way ahead of the legal framework of shequ governance. Below I will discuss more indepth the work station and the deliberative council and their different models.
5.1.1A Shequ Work Station
According to a study by the officials at the Ministry of Civil Affairs, there are
four models of shequ work station.300 In the separation model (fenshe moshi), the work
station is independent of the shequ residents’ committee. Its relationship with the
residents’ committee is one of mutual support. The community workers are recruited and
paid by the street office. In effect, the work station has the characteristics of being the
300
Minzhengbu jicheng zhengquan he shequ jianshe si ketizu, “Guanyu ‘shequ gongzuozhan’ yao liqing naxie renshi
(Several Clarifications Regarding the ‘Community Work Station’),” Shequ (Community) 2 (2007), pg. 6-9. One of the
authors of this article is the director of the office in charge of shequ jianshe at the Ministry of Civil Affairs.
176
“dispatched office” of the street office. Members of the residents’ committees are free
from many administrative burdens and duties and can spend more time and energy
deliberating on issues that matter to the shequ residents themselves. One drawback
however is that since the execution body (the work station) is in effect controlled by the
street office, the authority of the residents’ committee is also in doubt. Shenzhen is the
main city to have implemented this model.301 In the subordinate model (xiashu moshi),
the work station is to be directed by the street office and its staff (community workers)
hired and recruited by the street office, but it is to operate under the leadership of the
shequ residents’ committee and shequ party organization as well. In practical terms, it is
to be conceived as the executive organ of the residents’ committee. Some districts in
Beijing, Hangzhou, Nanjing are known to have implemented this model.
Under the vertical model (tiaoshu moshi), there is no one work station but several
“work stations”, such as shequ public security station, shequ health station, etc., each of
them being the dispatched station of a functional department. The work stations operate
under the dual leadership of their vertical bureaucratic boss (functional department) and
the residents’ committee. Finally there is the specialized model (zhuangan moshi). This
model is similar to the subordinate model described above, except that the hiring of the
community workers is done by shequ residents’ committee. It could be said that this
model of work station is most fitting to the governance structure of the standard Model A.
The Haishu district of Ningbo is a pioneer in implementing this model of work station.
301
See also Wang Dong, “Lun shequ guanlizhong jumin zizhi he zhengfu jigou de hudong (On the Interaction between
Residents’ Self-Governance and Government Organs in Community Management)” Sichuan xingzheng xueyuan
xuebao (Journal of Sichuan Administration College) 6 (2006), pg. 60-62.
177
The district government issued in 2005 issued a regulation to institutionalize the work
station system in the district.302
5.1.1B The Deliberative Council
The deliberative council (shequ xieshang yishihui) generally is chaired by the
leader of the shequ party organization. Members of the council include the chair of the
residents’ committee, selected residents’ representatives, selected representatives from
danwei stationed in the shequ, selected homeowners’ representatives and representatives
from the property management companies, officials from the street office, public security
bureau or other governmental organs, and other socially eminent persons (such as
deputies to the local people’s congress, successful businessmen and professionals,
celebrities), numbering about 10 and 15 people. The members of the deliberative council
are recommended by shequ residents and the danwei leaders in the shequ and approved
(or elected) by the residents’ assembly. Instead of an annual meeting, members of the
deliberative council are to meet quarterly and anytime necessary (fewer participants make
it easier to convene).303
Generally there are two models of the deliberative council. The first is that it is
the “substitute organ” (daixing jiguan) of the residents’ assembly when the residents’
assembly is not meeting. In this case, the deliberative council is actually quite significant,
since it is empowered to perform most of the functions of the residents’ assembly.
Nominally still a “deliberative” organ and not a “decision-making” unit, in practice it
could in fact deliberate and decide upon important matters. It also retains the supervisory
302
“Ningboshi Haishuqu shequ zhuanzhi gongzuo zhe guanli banfa [shixing] (Regulations of Professional Community
Workers in Haishu District, Ningbo City [Trial Version])” Shequ (Community) 5 (2005), pg. 20-21.
303
Xu, Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg. 59. My interviewees in Shanghai also confirmed that the
deliberative council meets at least four times in a year.
178
power of the residents’ assembly as well. The residents’ committee has to report to the
deliberative council. The deliberative council can recommend the suspension and
removal of members of the residents’ committee. Some districts in the cities of
Shenyang, Xi’an, Wuhan and Shanghai are examples of this model.304 The alternative
model is that the deliberative council is purely a “consultative body” (zixun guwen jigou).
In this case the deliberative council is less powerful and more fitting to the name
“deliberative” in its title. Its basic functions are thus consultation, coordination and
deliberation: it has no independent decision-making power and its recommendations are
for reference purpose only, without the binding force of a law.305
Whether it is the “substitute organ” model or the “consultative body” model, the
deliberative council in general serves two broad purposes. First, it is a mechanism to
formally include the political and social elite in shequ into the decision-making
process.306 Unlike the shequ activists (discussed in Chapter 4), who are mostly retirees
and elderly people whose life are oriented within shequ, members of the deliberative
council are almost exclusively people with higher socio-economic status (businessmen or
professionals) or with certain political status (district people’s congress deputies, public
security officer, party secretary) whose active life are mainly not confined within the
shequ. Even the retirees who are selected into the deliberative council had high cadre
rank before retirement and thus have more powerful political connection. The formal
inclusion of the elite is useful in the sense that the political, economic, organizational and
social connections and resources of these elite members of the society can be mobilized
304
See the case studies in Xu, Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg. 183-189, and in Lin Shangli, (ed.s),
Shequ minzhu yu zhili: anli yanjiu (Community Democracy and Governance: Case Studies), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui
kexue chubanshe (2003), pg. 198-230.
305
Deng Mingfen, “Lun shequ zizhi jincheng zhong chengshi jiceng zuzhi jianshe de xinsilu,” pg. 43.
306
Lin, Shequ minzhu yu zhili: anli yanjiu, pg. 211.
179
for purposes of shequ governance.307 Furthermore, since the shequ residents’ committee
is only a “mass self-governance organization” without a bureaucratic rank, having the
members of the elite integrated within it will increase its authoritativeness, especially
when dealing with the higher-ranked danwei within its jurisdiction.308
Second, the deliberative council is also a coordinative mechanism. With the
secretary of the party organization as its chair, and representatives from various sectors
(danwei, government, businesses, etc.) as its members, the council is a forum for the
different sectors to coordinate their operations and integrate their resources.309
5.1.2 Discussion on Democratic Decision-Making and Yixing Fenshe
In comparison to the confusing yixing heyi (legislation-execution unity) system,
the yixing fenshe reforms, whether in the mode of Model A or Model B, indeed are
successful in creating a more rational and effective shequ governance structure with
clearer division of authority and responsibility. But it is debatable whether the yixing
fenshe reforms have democratized the shequ decision-making process. In fact, instead of
strengthening democratic decision-making, the two new institutions might each have the
effect of weakening the residents’ committee and the residents’ assembly, the respective
electoral and participatory institutions in a shequ.
Although it is designed to lessen the heavy load of work of the residents’
committee, the work station might in practice also relieve some of the de facto powers of
the residents committee as well. Many work stations (especially the separation model and
307
Meng Fanwu, “Xieshang yishi: suantian kula zhenbuyi (Consultation and Deliberation: Joys, Hardships,
Difficulties) Shequ (Community) 12 (2002), pg. 21-22.
308
This is commonly known as “vertical-horizontal conflict” (tiaokuai chongtu) in China. Chapter 6 I will discuss more
about this conflict from the perspective of party organization.
309
Xu Qun, Zheng Lu, “Shequ ‘yishi weiyuanhui’ neng daiti ‘juweihui’ ma? (Can the Community ‘Deliberative
Council’ Replace the ‘Residents’ Committee’?) Liaowang xinwen zhoukang (Outlook News Weekly) 6 (2002), pg. 31.
180
vertical model) are in practice also controlled by the local government more so than by
the residents’ committee. In such instances, even if members of the residents’ committee
are elected democratically, it might not matter at all since they have in effect yielded
most of the powers to the work station. While the deliberative council is supposed to help
the residents’ assembly in deliberating important matters more effectively and efficiently,
in practice it has significantly diluted the authority of the residents’ assembly. With a
deliberative council empowered to do most of the things the residents’ assembly does, it
even becomes unnecessary for the latter to play any significant role. Since members of
the council are exclusively from the elite, this is hardly a more democratic
organization.310
Abolishing the yixi heyi (legislative-executive unity) system would help
democratize the decision-making process. But the subsequent yixi fenshe reforms have in
a way strayed away from these purposes. The full democratic potential of the residents’
assembly so far thus remains unrealized.
5.2 Democratic Management in Shequ
According to the 2005 White Paper on Chinese democracy, shequ democratic
management implies that the work of the residents’ committee and the administration of
shequ are carried out “within the framework of law.” Specifically, the White Paper
mentions two types of quasi-legal documents for shequ residents’ self-governance: the
“residents’ self-governance charter” (jumin zizhi zhangcheng or shequ zizhi zhangcheng
[community self-governance charter] in some instances) and “residents’ agreements”
(jugui minyue, jumin gongyue, or shequ gongyue [community agreements]).
310
One Chinese author criticizes the deliberative council as “illegitimate” and “impairing the real reforms of the
residents’ committee”. See Wang et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 314-315
181
The management of shequ affairs involves miscellaneous matters. The idea
behind shequ democratic management is that as a sphere of “societal self-governance”, it
is more appropriate for the residents of shequ to come up, on their own, with a set of rules
and regulations which they willingly adhere to, particularly the self-governance charter
and residents’ agreements. In rarer instances some shequ also adopt shequ managerial
rules (juti shiwu guanli guize) to institutionalize the operation of shequ institutions
(residents’ committee, deliberative council, etc.) and to regulate the public behavior of
the personnel of these institutions. For instances, there are specific managerial rules that
stipulate the procedure of disclosing the budgetary information, the management and
archiving of household files, the safeguard and use of the shequ official stamp, etc.311 In
the Laoshan Dongli shequ in Beijing, a “rule of order for shequ residents’ representatives
assembly”, “duties and obligations of residents' representatives”, “duties and obligations
of the residents’ committee members”, “duties and obligations of the members of shequ
deliberative council” and other specific managerial rules are instituted to regulate the
behavior of these shequ officials and to provide the basis for other residents to evaluate
their work and performance.312
But in general, the self-governance charter and residents’ agreements are the
standard documents required for each shequ in fulfilling democratic mangement. Article
15 of the Residents’ Committee Law stipulates that the residents’ agreement shall be
deliberated and drafted by the residents through the residents’ assembly, shall be
submitted to the relevant government authorities for approval, shall not contradict the
311
Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi, pg. 133.
Yu Xianyang, Lin Kelei, Zhu Xiaoyan, “Chengshi shequ minzhu zizhi de tiaojian yu jizhi (The Conditions and
Mechanisms of Urban Community Democratic Self-Governance)” Jiansu xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of
Jiangsu Administration Institute) 2 (2004), pg. 68.
312
182
constitutions and other national laws and policies, and shall be followed by members of
the residents’ committee and by residents. Although the Residents’ Committee Law uses
the term “residents’ agreement” (jumin gongyue), from the wording and spirit of this
article, it could be safely assumed that what is stipulated in this article of the law is the
residents’ self-governance charter. Today the term “residents’ agreement” refers to a
document different from what is intended in the law.
According to an explanation provided by an official at the Ministry of Civil
Affairs, there are four similarities and three differences between a residents’ agreement
and a self-governance charter. The similarities are that both documents are designed to
improve management of shequ affairs and regulation of residents’ behavior, both acquire
legitimacy through active participation by the residents in the drafting process, both have
certain forces of enforcement that are more authoritative than mere social norms but less
than that of a law, and both are only applicable to the residents who drafted them. The
differences between these two documents are in three points: 1) whereas the agreement
only covers one or few aspects of shequ affairs, the charter is a much more
comprehensive document that covers almost all aspects of shequ life; 2) whereas the
agreement is meant to regulate mostly the residents only, the charter is to be followed by
both shequ officials and residents; 3) since the charter affects more people and covers
more aspects, generally there are more residents participating in the process of drafting
the charter.313
5.2.1 Residents’ Agreement
313
Wang Shihao, “Shequ jumin gongyue yu shequ jumin zizhi zhangcheng youse qubie (What are the Differences
between Residents’ Agreements and Residents’ Self-Governance Charter)” Shequ (Community) 5-6 (2001), pg. 24.
183
A residents’ agreement is meant to oblige the residents to follow certain
behavioral norms agreed upon by the residents themselves. Most of the residents’
agreements are about specific trivial matters in neighborhood life (pet-keeping, littering
and spitting, car or bicycle parking, maintenance of public property, noise-making,
throwing out trash from high floors, etc.) about which neighbors have frequent argue but
which the government has little incentive or interest to interfere in.314 It therefore
specifies what kind of behavior is encouraged and discouraged (therefore a residents’
agreement will contain many provisions of “do…” and “do not…”).315 Typically a
residents’ agreement is a very short document, containing several sentences that are easy
to memorize. In some instances, it is even written in a verse form that can be sung.316
Within a shequ, the residents at each residential block or building can write a residents’
agreement for their own block or building.
The drafting of a residents’ agreement can be initiated by any resident. In an
example of the drafting process in a shequ in Shanghai, a resident came up with a draft of
a residents’ agreement for his residential building and then solicited opinions from his
neighbors through meetings of residents’ small groups or household survey. The draft
and the solicited opinions were then submitted to the residents’ committee, which
organized discussion groups and came up with a second draft and still invited residents’
314
Lu Wangda, Bao Tian, “Gongyue suixiao zuoyong da (Small Agreement with Big Influence)” Renmin ribao
September 24, 2002.
315
Wang & Bai, Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe, pg. 241-244.
316
For examples, see the residents’ agreements collected in this article, Ding Lei, Zhong Hua, “Shanghaishi Luwanqu
‘jumin gongyue’ xuandeng (Selected Compilation of ‘Residents’ Agreements’ in Luwan District of Shanghai)” Shequ
(Community) 24 (2003), pg. 38.
184
opinions on this second draft. Through several revisions the third and final draft became
the residents’ agreement.317
5.2.2 Self-Governance Charter
The self-governance charter (jumin zizhi zhangcheng or shequ zizhi zhangcheng
or other similar names) is a much more systematic, developed and comprehensive
document (this is the document that is intended in the Article 15 of the Residents’
Committee Law, despite the different term used in the law). The charter is supposedly
drafted directly by the residents and takes into account the national and intermediate
governmental policies and laws as well as local conditions of the shequ. As a quasi-legal
document, the self-governance charter in effect amounts to a “small constitution” of a
shequ.318
Since the self-governance charter is written by the residents and reflects the issues
and concerns of these residents, different localities will emphasize different things on
their charters. But in general, a self-governance charter covers the following aspects: 1)
the governance framework and organizational structure, such as the division of authority
and responsibilities between the various shequ bodies (residents’ committee, residents’
assembly, deliberative council [if there is one], residents’ small groups, etc.); 2) the
nature, rights, obligations and responsibilities of the each of these bodies and of the
members of these bodies; 3) basic rules and procedures in the management of shequ
affairs, especially the management of shequ finance. In some shequ, the self-governance
charter stipulates the relationship between shequ residents’ committee and other
317
Xie Jian, “‘Louzhu jumin gongyue’ jumin ziji ding (Residents Draft Their Own ‘Building Residents’ Agreement’)”
Shequ (Community) 23 (2006), pg. 14.
318
Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi,, pg. 132; see also Xu, Chen, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ
zizhi, pg. 170-171.
185
organizations, such as the street office, party organization, homeowners’ committee; in
other instances the charter contains stipulations on social norms such as neighborhood
relations, family and marriage, etc.319
Although the Residents’ Committee Law states that the charter is drafted in the
residents’ assembly, the procedure usually takes several steps: 1) publicizing and
educating the residents about the necessity of the charter for residents’ self-governance;
2) organizing the residents to study and discuss the national constitution and relevant
laws so that the charter will not contradict national laws and policies; 3) convening
meetings of residents' small groups for discussion by the residents’ committee; 4)
formulating the first draft in accordance with both the laws and the issues that are raised
by the residents in the meetings of residents’ small groups; 5) soliciting opinions from
shequ residents regarding the draft; 5) convening the residents’ assembly to make
changes and approval: 6) publicizing the approved draft of the charter and submitting it to
the authorities. Each household will also be mailed a copy of the charter.320
5.2.3 Discussion on the Residents’ Agreement and Residents’ Self-Governance Charter
In theory the residents’ agreement and the self-governance charter do make
management of shequ affairs more democratic –the residents are given opportunities to
participate in making the rules and regulations for their own shequ. Since these rules are
supposedly made by them, the residents should also be able to identify with and follow
these rules more willingly. Self-governance without government interference from the
319
See the self-governance charters published in the magazine Shequ. “Beijingshi Xisibeitoutiao shequ jumin
weiyuanhui zhangcheng (Residents’ Committee Charter in Xisibeitoutiao Community, Beijing)” Shequ (Community),
2-3 (2003), pg. 33-34; “Xiamenshi Huliqu Dianqian jiedao Xingleng shequ zizhi zhangcheng (The Self-Governance
Charter of Xingleng Community, in Dianqian Street, Huli District, Xiamen City)” Shequ (Community) 2 (2001), pg.
24-25. A different interpretation here is presented in Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi, pg. 132
320
Xu, Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg. 172-173.
186
outside seems plausible. However, in practice the usefulness of these documents in
raising the level of democratic management remains doubtful in many shequ.
In an article critical of the residents’ agreement published in the magazine Shequ,
the author points out that there are several flaws in the residents’ agreement. Most
residents actually do not treat the document as something that they would enthusiastically
embrace and follow but instead as another example of “a new form of propaganda by the
authorities”. Purportedly containing certain enforcement power, the residents’ agreement
in practice also has little enforcement capacity; it constrains only those who are willing to
follow it but not those who are not. The residents’ agreement in fact has little practical
usefulness in the daily life of shequ residents.321 The value of the self-governance charter
in improving democratic management also might not be as rosy as it seems. None of my
interviewees in Shanghai, including members of the residents’ committee and ordinary
residents, discussed much about the residents’ agreement and the self-governance
charter.322 Democratic management, defined as a system of self-governance based on
residents’ agreements and residents’ self-governance charter, appears to be the least
effective part among the official four elements of democracy in shequ.
5.3 Democratic Supervision in Shequ
In the 2005 White paper on democracy, democratic supervision in urban shequ is
prescribed as “practices” of “open management” in which all “important matters” in the
321
Yu Yiqing, “’Jumin gongyue’ de gongxindu weihe zubu xiajiang (Why the Credibility of the ‘Residents’
Agreement’ has been Declining)?” Shequ (Community) 23 (2006), pg. 10.
322
In a study of the villagers’ self-governance charter (the comparable document in the villages), the author
concludes that the charter reflects the will of the state more than the will of the residents. The villagers did
not actually write the initial draft of the document but instead merely commented on a “standard draft”
provided by the government. It is quite possible that in shequ the residents in fact played only a minor role
in the drafting process of the self-governance charter. See Yu Jianrong, “Shifan de qiyue (Ineffective
Contract)” Zhongguo nongcun guancha (China Rural Survey) 1 (2001), pg. 64-69.
187
work of residents’ committee shall be made public and subject to residents’ suggestions,
evaluation, supervision. The “open management” that the White Paper mentions is a form
of information disclosure system known as juwu gongkai in China. In addition to
information disclosure, democratic supervision also takes places in the form of
democratic evaluation (minzhu pingyi) of officials.
5.3.1 Information Disclosure (Juwu gongkai)
A Japanese scholar argues that increasing government transparency and
accountability and giving citizens the “right to [some] information” are important
hallmarks of the political reform initiatives of the present Hu-Wen administration.323
Despite the fact that many official secrets (particularly personnel appointments at the
high-level administration) remain inaccessible, and open violation of official secrecy
could be punished severely, the current administration is much more willing to
implement a system to disclose information related to the work of government (zhengwu
gongkai). At the grassroots level, this system is referred to as cunwu gongkai (in villages)
and juwu gongkai (in urban shequ).
Juwu gongkai is to make information regarding the finance, operations,
procedures, and policies of the residents’ committee publicly and easily accessible. Juwu
gongkai can find its legal basis in Article 16 of the Residents’ Committee Law, which
stipulates that the budgetary items of the residents’ committee should be made public and
supervised by the residents. However, other than the budget there is no consensus about
the range of information that should be made public. According to a district civil affairs
323
Kojima Tomoyuki, “China's Political Governance: Transformation from Jiang Zemin to Hu Jintao,” in
Restructuring China: Party, State and Society after the Reform and Open Door, edited by Nakagane Katsuji and
Kojima Tomoyuki, Tokyo: The Toyo Bunko (2006), pg. 210.
188
official in Shanghai, the contents of juwu gongkai should include: 1) the three-year work
target of the residents’ committee (since the normal term of office of the residents’
committee is three years); 2) the division of work responsibilities (portfolios) among the
residents’ committee members; 3) the promised work target of each member and the state
of fulfilling his/her work target; 4) the progress in implementing the resolutions passed
by the residents assembly; 5) the finances related to public affairs; 6) the processing of
those permit applications requiring the approval of the residents’ committee; 7) the list of
residents receiving social safety fund and food ration and their present conditions; 8) the
work on family planning; 9) the report of the residents’ supervisory small group; and 10)
any other aspect of the work of the residents’ committee when at least one-tenth of the
residents or one-third of the residents' representatives make such a demand.324 Similar
items are reported in the juwu gongkai implemented in some other cities such as Wuxi
and Baoji.325
In 2004, the Shenzhen city government approved a policy document on juwu
gongkai and democratic management to be practiced in the districts of Bao’an and
Longgang. In this document, the information to be disclosed is grouped into two
categories: political affairs and financial affairs. The political affairs (zhengwu) include
all policies, laws and regulations that involve residential life, the tasks assigned by higher
levels of government, family planning matters (such as plan, target, punishment fees for
violating the plan, number of violation, the use of punishment fees), the distribution of
emergency and welfare resources, the implementation of the work targets f residents’
324
Zhang Jinliang, He Zhijun, “Juwu gongkai, daodi ying gongkai xiexe? (Information Disclosure System, What
Should be Disclosed?),” Zhongguo minzheng (China Civil Affairs) 4 (2001), pg. 41.
325
“Beitang shequ juwu ‘shi gongkai’ (The Ten Items of Public Disclosure in the Communities of Beitang District),”
Wuxi ribao July 12, 2008; Liu Anshen & Cui Jindi “Baoji Weibinqu quanmian shixing juwu gongkai (Weibin district
of Baoji Comprehensively Implements the Information Disclosure System),” Zhongguo shehuibao August 26, 2004.
189
committee members, the use (construction, rental, etc.) of land, and all other important
matters that affect the interests of residents. The financial affairs include proposed
budget, property value, debt of the residents’ committee, as well as the actual incomes
and expenses, such as grants from higher authorities, collected fees, voluntary
contributions from residents or private sector, the pay and subsidies to residents’
committee members, the expenses during official duties, etc.326
The issue of land is a particular item of concern to residents of certain areas that
were originally villages, since village committees as collective entities are granted the
collective ownership right of land. In certain districts in the cities of Mianyang and
Qingdao, issues of land deals, “ownership”, compensation, profits and debts were
important items of juwu gongkai. The Mianyang municipal civil affairs department
further determines that contracts given out by the residents’ committees and the collective
economic projects in shequ have to be vigorously debated and supervised by shequ
residents.327 In the city of Shantou, the shequ in a district bordering rural areas inherited
collective ownership over certain lands, and derived rental income from these lands.
Alleged mismanagement over these lands by the residents’ committee members had
caused tension between the residents’ committees and the residents. A juwu gongkai
system was implemented so that ordinary residents were able to participate in the
326
“Shenzhenshi renmin zhengfu bangongting guanyu Bao’an Longgang liangqu chengshihua hou tuixing juwugongkai
jiaqiang minzhu guanli de yijian de tongzhi (Circular of the Opinion on promoting Residents' Committee Disclosure
and Democratic Management in Bao’an and Longgang Districts after Urbanization by the Office of the Shenzhen
People's Government),” (2004), Shenzhen Government Policy Document No.214.
327
Hu Min, “Mianyang zai quansheng xuaixian chutai shequ minzhu guanli zhidu: juwu gongkai jumin zuozhu
(Mianyang is the first in whole province to have a community democratic management system: the information
disclosure system and the mastery of the residents),” Sichuan ribao May, 9 2006; “Kaifaqu shixing juwu gongkai
minzhu guanli (Implementing Information Disclosure and Democratic Management in New Areas),” Qingdao ribao
September 17, 2006.
190
supervision of these land deals and in the decision making process by voicing their
opinions and concerns in the residents’ assembly.328
The residents’ committees (and villagers’ committees) were parts of the
distributional network of emergency relief assistance and resources in the deadly
earthquake in Sichuan province in 2008. The Bureau of Civil Affairs of Sichuan
Provincial Government specifically required making information regarding the total
amount of assistance, the distributional procedures and channels, the conditions and lists
of people receiving assistance, the re-construction plan and policies, and the official
evaluation of the performance of grassroots officials in their work on assistance
distribution, to be openly accessible through juwu gongkai and cunwu gongkai.329
Designing a juwu gongkai system involves the designation of the principal
institution that carries out the supervision work. Again, different localities have different
practices. Generally the shequ residents’ assembly is the principal supervisory body, in
which case the residents’ committee is to report to the assembly the information to be
disclosed. However, the infrequent meetings of residents’ assembly would render this
institution to be a rather weak supervisory body. In Hebei province, Shenyang and the
Jianghan district of Wuhan, the shequ deliberative council is designated as the principal
supervisory body. Outside of these institutional bodies, increasingly ordinary residents
328
Hong Yuehao, “Yi juwu gongkai chu hexie wending (Using Information Disclosure to Promote Harmonious
Stability),” Shantou ribao October 17, 2005.
329
Zhang Tao, “Sichuansheng minzhengting yaoqiu kangzhen jiuzai zhijin wuzhi shixing chun (ju) wu gongkai (The
Bureau of Civil Affairs of Sichuan Province Demands the Implementation of Information Disclosure in the Quake
Resistance Efforts),” Zhongguo shehubao June 24, 2008.
191
can also directly supervise the residents’ committee by requiring the residents’ committee
to allow access to the information under juwu gongkai.330
In some shequ, there are also the separate bodies of supervision small group and
“democratic financial management group (minzhu lichai xiaozhu)” established to do the
work of democratic supervision. The members of the supervision small groups are mostly
residents’ representatives and are to be elected. In Mianyang, the responsibilities of a
supervision small group is to make sure that all the items under juwu gongkai are made
public, to verify the accuracy of the disclosed information, and to check whether juwu
gongkai is implemented according to the proper procedures, on time and through
channels that are reachable by ordinary residents.
“Democratic financial management group” is specifically formed to supervise and
audit the finances of the residents’ committees. Again, the local practices are different
from places to places. In the Chenhua district in Chengdu, a relatively sophisticated
financial supervision system is in place in which budgetary items of shequ that involve
more than 600 yuan will need the approval of the “democratic financial small groups.” A
separate “financial supervision small groups” are formed to keep track of every spending
of the residents’ committee. Auditing is professionalized and annualized, and every
resident is reportedly able to initiate a call to audit any suspected spending.331
5.3.2 Public Evaluation (Minzhu Pingyi/Minpingguan)
330
Xu, Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg. 123. See also Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin
zizhi, pg. 138.
331
Yuan Chengmin & Liming, “Juwu gongkai, touming guanli (Information Disclosure, Transparent Management),”
Zhongguo shehuibao April 21, 2001; Hu Min, “Mianyang zai quansheng xuaixian chutai shequ minzhu guanli zhidu:
juwu gongkai jumin zuozhu (Mianyang is the first in whole province to have a community democratic management
system: the information disclosure system and the mastery of the residents),” Sichuan ribao (Sichuan Daily) May 9,
2006; Lin Feng & Che Wenbin, “Shenji shequ dangjiaren, xiang 'luanhuaqian' kaidao: Chenghuaqu wanshan chequ
minzhu jiandu jizhi, jianli yitao shequ chaiqu sheji zhidu (Audit the community authorities, say no to poor spending
decisions: Chenghua district perfects the mechanism of community democratic supervision and establishes a
community auditing system),” Chengdu ribao September 21, 2008.
192
The second aspect of shequ democratic supervision is the public evaluation of
governmental officials and residents’ committee members by shequ residents. The
practices of minzhu pingyi again vary from place to place. Some cities only have minzhu
pingyi for the members of shequ residents’ committees, while other cities practice minzhu
pingyi primarily to evaluate governmental officials other than the residents’ committee
members. Cities that have introduced institutional innovations in public evaluation
include Wuhan, Beijing and Tianjin. Their experiments and experiences are reported in
the following sections.
The Jianghan district in the city of Wuhan has been in the forefront in reforming
the structure of shequ governance for many years, with many innovative ideas and efforts
to make its shequ more autonomous. It positions the government-shequ relationship as
one of “guidance and service [from the government]” and “assistance and supervision
[from the shequ]” (zhidao yu xiezhu, fuwu yu jiandu). From this principle various
governmental organs (district functional departments and street offices) are to become
less involved in the work of shequ residents’ committees. To ensure the governmental
organs would adhere to this principle, it introduced a new policy initiative designed to
facilitate and eventually institutionalize the evaluation and assessment of governmental
officials by the public, the annual minpingguan (literally translated as public evaluation
of officials) activity, in 2000. What was innovative about the idea of minpingguan was
the empowerment of ordinary residents and making government officials and even the
whole departments subject to open public evaluation, thus increasing the sense of being
the “public servants” among government officials. Properly implemented, minpingguan
193
could be an effective weapon for residents to remove underperforming and bad officials,
or at least to force these officials to improve their performance.
Two detailed studies of the 2002 minpingguan activities show that the whole
activity of minpingguan consisted of three parts: the evaluation of certain governmental
officers sent to shequ by the representatives from shequ, the evaluation of the street office
by shequ residents’ committee members, and the evaluation of selected governmental
bodies at the district level by officials at the street offices and shequ.332
In the first evaluation, the governmental personnel to be publicly evaluated
include shequ police officers, family planning officers, sanitation and hygiene officers, as
well as city cleanliness maintenance officers (shirong ganbu).333 Traditionally, the works
and responsibilities of these officers (apart from the police officer) are taken care of by
shequ residents’ committees. This is still the case in many other shequ residents’
committees. In the reforms of Jianghan district, the residents’ committees were relieved
of these governmental tasks and instead the government departments at the district level
will have to send their own officers to the shequ to do these jobs. The evaluators
representing the shequ attending the minpingguan meetings include members of the
residents’ committee, secretary of shequ party organization, residents’ representatives,
members of the shequ deliberative council, and representatives from certain concerned
groups such as the elderly, women, and families on social security support, as well as
some local people’s congress deputies.
332
Unless specified otherwise, the following discussion is based on Xu, Chen et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg.
408-418; and Li Fan, “Cong Jianghanqu de shequ pingyi zhengfu kan shequ minzhu de fazhan (The Development of
Community Democracy from the Perspective of Community Evaluation of Government in Jianghan District) in
Zhongguo jiceng minzhu fazhan baogao 2002 (A Report on the Grassroots Democracy in China 2002), edited by Li
Fan, Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe (2003), pg. 428-436.
333
These officers are examples of the community workers of the “vertical model” mentioned above in the “democratic
decision-making” section.
194
In the minpingguan meeting, the governmental officers would first make formal
reports of their work in the past year to representatives from the shequs. The
representatives would then voice their opinions. Then they would evaluate each of these
cadres based on their attitude, performance, respect of the law, etc. with a vote. Officers
who received more than 20 percent “unsatisfied” votes from the evaluators in the meeting
would be considered for dismissal from office.334
The second part of minpingguan basically was a similar format, with street office
officials making reports of their work in the past year to the evaluators who consisted of
members of shequ residents’ committees and secretaries of shequ party organizations. A
following question-and-answer session allowed the evaluators to have the opportunity to
question and criticize the work of the street office officials, often sharply. Sometimes
street office officials would agree to make immediate changes in the meeting. After that,
the evaluators would vote on the performance of the street office as a whole based on
several categories, including “reforming street office-residents’ committee relations and
improving shequ self-governance”, “infrastructure construction for shequ jianshe”,
“ensuring shequ decision making autonomy on shequ matters”, “ensuring shequ
autonomy on financial management”, “supporting and developing shequ fuwu
(community services)”, “payments of subsidies to shequ workers and office expenses”,
and “maintaining a diligent, clean and honest administration” The street offices that
received more than 20 percent of unsatisfied votes would be singled out by the district
government for reform and reorganization.335
334
335
Li Fan, “Cong Jianghanqu de shequ pingyi zhengfu kan shequ minzhu de fazhan,” pg. 429.
Ibid, pg. 429-430.
195
The third part involved the evaluation of selected district-level government
departments and offices by officials from both the street offices and shequ. In the 2002
evaluation meeting, the seven departments to face public evaluation were public security,
health administration, municipal management, culture and physical education, civil
affairs, criminal justice, and family planning. The evaluators would evaluate based on the
work reports prepared by these departments. Again, the officials at the government
departments that received the most “unsatisfied” votes would be considered for demotion
or dismissal from office.336
The basic format of minpingguan in the following years remained similar, but the
composition of the evaluators and evaluated individuals and governmental bodies could
be different from year to year. For example, in the 2003 minpingguan, the list of
evaluated governmental personnel sent to shequ expanded to include officers responsible
of managing migrant population and social security. The evaluators representing the
shequ also were also more inclusive, with the migrant workers, retirees and poor families
all had representatives sent to minpingguan meetings as their evaluators. There was even
an evaluator specifically representing pregnant women. There were also some procedural
improvements of minpingguan meetings, such as lengthening the face-to-face interaction
between the evaluators and the evaluated, as well as improving voting methods and
process.337 In 2004, the city of Wuhan began the implementation of its main shequ
jianshe plan called “Action 883” (883 xingdong jihua, 883 referring to the number of
336
Ibid, pg. 430.
Chen Weidong, “Minpingguan rang jumin chengwei gongmin (Public Evaluation of Officials Let Residents Become
Citizens)” Shequ (Community) 2-4 (2004), pg. 11-12.
337
196
residents’ committees in Wuhan). Minpingguan was discontinued as a separate activity
but was fused into the plan and to be implemented throughout the city.338
Minpingguan in Jianghan district of Wuhan is the one that is most well-known in
China. Some other cities also have similar activities. In Fangshan district of Beijing, 13
district-level government departments were selected for minpingguang evaluation, in
which they would be evaluated on a 100-point scale (10 points for establishing a working
system with the residents’ committee, 20 points for helping to solve the problems
encountered by shequ residents, 30 points for fulfilling the department’s own
responsibilities and duties in relevance to the shequ, 15 points for guiding and helping the
residents’ committee in improving the quality of shequ life and meeting residents’ needs
and demands, 25 points for the level of satisfaction among residents regarding the
services provided by these departments through having their own agents sent to the shequ
rather than instructing the residents’ committee to perform such services. The evaluators
basically consisted of residents’ representatives.339 In the city of Tianjin, minpingguan
was also organized in Hexi district. Here, minpingguan consisted of two parts: evaluation
of the members of shequ residents’ committees by shequ residents’ representatives, and
evaluation of officials at the street offices by members of shequ residents’ committees.
Similar to the minpingguan activities reported above, the evaluators took a vote after
minpingguan meetings. Individuals and offices that receive substantial “unsatisfactory”
votes would then have to find out their problems and improve their work, especially for
338
Zheng Hangsheng, “Wuhan tese the hexie shequ jianshe moshi –‘883 xindong jihua’ (The Wuhan Model of
Harmonious Community Construction –‘Action Plan 883’)” Xuexi shibao July 17, 2006.
339
Tan Sufen, Xu Shuling, “Jumin daibiao rixin ‘minpingguan’ (Residents’ Representatives are Enthusiastic about
Public Evaluation of Officials)” Shequ (Commnity) 1-2 (2004), pg. 15.
197
the officials at the street offices. The leaders of the street offices as well as the secretaries
of the street party organizations, however, were not among the evaluated.340
In Fujian province, the provincial government decided to promote shequ
democratic evaluation (shequ mingzhu pingyi) meetings throughout the province
beginning in 2003. Shequ residents’ committees were the primary objects in these
evaluation meetings, while the evaluators consisted of residents’ representatives,
members of shequ deliberative council, deputies to the local people’s congresses and
local people’s political consultative conferences, and a select group of residents. The
meetings were organized and chaired by shequ party organizations.341 The district of
Shanhaiguan in the city of Qinhuangdao in Hebei province was also reported to have
conducted similar democratic evaluation meetings for members of shequ residents’
committees as well as the leaders of shequ party organizations, by shequ residents’
representatives and the representatives of party members in the shequ respectively.342
5.3.3 Discussion on Democratic Supervision (Juwu gongkai and Minpingguan)
Juwu gongkai is reportedly credited for improving social stability, governance
and legitimacy. Although this is far from the “freedom of information” policies common
in Western societies, juwu gongkai represents a correct first step to open up the
information space. This is especially important since informing the public or letting the
public have access to information related to governmental affairs has not been a tradition
of the ruling culture of the communist party. The public is at least acknowledged to have
340
Li Xiuyun, Yang Shichen, “‘Minpingguan’ dailai de xinqixiang (The New Atmosphere Brought by the Public
Evaluation of Officials” Shequ (Community) 5 (2005), pg. 26.
341
Lin Zhen, “Fujian quanmin tuiguang shequ minzhu pingyi huodong (Fujian to Promote Activities of Community
Democratic Evaluations Throughout)” Zhongguo shehuibao May 21, 2003.
342
Yang Zhifang, Zhao Fang, “Qinhuangdaoshi Shanhaiguanqu quanmian qidong shequ pingyi huodong (Shanhaiguan
district of Qinhuangdao to Start Community Evaluation Activities)” Zhongguo shehuibao January 4, 2008.
198
the right to information. Overall juwu gongkai is still quite undeveloped as a form of
democratic supervision. For example, although in most instances it requires the residents’
committee to open its book for inspection, there are no rules in terms of what would be
the consequences if the residents’ committee refuses to do so. In this sense, the
effectiveness of juwu gongkai largely depends on the willingness of the residents’
committee to vigorously implement it. Residents are still not yet institutionally
empowered to play a larger role of democratic supervision under the present models of
juwu gongkai.
The minzhu pingyi or minpingguan activities appear to be a better mechanism of
democratic supervision. A Chinese scholar concludes that minpingguang serves four
important functions: 1) institutional complementary function, in which it complements
and strengthens the existing design of shequ democracy; 2) information integration
function, in which it provides an alternative channel of information flow outside of the
bureaucratic structure, so that officials and governmental leaders have better knowledge
about what shequ residents think of their work; 3) communicative function, in which it
increases communication, and therefore trust and understanding, between officials and
ordinary residents; and 4) civic training functions, in which it contributes to increased
participation and involvement in public affairs among shequ residents, and also raises
residents’ attention to and awareness of public issues.343
Thus, not only does minpingguan enhance democratic supervision, it has the
potential of training the critical skills of democratic self-governance. With the
government officials being subject to evaluation, some vertical accountability towards the
343
Chen Weidong, “Minpingguan rang jumin chengwei gongmin (Public Evaluation of Officials Let Residents Become
Citizens)” Shequ (Community) 2-4 (2004), pg. 12.
199
residents is also being created. The government’s goal of reforming the bureaucracy to
make it more efficient and people-friendly could also be met by minzhu pingyi.344 Equally
significant is that this reform could lead to the de-institutionalization of the long-time
dominance of the residents’ committees by the street offices. However, notwithstanding
these positive outcomes, when there is no electoral mechanism (apart from the residents’
committee members who face election), the residents have no power to decide the
removal of a particular official. Perhaps this is the reason why democratic evaluation of
officials is more valuable in the absence of an electoral mechanism.
5.4 The Three-Meeting System (Sanhui zhidu) in Shanghai345
In the final part of this chapter I would like to focus on a unique “three-meeting
system”, which was pioneered by the Luwan district government in Shanghai in 1999 and
copied in some other parts of the city subsequently. The “three meetings” refer to the
decision hearing meeting (juece tingzhenhui, or simply tingzhenhui), conflict mediation
meeting (maodun xietiaohui, or simply xietiaohui), and governance evaluation meeting
(zhengwu pingyihui, or simply pingyihui) meetings. The designers of this “three-meeting”
system intended the system to be an innovative mechanism that combines “the leadership
344
Deng Quanguo, Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi, pg. 138.
Unless otherwise noted, the discussion on the “three-meeting” system draws from the following sources: Zhong
Haizhen & Wu Jianchu, “Yong zhidu beiyanghao zuofeng: Shanghai Luwanqu shixing juece tingzheng, maodun
xietiao, zhengwu pingyi ‘sanhui’ zhidu jishi (Using Institution to Improve Work Style: A Record of the Decision
Hearing, Conflict Mediation, and Governance Evaluation ‘Three-Meeting’ System in Luwan District of Shanghai),”
Zuzhi renshibao December 20, 2001; Yan Zhenghong, et al., “‘Sanhui’ zhidu de minxin: Shanghai Luwan jianwenlu
(‘Three-Meeting’ System Gains Support: An Account in Shanghai’s Luwan District),” Renmin ribao June 12, 2002;
“Chujin jumin zizhi, shixing ‘sanhui’ zhidu (Promoting Residents’ Self-Governance, Implemeting ‘Three-Meeting’
System),” Zuzhi renshibao June 21, 2005; “Shequ minzhu zizhi de baohushan -pingyihui, xietiaohui, tingzhenghui
zhidu (The Protective Umbrella of Community Democratic Self-Governance),” Shequ (Community) 7-13 (2002), pg.
28-29; Qin Jing, “Shanghai Luwan jianli le shequ ‘sanhui’ zhidu (Shanghai’s Luwan Establishes a Community ‘ThreeMeeting’ System),” Shequ (Community) 1-1 (2002), pg. 17-18; Xiong Chunmao, “‘Sanhui zhidu’ huejie shequ maodun
(‘Three-Meeting’ System Resolves Community Disputes),” Shequ (Community) 7 (2006), pg. 18-19; Wang Qi,
“‘Sanhui’ zhidhu de shijian yu sikao (The Thought and Practice of the ‘Three-Meeting’ System),” Shanghai dangshi yu
dangjian (Party History and Party Building in Shanghai) 11 (2007), pg. 40-43; Wang Zhenhua, Chen Yi, “‘Sansan
zhi’: Shanghaishi Luwanqu shequ guanli moshi de xintansuo (The “Three-Three” System: A New Approach to
Community Management in Luwan District, Shanghai),” Dangzheng luntan (Party & Government Forum) 11 (2004),
pg. 35-36.
345
200
of the party, the people’s mastership of their own affairs, and the rule of law.” These
meetings also accordingly reflect the “mass-line” tradition of the Communist party, and
in practice they have the effect of strengthening shequ democratic decision-making,
management and supervision.
An official of the party organization department of Luwan district party
committee summarizes the “three-meeting” system as “hearing in advance, decisionmaking more democratic and scientific”, “mediation during the process, achieving the
balance between different concerned parties”, and “evaluation afterwards, leaving the
evaluation of work performance to the mass”.346 Of course, this does not mean that
mechanically each decision in a shequ has to go through these three steps. A well
formulated decision made with public participation through a hearing meeting could
mean that a mediation meeting is not necessary since the concerned parties have already
resolved their disagreements in the hearing meeting. A mediation meeting can be
convened to deal with an issue not arising from the implementation of a decision by the
residents’ committee but from private actions taken by the residents themselves that
could jeopardize the interests of other residents. The evaluation meeting is not called to
evaluate the effectiveness of each decision but the overall performance of the members of
the residents’ committee. Nevertheless, the basic idea of the system is that there will be
some public participation in the decision processes of formulation, implementation and
evaluation in a shequ.
A policy document on the three-meeting system by the Luwan district
government provides some details of the working of these meetings. The evaluation
346
Wang Qi, “‘Sanhui’ zhidhu de shijian yu sikao,” pg. 40-41.
201
meeting is similar to the minpingguan meetings discussed above. The shequ residents’
committee is responsible for organizing an evaluation small group, with membership
selected among residents’ representatives and led by the chief of the shequ party
organization. The evaluation meeting is to be held annually, and the evaluated bodies
include the street offices, the dispatched offices and personnel of functional departments
(such as local public security bureaus, local offices of taxation, local environmental and
health administration bureaus, local housing authorities, community health centers,
among others), the property management companies, and community workers hired by
the residents’ committee. These bodies are evaluated according to their performances in
implementing their tasks and duties and their contribution to shequ jianshe. Those who
are to be evaluated are required to submit their annual working plan to the evaluation
small group each January. The evaluation meeting is usually held around the end of a
year.
Fifteen days before the meeting, each evaluated body is to submit its written work
report. After receiving the report, the evaluation small group will study the report and
conclude with its own written report. In the evaluation meeting, the evaluated bodies will
then report to the evaluation small group about their performances, issues to be tackled,
and suggestions for improvement. The evaluation small group will hold discussion on the
written and oral reports of the evaluated bodies, and come up with grades (good, average,
bad) for each body. The grades will be submitted to the superiors of these evaluated
202
bodies and will become their references for job evaluations, promotions, bonuses, or
demotions.347
The xietiaohui (mediation meetings) can be convened to mediate and resolve
issues that involve 1) the common interests of all shequ residents, 2) private disputes
between shequ residents and/or danweis, 3) conflict of interests among shequ residents,
and 4) any other issue that the concerned parties are willing to resolve through the
meeting. An important purpose of these meetings is to prevent potentially destabilizing
issues from escalating into more serious incidents. The residents’ committee members
with the security and mediation responsibilities are generally in charge of convening and
presiding over the meetings. The participants of the meeting include the residents’
committee members with the security and mediation portfolios, chair of the residents’
committee, community police officers, the shequ party leadership, certain street office
officials, and the residents or organizations that are involved in a dispute.
In the meeting, the disputing parties will first be given the chance to express their
viewpoints and arguments. The presiding residents’ committee members will then
proceed to make further inquiries about each party and try to find the common ground
and find solutions to these agreements. If the mediation is successful, the disputing
parties are to sign a written mediation agreement. The residents’ committee is then
responsible for supervising the implementation of this agreement. If the mediation
meeting is unable to resolve the conflicts between the disputants, the matter will be
referred to governmental authorities. However, if one of the disputing parties insists on
having the matter resolved through the mediation meeting, the meeting will be held at the
347
“Shequ minzhu zizhi de baohushan -pingyihui, xietiaohui, tingzhenghui zhidu (The Protective Umbrella of
Community Democratic Self-Governance),” Shequ (Community) 7-13 (2002), pg. 28.
203
maximum of three times before it is determined that the matter cannot be dealt with at the
meeting and requires judicial or administrative intervention.
The last of the three-meeting system is the hearing meeting (tingzhenghui).348 A
hearing meeting with the residents should be held before any decision or project that
involves public interests are made by the residents’ committee and/or local government
departments, although in practice most of the hearing meetings are about pending
government’s projects. The hearing meeting is not open to all residents. The number of
attendants of the meeting is to be determined jointly by the residents’ committee and the
relevant government departments. The attendants should have “good political and
cultural qualities, familiarity with the relevant issues and the ability to offer constructive
and representative suggestions.” Those who are directly affected by the concerned
decisions can attend the hearing meeting as well. A clerk shall be specially hired to
record the meetings of the hearing.
A hearing meeting usually is initiated by a city or district government department
when a proposed project will affect shequ residents (for example, approving a new road
construction crossing a neighborhood), in which case the department shall notify the
residents’ committee within 7 days. The residents’ committee shall work out the time,
place, the clerk, and the qualified attendants of the hearing meeting. Representatives from
the government department will first make oral reports to the attendants regarding the
issue, and after discussion among the attendants and the officials, a preliminary written
report summarizing residents’ opinions, proposals, and proposed revisions of the original
government plan shall be presented at the end of the meeting. After the meeting, the clerk
348
The 2005 White Paper on democracy also mentions hearing as an element that would enhance democratic decisionmaking.
204
will write a report based on the preliminary materials and submit such a report to the
district governmental authorities. Within 15 days of such submission, the district
authorities will report back to the residents’ committee regarding the final decisions.349
According to a press report, in two years since instituting the “three-meeting”
system the whole Luwan district had had 2231 mediation meetings, with 1881 of the
meetings successfully resolved the issues (84% success rate), 436 hearing meetings,
among them a total of 157 meeting resulted in having the residents’ opinions and
proposals being accepted by the government, and 1028 evaluation meetings, in which a
minority of officials had been demoted or removed because of residents’ criticisms.350 In
another rough estimate, in the seven years since instituting the “three-meeting system”,
the whole Luwan district had had more than 6000 mediation meetings, more than 1700
hearing meetings, and more than 2100 evaluation meetings.351
5.4.1 Discussion on the “Three-Meeting” System
An official argues that sanhui zhidu (“three-meeting” system) allows residents
direct, frequent and comprehensive political participation.352 Taken together, these
meetings do provide residents the opportunities to express their own voice regarding
different issues in their own shequ and to check and monitor government officials. The
hearing meeting is a particularly novel approach to make residents and officials to work
together in coming up with a proposal acceptable to both. The evaluation meeting has
similar positive functions with the minpingguan activities discussed above. And the
349
“Shequ minzhu zizhi de baohushan -pingyihui, xietiaohui, tingzhenghui,” pg. 29.
Zhong Haizhen & Wu Jianchu, “Yong zhidu beiyanghao zuofeng: Shanghai Luwanqu shixing juece tingzheng,
maodun xietiao, zhengwu pingyi ‘sanhui’ zhidu jishi (Using Institution to Improve Work Style: A Record of the
Decision Hearing, Conflict Mediation, and Governance Evaluation ‘Three-Meeting’ System in Luwan District of
Shanghai),” Zuzhi renshibao December 20, 2001
351
Wang Qi, “'Sanhui' zhidhu de shijian yu sikao,” pg. 41.
352
Ibid, pg. 41.
350
205
mediation meeting allows to residents to deliberate, debate and sort out their own
differences. In the process it also enhances trust among residents and has the effect of
building up social capital and strengthening citizenship. Considering that these
institutional innovations are created in an authoritarian polity, they do have the potentials
of creating a more responsive, accountable and democratic system of public
administration.
There is a danger, however, that these meetings are nothing more than putting up
a “democratic” face. For instance, it is quite conceivable that government officials could
have initiated a hearing and yet have already decided that nothing would be changed. In
such a case, the hearing meeting is nothing more than a required procedure to be
completed. The residents would have few options too when the outcome of the hearing
meeting did not favor them. Similarly, in a mediation meeting, the government officials
could have decided to favor a particular party and force other parties to make
accommodation. The mediation meeting in this sense only legitimizes the official’s
preference.
Conclusion
This chapter describes and analyzes the shequ institutions designed to embody the
processes of democratic decision-making, democratic management, and democratic
supervision. These institutions are also meant to create a more democratic public
administration and governance. For democratic decision-making, the yixing fenshe
reforms and the creation of new bodies (the shequ work station and the deliberative
council) have rationalized and improved the decision process. Nevertheless, the role of
the residents’ assembly, the primary institution for resident’s direct participation, remains
206
to be strengthened and reformed. For democratic management, the effectiveness of
residents’ agreements and the residents’ self-governance charter are still quite weak.
Residents’ participation in the drafting of these documents is still quite limited. For
democratic supervision, the institutions of “information disclosure” and “public
evaluation” are important tools and channels for residents to check and supervise official
power. “Public evaluation” is especially well-developed in certain cities, with well
defined procedures and real consequences for those officials who failed the evaluation
tests. Finally, the “three-meeting” system in Shanghai also holds great promise in
increasing residents’ level of participation and deliberation. Residents are offered the
opportunities to participate and contribute their input in a hearing meeting, solve their
disputes in a mediation meeting, and hold officials accountable in an evaluation meeting.
207
Figure 5.1 Two Models of Yixing Fenshe
Model A
Residents’ Assembly
(Decision Layer)
Shequ Party Organization
(The Leadership Layer)
Shequ Work Station
(Execution Layer)
Residents’ Committee
(Deliberation Layer)
Model B
Residents’ Assembly
(Decision Layer)
Shequ Party Organization
(The Leadership Layer)
Residents’ Committee
(Execution Layer)
Deliberative Council
(Deliberation Layer)
208
Chapter 6: Accommodating the Party or Accommodating Democracy:
Shequ Party Building and Shequ Democratic Development
The concept of shequ party building (shequ dangjian) was being articulated about
the same time of the formulation of the shequ jianshe policy. Although, in contrast to its
rural counterpart (the Organic Law of the Villagers’ Committee), the 1989 Residents’
Committee law contains no provisions on shequ party organizations, in China, any
discussion of democratic development cannot leave out the party. In fact, the party’s
leadership position in the shequ is affirmed in the Ministry of Civil Affairs 2000 policy
document “Opinion on Promoting Shequ jianshe Nationwide.”
In this chapter I will first discuss the concepts of party building and grassroots
party building, and then proceed to discuss two key elements in the shequ party building
program, and finally the relationship between shequ party organization and shequ
democratic development.
6.1 The Concepts of Party Building and Grassroots Party Building
The party occupies a special place in the state-society relations in China. The
party and state are in many ways institutionally mingled. Therefore, many analysts use
the term “party-state” as an analytical and descriptive model for the Chinese political
system. On the other hand, many Chinese scholars also argue that the communist party is
a “societal” organization, in the sense that it originated from a social movement and it
continues to represent and articulates societal/class interests. Society is therefore the
“base area” of the party. It provides the necessary “space” for the party to mobilize,
209
organize and consolidate support.353 The “party building” program in essence can be
conceptualized as a wide range of party self-strengthening measures designed to ensure
the party remains capable of leading both the state institutions and societal forces, as well
as competent in the performance of the numerous tasks of governance, social integration,
and mobilization. Party building also requires party members to be well trained in
ideology, organizational skills and organizational discipline. The ultimate goal is to
construct a well-disciplined, organizationally sophisticated, and highly competent mass
party. The exact theoretical contents and practical consequences of “party building,”
however, are flexible, with each generation of leadership adding their own
interpretations.
6.1.1 Party Building: From Revolutionary Party to Governing Party
Shiping Zheng argues that there is an inherent structural conflict in a
“revolutionary party-state” such as China, in which the two entities (party and state)
follow different organizational logics: the party is a perpetually revolutionarymobilization organization, while the state is an inherently conservative bureaucratic
institution.354 During the Mao years, there was stronger party prevalence over the state.
“Party building” program was skewed toward strengthening the party’s mobilization
capacity. As a result, the building up of state institutions suffered during this period, and
the political system was inherently unstable. With the post-Mao emphases on the rule of
law, political stability, technocracy, and merit-based recruitment of government staff, the
party building program also had to readjust to reflect the new challenges.
353
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The Residents’
Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee in Urban
Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg. 228.
354
Shiping Zheng, Party vs. State in Post-1949 China: The Institutional Dilemma, New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press (1997), pg. 16.
210
On the other hand, in terms of party-society relations, the party also faces
challenges in post-Mao era as well. With the advent of private and foreign enterprises, the
party no longer monopolizes organizational activities in the societal sphere. Increasingly
many newly established social organizations, registered and non-registered alike, are less
susceptible to the party’s control and influence.
The party building program in the reform era therefore aims to fundamentally
transform the party from being a “revolutionary party” to a “governing party.” Especially
for the present Hu-Wen leadership, the “strengthening of governing capacity” is the
critical mission of the party in the new century. In the Fourth Plenary Session of the 16th
Central Committee in 2004, the party approved the “Decision on Strengthening the
Building of Governing Capacity of the Party,” a document that reflects the Hu-Wen
team’s approach to governance and party building. The document demands the party to
comprehensively improve its ability to guide and manage the “socialist market
economy,” to “govern through scientific and democratic method,” to promote “oversight
of power” in the decision-making process, to build up the rule of law, to construct
“harmonious” society, and to elevate theoretical and ideological training among the
cadres.355
At the provincial and regional levels, the “strengthening of the governing
capacity” of regional party leaders include the enhancement of their ability to maintain
social stability, particularly their ability to respond to both natural and political crises.
Other important tasks include ideological-political education of party members,
355
Chen Mingxian, “Zhizheng nengli: wending fazhan yu minzhu zhizheng de liangnan (Governing Capacity: The
Dilemma of Stable Development and Democratic Governing)” in Hu Wen tizhi de pingheng zhanlue: siwei yu zhengce
(The Balancing Strategy of Hu-Wen Administration: Modes of Thinking and Policy), edited by Shin-in Chu, Taipei:
Yuanjin jijinhui (2005), pg. 52-23.
211
promotion of “scientific development”, and the management and improvement of cadres.
In essence, the “strengthening of governing capacity” is the basis for the realizing the
long-sought goal of creating a “well-off society” (xiaokang shehui).356
These new elements added to the party building program since the end of Mao’s
era fundamentally changes the party. As a “governing” party, it behaves more like
“conservative-bureaucratic” institution than a “revolutionary-mobilization” organization.
With this transformation, the party reduces the structural conflicts mentioned by Zheng,
and stabilizes the political system.
6.1.2 Grassroots Party Building
There are three basic levels in the party’s organizational hierarchy: the center,
regional (encompassing provincial, municipal, and county units) and grassroots units.
Grassroots party organizations are established in enterprises, villages, government’s
organs, schools, research institutes, streets and shequs, social organizations, companies of
Peoples’ Liberation Army, and any other types of grassroots organizations. Depending on
the number of party members in a particular grassroots unit, different types of grassroots
party organization can be formed. According to a party organizational handbook, a local
unit that has more than 3 but fewer than 50 party members, has to establish a party branch
(dang zhibu). A local unit that has more than 50 but fewer than 100 party members, has
to establish a party general branch (dang zhongzhi). If it has more than100 members, it
has to establish a party base-level committee (dang jiceng weiyuanhui). Collectively they
356
Zhonggong zhongyang zuzhibu dangjian yanjiusuo ketizu, “Guanyu jiaqiang difang dangwei zhizheng nengli
jianshe de diaoyan baogao (A Report on the Construction of Governing Capacity of Regional Party Committees)” in
Zhongguo xianshi wenti yanjiu qianyan baogao 2005-2006 (A Report on the Frontier Research on China’s Present
Issues 2005-2006), edited by Li Huibin & Xue Xiaoyuan, Shanghai: Huadong shifan daxue chubanshe (2006), pg. 63101.
212
are all referred to as “grassroots party organizations”357. Each grassroots party
organization is led by a leadership committee elected by the party members under its
jurisdiction. Within each grassroots organization, there is also a smaller, unofficial unit –
the party small group or party cell (dang xiaozu). Any three party members can form a
party small group. Since it is not an official unit, the activities and works of the small
group have to be directed and led by the party branch.358
Article 8 of the Constitution of the Communist Party of China stipulates that
every party member, regardless of party rank, shall have an organizational relationship
(zuzhi guanxi) attached to a grassroots party organization. Every member shall attend and
participate in the activities of the organization, such as the “democratic life meetings”
(minzhui shenghuohui).359 No party member shall be allowed to exempt him- or herself
from these organizational activities. Article 31 spells out the eight principal
responsibilities of a grassroots party organization, including 1) disseminating and
implementing party’s basic policies; 2) organizing study sessions on Marxist theories for
party members; 3) educating, managing, supervising, and serving its members; 4)
maintaining a close ties with the mass; 5) supporting the creative work of the party
members and the masses in the service of reform and socialist modernization; 6) training
and recruiting talented activists; 7) ensuring the strict observation of laws and
357
Therefore in this chapter I use the generic term shequ party organization rather then the more specific shequ party
committee, shequ party general branch or shequ party branch.
358
Xin shiji dangde jiceng zuzhi gongzuo shiwu shouce (A Practical Handbook of Grassroots Party Organizational
Work in the New Century) Shanghai: Shanghai renminchubanshe (2003) pg. 55-70.
359
In “democratic life meeting” (minzhu shenghuohui), party members would report about their political thinking,
study government policies and Marxist theory, engage in criticism and self-criticism, etc. For more discussion on the
party’s organizational activities, see Xin shiji dangde jiceng zuzhi gongzuo shiwu shouce, pg. 90-96.
213
administrative discipline among party and non-party cadres; and 8) directing party
members to resist unhealthy practices and to struggle against criminal activities.360
The Chinese Communist Party has always stressed the importance of its
grassroots organizations. It views them not only as effective mechanisms to penetrate and
mobilize the socio-political energy of the mass, but also the foundational blocks of the
party’s organizational edifice. For instance, the former Chinese leader Jiang Zemin once
warned about the dangers of weak grassroots party organizations that are ineffective and
divided, which would cause the “mountains” of “Party’s leadership and government, of
the Party’s entire work, and of the socialist state’s political power” to collapse.361
With the current Hu-Wen administration’s emphasis on governing capacity,
grassroots party building programs in the country are re-structured around this concept as
well. For example, the Organization Department of Fujian Provincial Party Committee
highlights six particular aspects of the governing capacity of the grassroots party
organizations. They include (1) development, (2) serving the mass, (3) competitiveness,
(4) execution, (5) management, and (6) control. Development refers primarily to the
ability to promote and guide economic development.362 Serving the masses would
demand that the party members to become activists and volunteers. Competitiveness is a
particularly novel idea, which means that grassroots party members should be subject to
electoral pressure in order to enhance their own qualities and to consolidate the party’s
governing status. Execution refers to the strict following and successful implementation
of the policies and instructions from the party hierarchy by grassroots party members.
360
Zhongguo gongchandang zhangcheng (The Constitution of the Communist Party of China) Beijing: Renmin
chubanshe (2007), pg. 28-29, 45-46.
361
Jiang Zemin, Jiang Zemin on the “Three Represents” Beijing: Foreign Languages Press (2003), pg. 168-170.
362
This is more applicable to village and enterprise party organizations, whose job would include promoting economic
development, but less so far other types of grassroots party organizations.
214
Management means that grassroots party organizations have to manage and supervise
their own party members well, making sure that they are well qualified and able to
maintain the “advanced nature” of the party. Finally, control demands grassroots party
organizations to be a vigilant and effective force in responding to and resolving
emergency crises and conflicts between cadres and mass. These grassroots party
organizations are the key force upholding social stability.363 Especially, grassroots party
organizations should be able to “demonstrate effective combat capability” when facing
“political turmoil,”364 meaning that they are the first line of defense in facing potentially
subversive or destabilizing activities, such as “mass incidents”, collective visits to
complaints bureaus, and anti-party activities.
There is also a new dimension of the grassroots party building program that
emphasizes the party’s “social nature” (shequ shuxing). As mentioned above, there is a
theoretical view in China that the party has a dual nature (political and social) that
justifies its active intervention in the society. Thus, although the state is withdrawing
from the social sphere, in tandem with the current official thinking to create “small
government, big society,” political power in the form of the party continues to expand its
influence in the society. The “social nature” of the party resulted in some service-oriented
elements in grassroots party building –interest mediation and societal attentiveness
(shehui guanhuai). Under interest mediation, grassroots party organizations should
ensure effective communication between different interests. They should coordinate and
363
Zhongong Fujian shengwei zuzhibu ketizu, “Gonggu dang de zhizheng diwei yu jiaqiang dang de jiceng zuzhi
zhizheng nengli jianshe wenti dianyan baogao (A Report on the Consolidation of Party’s Governing Status and the
Strengthening of the Construction of Governing Capacity of Grassroots Party Organizations)” in Zhongguo xianshi
wenti yanjiu qianyan baogao 2005-2006, pg. 107-111.
364
Zhonggong zhongyang zuzhibu dangjian yanjiusuo ketizu, “Guanyu jiaqiang difang dangwei zhizheng nengli
jianshe de diaoyan baogao,” pg. 97.
215
mediate disputes and conflicts. Under societal attentiveness, the party should be attentive
to and care about the spiritual life (thus working on ideological education), the political
life (grassroots self-governance and democracy), and the daily life of the people (socialcultural activities and helping the vulnerable groups).365 The idea that grassroots party
organizations should be more “socially attentive” illustrates the efforts of the party to
transform itself, to become less “revolutionary,” and therefore less political. At the same
time, it has transformed itself into a more pragmatic, welfare-oriented and service-guided
organization, while remaining broadly paternalistic.
At present, the party has millions of these grassroots party organizations
established in enterprises, villages, shequs, etc. Although the effectiveness of these
grassroots party organizations vary considerably among different areas, they still
constitute an important part of the governing structure in present-day China. Among
these grassroots party organizations, shequ party organizations generally tend to be
weakest. The shequ party building program is thus meant to boost their leadership in the
shequ.
6.2 Shequ Party Building: Organization and Integration366
Before the 1990s, the work of grassroots party building in the cities was
concentrated in the danwei, reflecting the Leninist principle of organizing the party’s
365
Lin Shangli, Gongchandang zhizheng fanglue (Governing Strategy of the Communist Party), Shanghai: Shanghai
shehui kexueyan chubanshe (2002), pg. 60-62.
366
For some general Chinese discussions on shequ party building, see Gao Hanrong, “Shequ dangjian yu woguo jiceng
shehui zizhi zuzhi de chonggou (Community Party Building and the Reconstruction of Grassroots Self-Governance
Organization)” Gansu shehui kexue (Gansu Social Sciences) 3 (2003), pg. 42-44; Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian
yanjiu ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian (Community Party Building in Urban China) Shanghai:
Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2000); Han Jun, “Xinshiqi shequ dangjian yu Zhongguo gongchandang de xiandaihua
(Community Party Building in the New Era and the Modernization of the Chinese Communist Part)” Xinjiang shehui
kexue (Social Sciences in Xinjiang) 3 (2005), pg. 24-27; Li Chaoyang, “Chengshi shequ dangjian: jiaqiang dangde
jianshe de zhanluexing xuanzhe (Urban Community Party Building: A Strategic Choice to Strengthen Party Building)”
Tianjin shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Tianjin Normal University) 5 (2005), pg. 1-5.
216
base units on the basis of production units, government organs, and service units. The
idea was to embed the party in different sectors of the urban society. Through integrating
these sectors under the party’s leadership the party would be able to extend its reach into
the deepest corners of the society. Therefore, party’s base units that were established on
the basis of residential areas (street offices and residents’ committees) had only a
marginal and peripheral role in much of the organizational history of the party in the
cities.
However, the reform of the danwei system beginning in the mid 1990s changed
that. Many party members were victims of corporate reorganization, bankruptcy, merger,
and layoffs during the reform of the danwei system. Many of them also became
unattached to any party organization –the so-called “pocket party members” (koudai
dangyuan).367 Furthermore, among the vast migrating labor force in the cities there is also
a large number of party members who have no contacts with their party organizations.
How to organize and mobilize these types of party members became a challenge for the
party.
Another issue is the emergence of the so-called “two-new” organizations
(liangxin zuzhi), referring to private or foreign enterprises and some newly established
social organizations (such as NGOs, foundations, charities). Most of these organizations
are concentrated in shequ residential areas and have very few or no party members at
all.368 The party’s influence is particularly weak in these organizations.369 There is also
367
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian, pg. 115. They are called
pocket party members because they keep their party certificates in their own pockets, i.e. no organizational attachment.
368
This is in contrast to the state-owned enterprises and the traditional social organizations, such as unions, writers’
associations, disabled persons’ associations, women’s associations, etc. in which the party continues to have a much
stronger presence and leadership.
217
the question of how to integrate and coordinate the work of two types of grassroots party
organizations in the cities –shequ party organizations and danwei party organizations
stationed in the shequ. All these challenges mean that the party has to employ a new
approach and method. The shequ party building program is thus formulated to tackle
these challenges and to maintain the overall political and organizational leadership of the
party in society.370
In the mid 1990s, some cities, most notably Shanghai, had already began the work
on shequ party building, but the central push for the shequ party building program began
only in 2000, around the time of the formulation of shequ jianshe policy. In a May 2000
speech on the “theory of three represents”, Jiang Zemin’s own “theoretical contribution”
to Chinese Marxism, he highlighted the significance of building up party organizations in
urban shequs , especially their “promotion of socialist culture and ethics, ideological and
political work among the masses, comprehensive maintenance of public order,
community services, [and efforts to maintain] close ties with the masses.”371
The 2000 Ministry of Civil Affairs document on shequ jianshe also affirms the
role of the shequ party organization in shequ jianshe. In addition, in November 2004 the
Central Organization Department of the CCP issued the directive “Opinions on Further
Strengthening and Improving the Street and Shequ Party Building Work”.372 Just as the
369
According to one estimate, as of the end of 2007, only 4.1% of the employees of “non-public” enterprises are party
members, only 8% of these enterprises have organized party presence. Cited from Wu Xiang, “Guanyu chengshi shequ
dangjian de lilun sikao (Theoretical Thinking about Urban Community Party Building)” Jingji yu shehui fazhan
(Economic and Social Development) 6:10 (2008), pg. 65.
370
Chu Jianyi, “Goujian shequ dangzuzhi lingdao hexin de baozhang jizhi (Constructing the Mechanisms that Ensure
the Core Leadership Role of Community Party Organizations)” Lilun tantao (Theoretical Investigation) 5 (2005), pg.
151.
371
Jiang Zemin, Jiang Zemin on the “Three Represents”, pg. 23-24.
372
“Zhonggong zhongyang zuzhibu guanyu jinyibu jiaqiang he gaijin jiedao shequ dangde jianshe gongzuo de yijian
(Opinions by the Party Central Organization Department on Further Strengthening and Improving Street and
Community Party Building Work)” Renmin ribao November 22, 2004.
218
2000 Ministry of Civil Affairs document has been serving as the basic guideline for
shequ jianshe, this document by the Central Organization Department is also the official
policy guideline for the shequ party-building work. Both the Ministry of Civil Affairs
document and the Central Organization Department documents also specify the basic
responsibilities of the party organizations at the grassroots levels. Table 6.1 summarizes
the basic responsibilities laid out in these two documents.
Shequ party building, therefore, involves a number of elements, such as
strengthening the quality of party leadership and cadres in shequs, reorganization and
integration, expanding the range of activities and services provided by shequ party
organization, ideological and theoretical training of the party members, etc.373 Among
them the organization and integration work are the backbone of shequ party building.
6.2.1 Organization
As the speech by Jiang indicates, an important part of shequ party building is to
organize the party members in the shequs, many of whom had become “pocket party
members”, and to establish the party’s organizational presence in the shequs.374 Any
shequ with more than 3 party members should organize a party branch or party cell. The
organizational relationship of those retired, layoff, and mobile party members should be
transferred to shequ party organization. Fresh college graduates with party membership
also should have their organizational relationship with the party established in shequs
373
Kazuko Kojima and Ryosei Kokubun, “The ‘Shequ’ Construction Programme and the Chinese Communist Party” in
Bringing the Party Back In: How China is Governed, edited by Kjeld Erik Brodsgaard & Zheng Yongnian, Singapore:
Eastern Universities Press (2004), pg. 226-232.
374
The CCP is quite interested in the community centers organized by the activists and members of the People Action
Party in Singapore. The local party activists in Singapore play the crucial role of mobilizing popular support for the
ruling party. They construct sophisticated local networks that penetrate into every corner of a neighborhood,
strengthening the influence and competitiveness of the ruling party. See Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu
ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian, pg. 158.
219
before they find employment. The goal is to have at least one party organization for every
shequ (yiju yizhi in Chinese, literally “one residents’ committee, one branch”). Once
organized, the party will then have a formal organizational presence within the shequ and
could fulfill the leadership role. In addition, the party organization should also continue
recruiting talented elements from the mass. All these efforts are aimed to widen the
organizational reach of the party deeper into the corners of the society. As of 2004, 93%
of the shequ have at least one party organization.375
6.2.1A Party Organization at the Street-Office Level
Organizational work of shequ party building is not confined to the shequ level
only. An important part of it is to strengthen and re-organize the authority of the streetlevel party organization. Within the party hierarchy, the shequ party organization
occupies the lowest rank. For many of the high-ranked danwei party organizations
stationed in a shequ, the authority of the shequ party organization over them is extremely
weak. In many instances, street-level party organizations are likewise outranked by
danwei party organizations. The high-ranked danwei party organizations command huge
resources, but have no incentive to assist the streets and shequ in the work of shequ
jianshe. On the other hand, lower-ranked party organizations are given many
responsibilities but without the authority to fully mobilize the necessary resources. This
vertical (danwei)/horizontal (streets & shequ) conflict is indeed common in China’s
administrative system –the so-called “tiaoquai chongtu” (vertical-horizontal conflict). In
order to strengthen the authority of shequ party organizations, many cities reorganize the
375
Zhan Chengfu (ed) Shequ jianshe gongzuo jinzhan baogao (The Report on the Progress of the Work of Community
Construction) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 4.
220
street-level party organization, instituting a “street party work committee” (jiedao
danggongwei) in place of the regular “street party committee” (jiedao dangwei).376
The “street party work committee” is different from a regular party unit. The
“work committee” is a dispatched organ of the district party committee. Leaders of the
“work committee” are directly appointed from above, not elected from below. Other than
the responsibilities specified in the party’s constitution, the “work committee” is also
entrusted with specific responsibilities and functions by the district committee. The term
of office for leaders of the “work committee” is also longer than the leaders of a regular
party organization.377 The composition of the leadership of the “work committee”
generally includes some representatives from danwei party organizations. For instance, in
Shanghai, the leadership of a street party work committee consists of 11 to 13 members;
among them are directors of street-level public security bureaus and representatives from
the party organizations in government’s functional departments and other danwei.378
Through the “work committee” system the vertical and horizontal authorities are
connected and integrated. Since the authority of the street party work committee comes
from the district party committee, it is empowered to “mobilize the resources and [to]
coordinate the related work of the various offices and units” within the street’s
jurisdiction,379 at least those with comparable rank at district level. In such a way, under
the overall leadership of a street party work committee, shequ party organizations could
376
The vertical-horizontal conflict is also the main subject in the next section, here I will discuss only the nature of
street party work committee.
377
Interestingly Mainland Chinese sources rarely discuss the nature of the work committee and its differences with a
regular party organization. The above discussion is based on a Taiwanese source, see Lu Jing, Zhonggong dangzheng
yanjiu lunwenji, shangji (Essays on the Study of Chinese Communist Party-State, First Volume) Taipei: Zhonggong
yanjiu zhazhishe (1999), pg. 51-52.
378
Wang Guoyi, “An ‘1+3’ tizhi tiaozheng shequ dangzuzhi shezhi (Adjusting Community Party Organizational
Setting According to the ‘1+3’ System)” Zuzhi renshibao September 7, 2006.
379
Akio Takahara and Robert Benewick, “Party Work in Urban Communities” in The Chinese Communist Party in
Reform, edited by Kjeld Erik Brodsgaard and Zheng Yongnian, New York, NY: Routledge (2006), pg. 160.
221
become more forceful when dealing with high-ranked danweis stationed in their
jurisdiction.
6.2.1B Party Organization below the Shequ Level
Below the shequ level, party’s organizational penetration is to be extended to
blocks and buildings –the so-called “loudong dangjian.” (Also referred to as louyu
dangjian or louzu dangjian. All these terms refer to party building work in residential or
commercial blocks and buildings.) Let say there is a shequ with more than 100 party
members (all with their organizational relationship attached to the party organization of
this shequ). The party members who are scattered in different residential blocks and
buildings will be organized into party branches or cells in their respective blocks and
buildings. This will create a shequ party network with the shequ party committee as the
center and the smaller units as its tentacles extending to each block and building.380 Many
of the activists and leaders of residents’ small groups (see Chapter 4) are also party
members, and sometimes residents’ small groups coincide with the smaller party
branches and cells. These party members in the most basic units play the leading role in
mobilizing their neighbors to participate in various shequ activities, doing ideological
work, as well as being the eyes and ears of the party. In a district in Shanghai, party cells
are required to ensure that there are “no illegal activities…, no security incidents, no
superstitious activities” in their building and bocks.381 On the other hand, these smaller
380
For some of the empirical examples of loudong dangjian, see the following press reports. Chen Guangming, Wang
Bingkun, “Loudong dangzhibu, dangjian yan chujiao (Block Party Branch, Extended Tentacles of Party Building)”
Xinhua meiri dianxun June 26, 2006; Dong Yongqian, “Xigu tuichu shequ dangjian xinmoshi (Xigu’s New Model of
Community Party Building)” Lanzhou ribao October 24, 2008; Huang Guoliang, Xiao Suping, “Xihuqu shequ dangjian
chuangxinlu, xiaoxiao loudongzhang yinyin zhu minqing (New Path of Community Party Building in Xihu District,
Block and Building Leaders Serving the People)” Xi’an ribao November 11, 2004.
381
Zhonggong Shanghaishi Jiading quwei zuzhibu, “Kaizhan ‘louzu dangjian’ jianshe hexie shequ (Carrying out
‘Building Party Building’, Constructing Harmonious Community)” Dangzheng luntan (Party Government Forum) 9
(2007), pg. 11-12.
222
units are also the most basic units of the party to “serve the people.” They pay visit to
sick neighbors, mediate family and neighborhood disputes, and organize some cultural
activities and exercises for the old and retired people.382 Through the street party work
committee, yiju yizhi (one residents’ committee, one party branch), and loudong dangjian
(block party building), a vertical party network ranging from the street to each residential
block is instituted.
6.2.1C Party Organization in “Two-New” Organizations
Organizational penetration also extends to the so-called “two-new” organizations.
Party building work in these organizations in a minimum sense would thus involve
organizing the party members working in these organizations (no matter how few they
are) into branches and cells, and recruiting prospective talents.383 One effective way to
extend party building in these organizations is again through “louyu dangjian” (block
party building), in this case establishing party organizations in commercial buildings.384
For example, whereas a company might have only one or two party members, a
commercial building with several companies might have enough party members to
establish an organizational presence. The commercial buildings are generally located
outside of the jurisdiction of residents’ committee, and therefore it is the responsibility of
the street party work committee to extend party building work to these organizations. But
for those buildings located within shequs, sometimes the shequ party organization is
entrusted to do party building work there. Louyu dangjian is reportedly a successful
strategy of grassroots party building. In Shanghai, the latest statistics show that, due to
382
Wu Deyu, “Zenyang dangyao yiming louyuan dangzhibu shuji (How to Become a Good Secretary of Building Party
Branch)” Shequ (Community) 24 (2006), pg. 28-29.
383
Xin shiji dangde jiceng zuzhi gongzuo shiwu shouce, pg. 744.
384
Ou Xiaoming, “Louyu dangjian yu shequ dangjian de hudong (Mutual Interaction between Building Party Building
and Community Party Building)” Dangzheng ganbu luntan (Cadres’ Tribune) 11 (2005), pg. 9-10.
223
louyu dangjian, there were 12941 party organizations established in the “two-new”
organizations in 2008, a 320% growth over 5 years, and that more than 205,000 party
members belonged to “two-new” party organizations.385
If all urban shequ in China are successful in the organizational work of shequ
party building described above, then not only will the party’s base would become more
consolidated and entrenched, the party may also be able to re-establish its ubiquitous
presence in urban society.
6.2.2 Integration
Another important element in the shequ party building program is to integrate the
danwei party organizations and members. Although the reorganization of street party
work committees has achieved some results, by no means does this reorganization
institutionally guarantee the full cooperation of all danwei party organizations. Provincial
and municipal units are still ranked much higher than the street party work committee.
Securing their cooperation can be a struggle for the street party work committee. On the
other hand, the dispatched organs of district government’s departments at the street level
are in theory integrated under the authority of the street party work committee, but it is
not as easy as it seems. Each of these organs still has to follow the leadership and
command within the vertical bureaucratic channel, under the notion of “dual leadership”
(shuangchong lingdao). How the “dual leadership” concept operates is still not quite
institutionalized and it is not uncommon that the authority of the street party work
committee to be sidelined.
385
Hong Meifen, “‘Liangxin’ zuzhi dangyuan 5nian zeng liangbeiduo (Party Members of “Two-New” Organizations
Growing More than Double)” Jiefang ribao June 26, 2008.
224
Finally, there are many party members whose organizational relationships are
attached to the danwei outside of their shequ (the Chinese term is zaizhi dangyuan). For
these party members, their obligation to participate in party’s organizational activities is
being fulfilled in their own danwei, not in the shequ. They are not even required to reveal
themselves as party members in shequ. Many of them are indeed uninterested in the work
and activities of shequ party organization, but the shequ party organization has
traditionally no authority over them.386
The problems described above are commonly encountered when carrying out
shequ party building work in many cities. In order to better coordinate and integrate the
horizontal party organizations (shequ and street) and vertical party organizations
(danwei), the 2004 Central Organization Department document suggests establishing
some kind of “party building coordination mechanism” what would give the horizontal
party organization more powers. Horizontal party organizations can request mobilization
of the resources commanded by vertical party organizations. Some cities had already
experimented with this kind of integration reform before the issuance of the 2004
document.
In Beijing, a “party building coordination committee” is established at the street
level with its branches extended to the shequ level. The “coordination committee” is an
386
Wu Wei, Chen Richang, “Shequ dangjianzhong ‘tiaokuai chongtu’ maodun de huajie (Solving the Problem of
‘Vertical-Horizontal Conflict’ in Community Party Building)” Gansu xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Gansu
Administration Institute) 3 (2004); Xu Yong, Chen Weidong, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Self-Governance in
China's Urban Communities), Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe (2002), pg. 261-265. According to one estimate, on average
only 30% of the party members in a shequ have their organizational relationship attached to shequ party organization,
60% of the party members are the so-called zaizhi dangyuan, and about 10% are still “pocket party members.” See
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian, pg. 265. The organizational
department of Guizhou provincial committee estimated that only 0.37% of the party members in the province have their
organizational relationship attached to shequ. See Shengwei zuzhibu zuzhichu, “Wosheng chengshi shequ dangjian
gongzuo diaocha (Investigating Urban Community Party Work in the Province)” Dangdai Guizhou (Guizhou Today) 6
(2003), pg. 31.
225
attempt to transition the organizational system of grassroots party building from having
the vertical and horizontal party networks separated to having an “integrated horizontalvertical party networks, with the horizontal party organizations in charge” (tiaokuai jiehe,
yikuai weizhu). According to one survey, at the end of 2002 all street offices in Beijing
have established the “coordination committees.” A total of 3084 danwei party
organizations have joined the coordination committees, among which are 451 centrallevel danwei party organizations.387 Shanghai also has similar mechanisms at the street
level, with different titles such as “shequ party building joint conference” or “shequ party
building research society.”388
The integration work is more difficult than the organization work of shequ party
building. As the authors of the Beijing survey cited above acknowledge, crucial to the
success of the “party building coordination committee” is the support of the danwei party
leaders. In another party report, it is recognized that whether these mechanisms are able
to mobilize danwei party members and resources depends on the personal relationship
between danwei party leaders and street party leaders. The “street party work committee”
on paper commands huge authority, but there is a lack of an institutionalized guarantee
that it actually wields such authority.389
It is still too early to judge whether shequ party building as a whole accomplishes
the intended goals. The weaknesses of shequ party organizations are frankly
acknowledged in a number of Chinese publications. At present, many shequ party
387
Beijing chengshi shequ dangjian ketizu, “Beijingshi chengshi shequ dangjian zhuangkuang diaocha (A Survey of
Party Building in Beijing’s Urban Communities)” Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems) 4 (2003), pg. 66.
388
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian, pg. 254; Wang Bangzuo
et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili, pg. 252.
389
Jiangshusheng dangde jianshe xuehui, Taizhoushi dangde jianshe xuehui, “Guanyu shequ dang zuzhi lingdao
tizhideng jige wenti de gaige gouxiang (Ideas of Reforming the Community Party Organization Leadership System and
Other Issues)” Dangde shenghuo (Party’s Life) 2 (2007), pg. 16-19.
226
organizations are still far from having the different aspects of “governing capacity”
emphasized by the present leadership. A Chinese official highlighted several main
problems of shequ party building, criticizing it for being overly focused on the
quantitative aspect (expansion of party members, party organizations and party
activities), and paying inadequate attention to the political and organizational
performance and capabilities of many of these party organizations. Actual participation
by party members was not as active and passionate as assumed, while the organizational
activities were impractical and irrelevant. Party members also complained that they had
too much obligations to fulfill. General social indifference toward shequ party
organizations and their activities was still prevalent. Some party organizations became
hollow once key leaders moved to other places. The lack of cohesiveness among newly
established party organizations was not unusual; and although some party organizations
were being successfully established and consolidated, others were failing and
disintegrating.390
Notwithstanding the mixed results of the program of shequ party building, the
role of the party organization as the “core leadership” in shequ governance is still
affirmed in national documents. How party organization might affect shequ democratic
development and vice versa will be discussed in the next section.
6.3 Shequ Democracy and Shequ Party Organization
390
Liu Jiyuan, “Shequ dangjian you liangde leiji xiang zhide tisheng jieduan zhuanbian yanjiu (A Study of the
Transition of Community Party Building from Quantitative Accumulation to Qualitative Improvement)” Zhonggong
Shijiazhuang shiwei dangxiao xuebao (Journal of the Party School of Shijiazhuang Committee of CCP) 10:2 (2008),
pg. 12-13.
227
Some scholars interpret the weakness of shequ party organization as beneficial to
shequ democratic self-governance.391 This incompatibility view rests on the assumption
that as a Leninist organization, the party is bound to follow instructions from above.
Therefore, the stronger the party organization is, the more likely that democratic selfgovernance in a shequ is insignificant. Unsurprisingly, the mainstream view in China
argues for the leadership of the party organization in the development of grassroots
democracy. Although the party organization is the “core leadership” in a shequ, it does
not directly interfere with the decision making process. Its main job is to ensure that the
decisions made and carried out by the residents’ committee or residents’ assembly do not
contradict the overall national and local policies and laws. Furthermore, the leadership of
the party is also necessary so that destabilizing forces in society would not have a chance
to seize on the opening up of democratic space to create political and social instability.
Democratization has to be orderly, and shequ party organizations are the “stabilizing
force” in the process of democratic development.392
The relationship between shequ party organization and shequ democratic
development, however, is complicated. In Chapter 4, it was noted that the party
organization has the ability and motive to interfere at each stage of the election process. It
could be argued that the party’s manipulation and interference is detrimental to
democratic reforms of the electoral systems. On the other hand, the party is also
391
Xu Yong, “‘Lushe jueqi’ yu ‘dushi tupo’: Chongguo chengshi shequ zizhi yu nongcun cunmin zizhi bijiao (‘Green
Uprising’ and ‘Urban Breakthrough’: A Comparison of Urban Community Self-Governance and Rural Villagers’ SelfGovernance in China)” Xuexi yu tansuo (Study and Exploration) 4 (2002), pg. 36.
392
Xie Xiaochun, Bu Dengxue “Shequ dangjian: shequ jiceng minzhu jianshe de jishi (Community Party Building: the
Foundation of Community Grassroots Democratic Construction)” Dang de jianshe (Party Building) 3 (2007), pg. 2526; Hu Hui, “Lun jumin zizhi shijiaoxia goujian chengshe shequ dangjian gongzuo xingeju (On the Construction of a
New Framework of Urban Community Party Building from the Perspective of Residents’ Self-Governance)” Zhongguo
gongchandang (Communist Party of China) 10 (2007), pg. 100-103.
228
instrumental in the mobilization of residents to participate in residents’ committee
elections. A survey on Shanghai residents shows that party members are generally more
active and willing to contribute to shequ jianshe than non-party members.393 Some
analysts suggest that without the supportive role played by the party organization, shequ
democratic development would not have proceeded so healthily and smoothly.394 The
party members in this sense are playing the “exemplary role” (xianfeng jiaose) in
electoral participation and mobilization.
Another example of the complicated picture of the relationship between party and
democracy in shequs is the so-called “two-committee” problem. The nature of the
problem is which organization is the “boss”? Is it the residents’ committee, which is
popularly elected (no matter how flawed the electoral procedure is), or the shequ party
organization, which is not popularly elected but privileged to perform the leadership role
in the shequ?395 Although the ideal design of the party organization is that it is not to
interfere in the decision-making process and involve itself in the day-to-day affairs of
running the shequ, in reality the exact division of responsibilities and authorities between
the two bodies is never clear. Whether democracy should accommodate the party, or
whether the party should accommodate democracy, is a tough question in the democratic
development in shequs. So far, there are two main approaches to resolving the problem:
(1) incorporating the leadership of the shequ party organization with the residents’
393
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu (ed.) Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian, pg. 166.
Gu Jianjian, “Zhuanxingqi shequ dangjian gonzuo de zhelidian: juminqu dangzhibu jianshe (The Main Aspect in
Urban Community Party Building Work during Transitional Era: Building of Party Branch in Residential Areas)”
Shanghai dangsi yu dangjian (Shanghai Party History and Party Building) 6 (2001), pg. 54. Two foreign scholars also
conclude with the observation that “the leadership role of the party is indispensable for an effective operation of the
[shequ]”, cited in Akio Takahara and Robert Benewick, “Party Work in Urban Communities,” pg. 169.
395
This problem is not unique to shequs, conflicts between villagers’ committees and village party organizations are
not uncommon as well.
394
229
committee, and (2) reforming the shequ party organization to make it more
democratically accountable to non-party members.396
6.3.1 Incorporating the Leadership of the Shequ Party Organization with the Residents’
Committee
Partly borrowing from rural experiences, there are strong suggestions to fuse
shequ party organization and shequ residents’ committee (neizhihua).397 This is achieved
through two methods: 1) the secretary of the shequ party organization is also the chair of
the residents’ committee, a practice known as “yijiantiao” (literally “one shoulder
carrying [all responsibilities]”); and 2) members of the leadership committee of the shequ
party organization are concurrently holding positions in the residents’ committee, a
practice known as “jiaocha renzhi” (cross-holding of office positions). Incorporating both
organizations is the approach favored by the national leadership. The 2004 Central
Organization Department document encourages cross-holding of positions between shequ
party leaders and members of the residents’ committee, and that shequ party secretary
should also become the chair of the residents’ committee through elections.
In early 2006, the Ministry of Civil Affairs also issued a directive on residents’
committee elections that encourages cross-holding of office positions. In this document,
it suggests that party members who are interested to run for positions in the party’s
leadership should first get elected as members of the residents’ committee before being
nominated as candidates in party elections. Those who are unable to get elected as
members of the residents’ committee should not be nominated in party elections,
396
It should be pointed out that both approaches have their origins in village practices. See “‘Liangpiaozhi’, ‘liangtui
yixuan’ yu ‘yijiantiao’ de chuangxinxing (The Innovativeness of ‘Two-Ballot System’, ‘Two Nomination One
Election’ and ‘One Shoulder Carrying’) Shehui zhuyi yanjiu (Socialism Studies) 6 (2007), pg. 73-76.
397
Xu Yong, Chen Weidong, et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi, pg. 274-278.
230
especially if it is the position of the party secretary. As for party members who are
already members of the residents’ committee, they should run for leadership positions of
the party in party elections.398 Both yijiantiao and jiaocha renzhi are meant to achieve
“structural integration” in which residents’ committee members overwhelmingly are
party members.399
As of 2004, 89% of the chairs of the residents’ committee throughout the country
were party members.400 This statistic, however, does not tell us whether these party
members were also party secretaries or not. Table 6.2 provides some of the data on
yijiantiao and jiaocha renzhi in selected provinces and cities in the years 2003-2007.
From the table we can see that the incorporation approach is indeed quite successful.
About half of the residents’ committee members were party members.401 While in Beijing
42% of the chairs of the shequ residents’ committee were party secretaries, other
provinces and cities reported more than half of their shequ residents’ committee chairs
also concurrently served as party secretaries, with the city of Nanjing reporting a 90%
rate of yijiantiao.
Theoretically speaking, incorporating the two bodies could lead to greater
democratic accountability between the shequ party organization and shequ residents.
Under this approach, the party secretary and other shequ party leaders have to stand
before the test of public opinion and popular elections. As the above-mentioned 2006
398
“Minzhengbu guanyu zuohao 2006nian shequ jumin weiyuanhui huanjie xuanju gongzuo de tongzi (A Directive by
the Ministry of Civil Affairs on the Election Work of Residents’ Committees in 2006)”, collected in Zhan Chengfu
(ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of Election Work of Community
Residents’ Committee) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 68,75,84,100,108-109
399
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu, pg. 173.
400
Zhan Chengfu (ed) Shequ jianshe gongzuo jinzhan baogao (The Report on the Progress of the Work of Community
Construction) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2005), pg. 5.
401
This pattern is confirmed in the two residents’ committees in Shanghai that I have conducted interview. Both
residents’ committees have 50% party members.
231
Ministry of Civil Affairs directive spells out, those who failed the test of residents’
committee elections should not be allowed to contest in party elections. The party indeed
would have to accommodate democracy. From a practical perspective, incorporating the
two bodies also strengthens the residents’ committee. Party members in the residents’
committee could use their resources and connections in the party to help the work of the
residents’ committee.402
However, incorporating the two bodies could also lead to the subordination of the
residents’ committee by the party organization. The high percentage of yijiantiao raised
the suspicion that this is the unwritten required “quota”.403 One would not be surprised to
learn if the party organizations had dominated and manipulated the election process to
achieve this quota. There are critics of this approach as well from a different perspective.
Increasingly line between the shequ party organization and the residents’ committee is
blurred. The unintended consequence is actually weakening the shequ party organization,
since now it would have to involve itself in the detailed daily administrative affairs in the
shequ. The authority of the shequ party organization in fact has to depend on the
effectiveness of the residents’ committee. It now also has less time to strengthen its own
organizational and integration work.404
6.3.2 Inner-party Democratic Reforms at the Shequ Level
402
This point was made to me by a residents’ committee chair I interviewed in Shanghai in November 2007.
According to an official at the Ministry of Civil Affairs, many local governments have imposed the 70% quota of
yijiantiao in village committee elections, a practice known as “yidaoqie” (literally “one knife cut”) in China. It is
conceivable that many street officials also similarly impose such quota in shequ residents’ committee elections. This
official disagrees with such practice and discourages imposing the quota. See Liu Feng, “Moba ‘yijiantiao’ biancheng
‘yidaoqie’ (Do Not Make ‘One Shoulder Carrying’ Becomes ‘One Knife Cut’) Zhongguo minzheng (China Civil
Affairs) 9 (2002), pg. 45.
404
Zhang Baofeng, Xiandai chengshi shequ zhili jiegou yanjiu (A Study of the Governance Structure of Modern Urban
Communities), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 248-249; see also the discussion by Kazuko Kojima
and Ryosei Kokubun, “The ‘Shequ’ Construction Programme and the Chinese Communist Party,” pg. 230-232.
403
232
To boost the “democratic legitimacy” of shequ party organizations, a number of
cities have also experimented with some institutional innovations to democratize the
shequ party organizations. Although the leadership at various levels of the party
hierarchy is supposed to be “elected,” in practice control and appointment from above are
much more likely the norms. The inner-party electoral system basically is nothing more
than a formality process to confirm the selection already made through the Nomenclature
system. In the shequ, the street-level party officials would nominate the candidates of
shequ party elections, and the party members in an “election” confirmed the selection.
A reform known as gongtui zhixuan (literal translation is public nomination and
direct election) thus has been implemented in some cities to democratize the electoral
process. Gongtui zhixuan originated from the elections of party chiefs in rural villages, it
aims to increase participation by party members and the public and competition between
candidates. There are different models of gongtui zhixuan, but all of them, as the name
gongtui zhixuan suggests, involves ending the monopolization of nomination by party
officials and allowing for direct election by party members.405 296 shequ party
organizations in Shanghai are reported to have carried out gongtui zhixuan reforms.406
Other cities reported to have experimented with gongtui zhixuan include Beijing,
Shenzhen, Ningbo, Nanjing, Dalian, Chengdu, etc. Similar to village gongtui zhixuan
reforms, many gongtui zhixuan reforms in urban shequs also let the non-party residents
have a say in the election process.
405
Hong Meifen, “Tuiguang ‘gongtui’ kuoda ‘zhixuan’ (Promoting ‘Public Nomination, Expanding ‘Direct Election’)”
Jiefang ribao March 5, 2008.
406
Hong Meifen, “Houxuanren bubian gongtui, chengshu de jinxing zhixuan (Candidates Commonly Public
Nominated, Direct Election Carried out Maturely)” Jiefang ribao September 3, 2008.
233
The most common practice of gongtui zhixuan is to allow nomination by shequ
party members (jointly or self-nomination) and non-party residents’ representatives.
Street party officials then decide from the preliminary nominees who would become the
formal candidates. Party members will then directly elect the secretary and other shequ
party leaders. In some instance, candidates are not necessarily restricted only those party
members whose organizational relationship are attached to the shequ only. For instance,
in order to encourage the participation of danwei party members, a district in Beijing
allows nominating danwei party members to run for the election of shequ party
organization.407
In a district in the city of Sanmenxia in Henan province, a similar model called
“santui zhixuan” (three nominations and direct election) allows shequ party members,
non-party residents’ representatives, and representatives from danweis and businesses to
nominate the candidates. This is another effort to integrate better the relationship between
shequ party organization and danwei party organizations.408 In a Shenzhen district, the
“santui yiping yixuan” (three nominations, one evaluation, and direct election) model
allows for organizational nomination, joint nomination by party members, and selfnomination. The participation of non-party residents is in the “democratic evaluation”
meeting of the preliminary nominees, in which these nominees are evaluated by the party
407
Wu Gaobin, et al. “Yici kuoda dangnei minzhu de shengdong shijian (A Lively Practice of Expanding Grassroots
Inner-Party Democracy)” Huangshi ribao July 7, 2008; Zhang Weifang, et al., “72ge shequ dang zuzhi banzi ‘gongtui
zhixuan’ (72 Community Party Organizations with “Public Nominations, Direct Elections)” Ningbo ribao March 8,
2009; Nie Qiao, “Woshi shouci shishi ‘gontui zhixuan’ (First Implementation of ‘Public Nomination, Direct Election’
in the City)” Dalian ribao April 21, 2008; Zhao Zhihui, Fangqiang, “‘Gongtui zhixuan’ changsheng shouwei ‘80hou’
shequ dangwei shuji (‘Public Nomination, Direct Election’ Results in the Election of a ‘Post-80” as Community Party
Committee Secretary)” Nanjing ribao March 17, 2009; Sheng Ruowei, “Gongtui zhixuan, xuanchu manyi dangjiaren
(Public Nomination and Direct Election, Electing a Good Leader)” Renmin ribao May 20, 2009; Wu Pinghua, Han
Qinghua, “Chengdu: shequ ‘gongtui zhixuan’ poti jiceng minzhu zizhi (Chengdu: Community ‘Public Nomination and
Direct Election’ a Breakthrough of Urban Grassroots Democratic Self-Govenance)” Zhongguo jingji shibao December
4, 2007.
408
Wu Hua et al., “Hubinqu: qunzhong xuan ‘zuzhi’ (Hubin District: the Mass Elect the ‘Organization’” Henan ribao
July 1, 2007.
234
members and non-party residents’ representatives, before the street party officials
determine the final list of formal candidates.409
Apart from gongtui zhixuan, there are also some reform measures to increase
democratic supervision of shequ party organizations. One example is the “shequ party
oversight council” (shequ dangwu jiandu weiyuanhui) established in a shequ in Chengdu.
The oversight council is elected separately from the leadership committee by the party
members. Shequ party leaders and their family members are not allowed to sit on the
oversight council. The duties of the council include preventing power abuses and
corruption by shequ party leaders, ensuring the integrity of the procedure of party
elections, and implementing “disclosure of information of party’s affairs” (dangwu
gongkai)410. The oversight council has the right to sit on the meetings held by the
leadership committee, to read every party document, to question members of the
leadership committee, and to recommend impeachment of particular shequ party
leaders.411
In designing the system of oversight council, there was a strong emphasis on
“oversight by a different body” (yiti jiandu). The oversight council is still a party organ,
but it is clear to the district officials who designed this system that to effectively
supervise the shequ party leaders, there has to be an institution independent from the
control of these leaders. Although it would be absurd to argue “check and balance” and
409
Yuan Lianggang et al., “Luohu shequ dangzuzhi huanjie 100% shixing shuang zhixuan (Community Party
Organizations in Luohu District 100% Double Direct Elections)” Shenzhen tequbao April 30, 2008.
410
Dangwu gongkai is similar to the Juwu gongkai described in Chapter 5. See Li Kuiyang, “Jiji tansuo dangwu
gongkai de xintujing (Positively Experimenting with New Ways to Open up Party Affairs)” Xuexi yuekan (Study
Monthly) 7 (2008), pg. 92-93.
411
Jin Zhu, “Jiaozhi shequ dangwu jiandu xiang ‘yiti’ zhuanbian (Jiaozhi Community Oversight of Party Affairs
Transitioning to a ‘Different Body’)” Shequ (Community) 5 (2007), pg. 20-21; “Shishi yiti jiandu, Chengdu shidian
jianli shequ dangwu jiandu weiyuanhui (Implementing Different Body Supervision, Chengdu Experimenting with
Community Party Affairs Oversight Council)” Lingdao juece xinxi (Information for Deciders) 17 (2007), 19.
235
“separation of powers” are taking hold within the CCP, the idea of “supervision by a
different body” is nevertheless something novel. The party always has an internal
regulation and corruption investigation mechanism –the “disciplinary inspection
committee.” The disciplinary inspection committee, however, has not been very effective
in preventing and investigating corruption and power abuses, since it is controlled by the
party committee at the same level of the party hierarchy.412 In comparison to the
disciplinary inspection committee, the design of the oversight council and the idea of
“supervision by a different body” represent a progressive step toward a more
democratically governed party organization.
Incorporation of the shequ party leadership and the residents’ committe and
democratizing shequ party organizations are not exclusive to each other. A shequ party
organization could experiment with embedment and inner-party democratic reforms at
the same time. The overall shequ democratic development could have a democratizing
impact on the party organization. But such optimistic picture still has to be balanced by
the fact that the no matter how many tests of popular scrutiny the shequ party leaders
have to go through, their ultimate boss is the street-level party organization, under the
party doctrine of “democratic centralism.” A shequ party secretary that rides on popular
support against his/her boss at the street-level could be destabilizing the coherence of the
regime; it would surprise no one if this secretary is immediately removed from power. So
far the evidence in this chapter supports the argument that the party has tentatively in
412
For the nature of the disciplinary inspection committee and its relationship with the party committee, see Lu Jing,
Zhonggong dangzheng yanjiu lunwenji, shangji, pg. 51-52, 174-199.
236
some aspects accommodated democracy, but whether this is sustainable and consolidated
in the long-run remains to be seen.
Conclusion
This chapter analyzes the role of the party organization in the process of shequ
democratic development. The party has a long history of strengthening its grassroots
units and organizations. Under the concept of “party building,” it has taken a number of
measures to strengthen the cohesiveness, ideological conviction, and organizational
discipline of these party organizations. The strong focus on “governing capacity” in the
recent years also means that the party building program for grassroots party organizations
have some new elements that emphasize their abilities to respond to and diffuse
destabilizing crises and to serve the people. On the other hand, shequ party organizations,
being the weakest grassroots organizations of the party and being hampered by the
“vertical-horizontal conflict,” mainly concentrate on strengthening the organization and
integration aspects of shequ party building.
This chapter also describes and analyzes different ways in which the party
accommodates the democratic development of shequ. Subjecting party leaders to
residents’ committee elections ensures that party leaders also have popular mandates.
Opening up the nomination process to non-party residents also increases the likelihood
that elected party leaders enjoy certain legitimacy. Having an oversight council that is
separate from the party leadership to supervise the leaders strengthens democratic
supervision. These institutional innovations suggest that the party, at least at the
grassroots shequ level, is concerned about its own “democratic deficit,” and is
experimenting ways to boost its democratic legitimacy.
237
Table 6.1 Formal Responsibilities of Street-Level and Shequ-Level Party Organizations
in Two National Documents
2000 Ministry of Civil
2004 CCP Central
Affairs Document on Shequ
Organization Department
Jianshe
Document on Shequ Party
Building
Street-Level Party
NA
1) To publicize and
Organization
implement the line,
principles, and
polices the party
center, superior party
organizations, and its
own decisions; to
organize and lead the
cadres and mass in
completing its own
tasks
2) to discuss and decide
important matters
regarding urban
management,
economic
management, and
community
construction; to
coordinate with the
relevant departments
and mobilize various
resources to serve the
masses and support
the work of shequ
jianshe
3) to lead the street
office and other
street-level mass
organizations such as
unions and women
federations; to lead
the party building
work in the “two
new” organizations
4) to lead ideologicalpolitical work,
grassroots
democratic
238
5)
6)
Shequ-Level Party
Organization
1) to publicize and
implement party’s
line, principles and
policies and the laws
and regulations of the
state
2) to unite and organize
party members and
ordinary residents in
carrying out various
shequ tasks
3) to support and ensure
the rule of law and
fulfillment of
responsibilities by
shequ residents’
committee
4) to strengthen its own
organizational
construction and
ideological political
work
5) to perform the
exemplifying role of
the party members in
the shequ
1)
2)
3)
4)
5)
6)
construction, and
spiritual civilization
construction, to
strengthen public
safety, protect social
stability
to strengthen its own
organizational
construction and lead
shequ-level
organization
construction
to improve cadre
education,
appointment,
management
supervision
to publicize and
implement party’s
line, principles and
policies
to discuss and decide
important matters
regarding shequ
jianshe
to lead the shequ
residents’ committee
and support shequ
self-governance
to maintain close ties
with the mass,
resolve social
disputes and
maintain social
stability
to organize party
members and the
mass in doing shequ
jianshe work
to strengthen its own
organizational
construction
Sources: “Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijing chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian (Opinion of the Ministry of Civil
Affairs on Promoting Community Construction Nationwide” in Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s
Community Construction Yearbook 2003), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004), pg. 137-138; “Zhonggong
239
zhongyang zuzhibu guanyu jinyibu jiaqiang he gaijin jiedao shequ dangde jianshe gongzuo de yijian (Opinions by the
Party Central Organization Department on Further Strengthening and Improving Street and Community Party Building
Work)” Renmin ribao November 22, 2004; “‘Zhonggong zhongyang zuzhibu guanyu jinyibu jiaqiang he gaijin jiedao
shequ dangde jianshe gongzuo de yijian’ wenda (Questions and Answers Regarding the ‘Opinions by the Party Central
Organization Department on Further Strengthening and Improving Street and Community Party Building Work’)”
Shijian (Practice) 3 (2005), pg. 15-16.
240
Table 6.2 Percentages of Jiaocha renzhi and Yijiantiao
Cities
Beijing
Shanghai
Nanjing
Jinan
Qingdao
Provinces
Liaoning
Hubei
Residents’ Committee
Members as Party Members
(Jiaocha renzhi)
Chair of the Residents’
Committee as Secretary of
the Shequ Party
Organization (Yijiantiao)
47%
54.7%
57%
52%
NA
42%
NA
Above 90%
NA
63%
49%
NA
75%
Above 70%
Source: Zhan Chengfu (ed.), Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jingcheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of Election
Work of Community Residents’ Committee) Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 68,75,84,100,108-109;
Ao Zujian, “Wei chujin chengshi shequ hexie tigong jianqiang de zuzhi baozheng (Providing a Strong Organizational
Basis in Promoting Urban Community Harmony)” Zhengce (Policy) 10 (2007), pg. 45; Akio Takahara and Robert
Benewick, “Party Work in Urban Communities” in The Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by Kjeld Erik
Brodsgaard and Zheng Yongnian, New York, NY: Routledge (2006), pg. 163.
241
Chapter 7: Homeowners’ Committees: The Emergence of Shequ-based
Civil Society
The development of the homeowners’ committee (yezhu weiyuanhui)413 in urban
shequs epitomizes a different pattern of grassroots democratic development. The
characteristics of the homeowners’ committee are similar in some ways to the civil
society organizations in Western societies. In contrast to the residents’ committee, the
homeowners’ committee is generally viewed as having more potential to develop into an
autonomous organization capable of representing and articulating the interests of urban
residents-homeowners.
The government did not anticipate the emergence of the homeowners’ committee
in the shequ. The focus of the shequ jianshe policy has always been the revitalization of
residents’ committees in urban grassroots governance. The most important policy
document on shequ jianshe (the 2000 Ministry of Civil Affairs document) does not
contain any significant description of the homeowners’ committee. Likewise, official
discourse on grassroots democracy always points to the elections and democratic
governance of the shequ residents’ committee. Nevertheless, this does not mean that the
government is unsupportive of the development of the homeowners’ committee.
Beginning in the mid-1990s, both central and local governments have issued and
promulgated a body of laws and regulations to regulate, but also to ascertain, the role and
functions of the homeowners’ committee in urban shequs.
This chapter consists of the following sections: the concept and background of
property management, laws and regulations regarding property management and the
413
Also translated as proprietors’ committee or property owners’ committee.
242
homeowners’ committee, the homeowners’ “rights-defense” movement and the
homeowners’ committee, institutional innovations in homeowners’ self-governance, and
finally the relationship between the homeowners’ committee, civil society, and
democratic development.
7.1 Property Management and Homeowners’ Committees
The emergence of homeowners’ committees can be traced back to the housing
policy reform414 and the subsequent emergence of the privatized housing market in
China. Before the housing reform, which began in the late 1980s and involved a complex
set of plans over several years, the danwei (work unit) was the main provider of housing
(primarily apartments) to employees.415 At least one working family member usually
resided in the same area in which the work unit was located. The main focus of the
housing policy reform initially aimed to remove the heavy financial and administrative
burden for work units by privatizing this public-owned housing through subsidies. More
recently, the housing reform has tried to create a vibrant, commercialized property market
by encouraging real property developers to develop new residential areas and to
undertake urban re-development projects.416
Today, it is estimated that at least 40% of urban residents are homeowners. Those
who acquired their property through privatization of work unit property and through
government subsidization generally belong to the low and lower-middle income strata,
414
The housing policy reform is applied exclusively in urban areas. Rural residents are basically completely unaffected
by the housing policy reform, as are migrant workers to the cities, as they never were part of urban work units.
415
There was some private ownership dating back to the pre-revolutionary era, but for the most parts private
homeownership was practically non-existent.
416
For housing reform in China, see Ya Ping Wang & Alan Murie, “Social and Spatial Implications of Housing Reform
in China” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24:2 (2000), pg. 397-417; Jieming Zhu, “The
Changing Mode of Housing Provision in Transitional China” Urban Affairs Review 35:4 (2000), pg. 502-519; Yang
Buo, Cong chongtu dao zhixu: hexie shequ jianshezhong de yezhu weiyuanhui (From Conflict to Order: Homeowners’
Committees in the Construction of Harmonious Community), Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2006), pg. 37-40.
243
whereas those who purchased their property from the property market are generally
members of the middle and upper-middle income strata. It is the latter group that tends to
be more active in protecting and advancing their rights and interests as homeowners.417
In the pre-housing reform era, property’s maintenance was performed by the
logistics departments of work units or the housing bureaus of local governments. The
occupants showed little interest in taking a good care of the property. With the emergence
of private homeownership, homeowners have a stronger incentive to keep their property
well maintained. Homeowners invested a large sum of money to purchase their property,
so they have a direct stake in keeping their property value high. Property value in turn
depends on the quality of property management and the quality of life and governance in
their residential area.418 Homeowners’ committees are therefore organized to represent,
protect and advance homeowners’ rights and interests. Homeowners’ assemblies are the
forums for homeowners to meet, discuss, and decide on important issues.419
7.1.1 The Concept of Property Management
Upon purchasing a property, a homeowner acquires the exclusive ownership right
of the purchased unit and shared ownership right to common areas and equipments
417
According to the nationwide census conducted in 2000, 45.2% of urban residents are homeowners. Among them,
65.15% purchased their property from their work unit; 20.38% purchased from the property market, and 14.47% of the
homeowners acquired their property through the scheme of government-subsidized “economy housing”. See Liu
Yongli, “Jumin zhufang zhuangkuang dagaiguan (Huge Changes in the Patterns of Urban Housing)” Zhongguo
xinxibao October 28, 2002. The next census is scheduled in 2010.
418
Xia Jianzhong, “Zhongguo gongmin shehui de xiansheng: yi yezhu weiyuanhui weili (The Forerunner of Civil
Society in China: The Homeowners’ Committee as an Example),” Wenshizhe (Journal of Literature, History and
Philosophy) 3 (2003), pg. 116-117.
419
Although the homeowners’ committee is a “new thing” in China, it is not an institution unique to China (unlike the
residents’ committee). In the United States, there is a comparable organization of homeowners’ organizations–the
Residential Community Associations (RCA), that are prevalent in the so-called “common interest development”
housing. The homeowners’ committee is akin to the board of directors of the residential community association,
whereas the homeowners’ assembly, in which the homeowners’ committee answers to, is similar to the general meeting
of the residential community association. See Robert Jay Dilgor, Neighborhood Politics: Residential Community
Associations in American Governance, New York, NY: New York University Press (1992); Evan McKenzie,
Privatopia: Homeowner Associations and the Rise of Residential Private Government, New Haven: Yale University
Press (1994).
244
(lanes, elevators, gardens, the water supply and sewage system, the heating equipment,
etc.). He/she also enjoys at least the usage right (if not also the shared ownership right) of
shared facilities, such as playgrounds, activity centers, sports facilities, swimming pools,
and so on. “Property” in this sense includes all of the above.420 Management of common
property areas and shared facilities comes to be known as “property management” (wuye
guanli). The concept of “homeowners’ self-governance” (yezhu zizhi) means that
homeowners cooperate to jointly take care of their common property areas and shared
facilities, as well as the governance of public affairs related to the common interests of
homeowners. In effect, however, the predominant model in China is the delegation of
property management responsibilities to a property management company, which is
nominally hired by, and under the supervision of, the homeowners’ committee. 421
7.1.1A Property Management Company
Each neighborhood (or xiaoqu)422 is managed by a property management
company. In most instances a neighborhood consists of a few building blocks; but
sometimes it could consist of only a single building. A shequ generally encompasses
several xiaoqus, or in some instances, a large xiaoqu coincides with the boundary of a
shequ. Xiaoqu here basically is a concept applied to property development and
management. It can be conceptualized as a private housing estate. Shequ, on the other
420
The ownership patterns of these common areas and public facilities however are not uniform. In some
neighborhoods, the developer continues to own some common areas and public facilities, with the homeowners
guaranteed the usage rights. While in other neighborhoods, homeowners acquire shared ownership rights over more
common areas and facilities once they purchased a unit, but also had to pay a higher property price.
421
See Yang Buo, Cong chongtu dao zhixu, pg. 40-51.
422
In Chinese media, zhuzhai xiaoqu (residential neighborhood), xinjian xiaoqu (new neighborhood), loupan xiaoqu
(development estate neighborhood), shangpinfang xiaoqu (commercial housing neighborhood) are the terms used to
essentially refer to the same thing.
245
hand, is a designated (lowest) level of administration. Throughout this chapter, the terms
xiaoqu and neighborhood are used interchangeably.
While the primary responsibility of property management companies is the
maintenance and repair of common property areas and public facilities, they also perform
certain key functions that make residents highly dependent on them. Most property
management companies also provide public security, trash collection, sanitation services,
and parking management. Many of these companies are also responsible for the
distribution of public utilities (running water, electricity, gas and heat). Thus, if a
property development company decided to suddenly terminate its services in a xiaoqu,
the life of the residents of this xiaoqu could become extremely difficult. They would have
no running water, heat or electricity supplies. No one would come to collect trash and
provide security petrol. In addition, for many newly developed residential areas, in which
the residents’ committee has not yet been established, property management companies
also assume many functions of the residents’ committee, such as assisting the local
government in the areas of crime watch, household registration, health and sanitation
inspections, and even political propaganda and mobilization. In short, the property
management company can be quite powerful vis-à-vis ordinary resident-homeowners.
Today, there are at least 20,000 property management companies operating in
Chinese cities. About 70% of these companies are privatized logistics departments of
work units or privatized housing bureaus of local governments. These companies
primarily service homeowners who purchased their property from their work units or
through government subsidization. These companies generally maintain close ties to the
local government or the work units they were formerly attached to. In the commercial
246
property market, however, property management companies are generally established by
property developers in the form of “after-sale services” (around 20% of all property
management companies). Generally speaking, these companies tend to act as an agency
of the developers and side with the developers in their disputes with homeowners.
Finally, about 10% of the property management companies are independently established
by private entrepreneurs or are foreign invested. The service provided by this type of
company tends to be the best and the most professional, but also is the most expensive.423
7.2 Laws and Regulations on Property Management and Homeowners’ Committee
In March 1994, the Ministry of Construction (in 2008 the Ministry was reorganized as the Ministry of Housing and Urban-Rural Development) issued the
“Management Measures of Urban New Residential Neighborhoods”, the first regulation
of its kind to spell out the rights and obligations of both the property management
company and the homeowner. This is the first official document authorizing the
establishment of a homeowners’ organization, which, at that time, was called the
“neighborhood management committee” (xiaoqu guanli weiyuanhui). Neighborhood
management committees were the predecessors of today’s homeowners’ committees.
7.2.1 Regulations of Property Management, Property Law, Rules of the Homeowners’
Assembly
Despite the promulgation of the “Management Measures”, conflicts involving the
violations of homeowners’ rights and interests persisted and intensified as more
commercial developments and urban renewal projects were undertaken in Chinese cities,
while the regulatory regime remained weak. Corruption and misbehavior among
423
Xu Jiansu, Wang Yan, “Xiaoqu yezhu weiquan de xiangguan wenti tantao (Discussion of Issues Related to RightsDefense among Neighborhood Homeowners),” Hebei jingmao daxue xuebao (Journal of Hebei University of
Economics and Trade) 7:1 (2007), pg. 35.
247
developers were widespread. This prompted the government to revise and update the
regulatory framework of property management. The “Management Measures” were
superseded by the Regulations of Property Management (wuye guanli tiaoli). The
government reportedly took four years to finalize the document in 2003. In the drafting
process the Ministry of Construction claimed to have incorporated more than half of the
four thousand suggestions coming from the public. It also claimed that the “Regulations”
would be a powerful document protecting homeowners’ rights.424 Following the
promulgation of the 2007 “Property Law of China,” the “Regulations” were also updated
to synchronize with the stipulations protecting private property rights in the Property
Law. The Property Law and the “Regulations” are the two highest laws governing
property management and homeowners’ organizations.
Apart from these two laws, in 2003 the Ministry of Construction also issued
“Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly” (yezhu dahui guicheng). The “Rules of the
Homeowners’ Assembly” specify the formation, organization, and operation of the
homeowners’ assembly and the homeowners’ committee.425 Technically speaking, the
legal power of the “Rules” is not as authoritative and established as the two basic laws,
since the “Rules” are meant to be an instructional guidance, not a law. Nonetheless, it is
still an important document regularly cited by local governments, the courts, and
homeowners.
In addition to these national laws and regulations, provincial and city
governments also enact their own “implementation measures” of the “Regulations of
424
Zhan Diyou, Hu Yibing, “Dui ‘wuye guanli tiaoli’ youzan youtan (Praises and Criticisms of the ‘Regulations of
Property Management’,” Zhongwai fangdichan daobao (Chinese and Foreign Real Estate Times) 14 (2003), pg. 119123.
425
Lu Jun, “‘Yezhu dahui guicheng’ chutai: quanzhe fenming yifa weiquan (The Issuance of “Rules of the
Homeowners’ Assembly”: Defending Rights Based on Law),” Zhonghua gongshang shibao July 4, 2003.
248
Property Management” that serve as the basic law on property management in their areas
of administration. Some city governments (such as Beijing, Shenzhen, and Zhengzhou)
also issue their own instructional guidance. A Western scholar argues that these local
regulations and “implementation measures” tend to restrict and diminish homeowners’
rights that are laid out in the more general provisions contained in national documents.426
However, this is not always the case. Some provincial regulations, such as the provincial
regulations on property management enacted by Zhejiang province, appear to give more
substantive rights (such as litigation right) to the homeowners’ committee.427
7.2.2 Homeowners’ Covenant, Meeting Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly, Property
Service Contract
In addition to these national, provincial, and city laws and regulations,
homeowners are also bounded within a neighborhood by three basic documents –the
“homeowners’ covenant”/“management rules”428, the “meeting rules of the homeowners’
assembly”(yezhu dahui yishi guize), and the property service contract.429 The
homeowners’ covenant stipulates the usage, maintenance, and protection of property, the
common interests of homeowners, homeowners’ obligations, and the
punishment/responsibilities for those homeowners who fail to fulfill their obligations.430
426
Benjamin Read, “Property Rights and Homeowner Activism in New Neighborhoods” in Privatizing China:
Socialism from Afar, edited by Li Zhang and Aihwa Ong, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press (2008), pg. 45, 54.
427
Ning Jie, “Yezhu jigou de ‘mingzheng’ yu ‘yanshun’ (‘Proper Name’ for the Homeowners’ Organizations)” Renmin
fayuanbao-fazhoubao October 27, 2006; Tian Menghai, Wu Enyu, “Lun yezhu weiyuanhui de yuangao diwei (On the
Plaintiff Status of the Homeowners’ Committee),” Fazhi yanjiu (Rule of Law Studies) 8 (2008), pg. 61-66.
428
The general term for this document is “homeowners’ covenant” (yezhu gongyue), but the revised Regulations of
Property Management in 2007 renames it as “management rules” (guanli guiyue). Nonetheless, the term “homeowners’
covenant” is still being used predominantly in China today, so it is used in this chapter.
429
Chen Ming, “Yezhu ying zhongshi sange ‘daibiaoxing’ wenjian (Homeowners Should Pay Attention to the ‘Three
Authoritative’ Documents),” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 8 (2006), pg. 49-51.
430
The homeowners’ covenant is similar to the “covenants, conditions and regulations” (the so-called
CC&Rs) in American neighborhoods. The property developer generally supplies a temporary homeowners’
covenant until it is replaced by the covenant drafted by the homeowners themselves. The homeowners’
collective right to draft their own covenant is in this case more democratic than American CC&Rs, which
are written by the developer without any input from homeowners. Although there are some disagreements
249
The “meeting rules of the homeowners’ assembly” stipulate the rules of order in the
meeting of the assembly, the procedure of making binding resolutions, and the voting
right of homeowners.431 Both of these documents are the “internal documents” that
govern the organization, functions and procedures of the homeowners’ assembly and the
homeowners’ committee.
The property service contract stipulates the exact services the property
management company provides and the amount of service charges. According to the
Regulations of Property Management, the developer is responsible for hiring a property
management company (again, this tends to be a company established by the same
developer) and signing a contract with this company before the homeowners’ assembly
signs a new contract (or the homeowners’ assembly decides to hire another company).
The contract signed by the developer is called the “early contract” or “temporary
contract” in China (for issues related to the contract, see Reports 3 and 4 in Appendix
7.1).
Altogether these laws, rules and regulations, and covenants dealing with property
management and homeowners’ committees constitute a complex legal system, not to
mention significant variations over time and place and inconsistencies among some of the
laws and regulations. Many disputing parties could cite provisions justifying their
over the legal force of the homeowners’ covenant, generally Chinese scholars agree that it has some
contractual nature and violations of the covenant could be brought to the courts. See He Xiaohui, “Woguo
yezhu gongyue wenti zhi tantao (An Inquiry into the Issue of the Homeowners’ Covenant in China),”
Gansu zhengfa chengren jiaoyu xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Adult Education of Gansu Political Science
and Law Institute) 1 (2006), pg. 20; see also Jin Zhiwei, “Yezhu gongyue shibushi hetong (Is the
Homeowners’ Covenant a Contract)?” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor) 5 (2005), pg. 37-39; Qian Xiaoping, “Yezhu gongyue falu xingzhi zhi tantao (An Inquiry into
the Legal Nature of the Homeowners’ Covenant),” Beijing gongye daxue xuebao (Journal of Beijing
University of Technology) 4:4 (2004), pg. 78-82.
431
Article 10 and 11 of the 2003 “Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly”. See “Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly”
Zhongguo jianshe xinxi (Information of China Construction) 14 (2003), pg. 15.
250
positions from different laws and regulations.432 The homeowners’ “right-defense”
movement in this sense generally requires skillful lawyers.
7.3 The Homeowners’ Rights-Defense Movement and the Homeowners’ Committee
In recent years, the more developed Chinese cities (such as Beijing, Shenzhen,
Shanghai, and Guangzhou) have seen an explosion in the number of property developers
and property management companies. It is also in these cities that the homeowners’
“rights-defense” movement (yezhu weiquan yundong) is most vibrant and wellpublicized.
“Rights-defense” (weiquan) movements (such as consumer’s rights,
environmental protection, migrant’s rights, etc.) have been proliferating in China in
recent years. Ostensibly they are dealing with nonpolitical “functional” issues; but their
effects sometimes do have significant implications for the political system. By appealing
to Chinese laws and the constitution when they challenge local governments, it is harder
for the authorities to label them as anti-regime movements. In fact, sometimes higher
authorities also do sympathize and agree with the case made by rights-defense
activists.433 These movements therefore could be “regime supportive” and “rights
upholding” at the same time. Nevertheless, this does not mean that the government will
not crackdown on these “rights-defense” movements if they are perceived to become a
destabilizing force in society.
432
Note that the complexity of the laws about property management is not unique to China too. In America, “different
results were reached on important issues [regarding homeowners’ association] from state to state, many even among
judicial districts in the same state.” See McKenzie, Privatopia, pg. 151.
433
Bruce J. Dickson, “The Future of the Chinese Communist Party: Strategies of Survival and the Prospects for
Change” in Charting China’s Future: Political, Social and International Dimensions, edited by Jae Ho Chung,
Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield (2006), pg. 35-36.
251
The homeowners’ “rights-defense” movement thus is one of these rights-defense
movements; it is a “rights-based collective action on the part of citizens armed with an
awareness of the gulf between what they are legally entitled to and what they are getting
in practice.”434 There are however some general differences between the homeowners’
movement and other rights-defense movements. First, in comparison to the more
unpredictable “rights-defense” movements (especially among workers and peasant
groups), which can easily escalate into violent mass incidents, homeowners’ resistance is
generally “reasonable, acceptable, modest, [and] persistent.”435 Although this does not
mean that homeowners’ resistance is always peaceful and rational,436 in general the
homeowners’ movement is essentially moderate and operates within boundaries of the
law.
Second, “the principal motor driving homeowner organization is not government
policy at either the central or local levels but rather the ways in which homeowners feel
their rights are being abused by the developers and property management companies.”437
This is different from other rights-defense movements in which local governments are the
principal villains. Although there are always susceptible connections between developers,
434
Benjamin Read, “Democratizing the Neighborhood? New Private Housing and Home-Owner Self Organization in
Urban China” The China Journal 49 (2003), pg. 58. For homeowners’ weiquan movement, see Xu Daowen, “Yezhu
weiquan heyi chengwei ‘yundong’ (How Homeowners’ Protection of their Rights Become a ‘Movement’”
Nanfengchuang (Southern Wind) 10 (2005), pg. 48-49; Zhang Zhifan, “Weiquan yundong tuijin hexie shequ (RightsDefense Movement Promoting Community Harmony” Shequ (Community) 1 (2005), pg. 22-23. For other cases of
weiquan movement, see the discussion in Richard Baum, “Political Implications of China’s Information Revolution:
The Media, the Minders, and Their Message,” in China’s Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy,
edited by Cheng Li, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press (2008), pg. 174-176.
435
Yongshun, Cai, “China’s Moderate Middle Class: The Case of Homeowners’ Resistance” Asian Survey 45:5 (2005),
pg. 793-794.
436
There are incidents of physical assaults in the homeowners’ rights-defense movement. See Zhou Yan, “Zai kongzhi
yezhu zhijian fei lixing weiquan zhong tisheng wuye guanli pinzhi (Improving the Quality of Property Management in
the Control of Irrational Rights-Defense among Homeowners),” Zhongguo fangdichan (Chinese Property
Management) 3 (2005), pg. 62-63.
437
Benjamin Read, “Property Rights and Homeowner Activism,” pg. 45
252
property management companies, and local governments438, local governments generally
are not a direct target of homeowners’ resistance. Sometimes the local authority is viewed
as a neutral force that would side with the party that has a just demand in a dispute –the
homeowners. Nevertheless, this does not mean that a local government will never be a
target, especially if its decisions are perceived to have violated homeowners’ rights and
interests.
7.3.1 Major Issues in Homeowners’ Rights-Defense Movement
The major issues in the homeowners’ rights-defense movement typically involve
at least one of the following:
1) an unfair contract forced upon property purchasers by developers;
2) the refusal of property developers to handover the use of public facilities and
equipment to homeowners, and instead, illegally rent out these facilities for their own
profit;
3) the failure of property developers to provide property deeds (fangchanzheng) to
the homeowners, without which the ownership of the property is not complete;
4) changes in the development plan of a neighborhood (such as replacing a garden
or playground that had been promised to the homeowners with a supermarket or a factory
from which the developer could profit from);
5) high property management fees imposed on the homeowners, combined with
the low quality of the service provided;
438
Collusion between property developer and local officials is identified as one of the most corruption “high-risk
sectors” by Chinese government. See Minxin Pei, “Fighting Corruption: A Difficult Challenge for Chinese Leaders” in
China’s Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by Cheng Li, Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press (2008), pg. 229-250.
253
6) the loss of, or damage to, private property (typically automobiles) that is due to
the alleged inadequate security services provided by the property management company;
7) disagreements over certain extra fees and assessments imposed by the property
management company;
8) the occupation and usage of certain common property and public facilities by
the property management company for profiteering activities;
9) the inability of homeowners to change their property management company, or
even if they did, the refusal by the property management company to transfer its services
to another property management company;
10) the failure of local housing and property authorities to settle homeowners’
complaints in a fair and neutral manner;
11) the failure of having a homeowners’ committee to be established;
12) conflicts between the homeowners’ committee and homeowners, especially
when the latter alleges abuses and corruption among members of the homeowners’
committee; and
13) in more recent years, the adverse environmental and social impact of certain
decisions made by the city and district governments on homeowners’ lives and
surrounding environment.439
7.3.2 The Homeowners’ Committee
439
Zhao Linmin, “Yezhu weiquan, zhengfu zenmeban (Homeowners Protecting their Rights, What should the
Government do)?” Nanfengchuang (Southern Wind) 7 (2005), pg. 52-53; “Wuda jiaodian wenti (Five Critical Issues”
Renmin fayuanbao –fazhoukan, September 1, 2006; Li Ji et al., “Nanliqing de wuye he yezhu weiquan zhizheng (The
Hard-to-Solve Conflicts between Property Management and Homeowners’ Rights Defense)” Renmin fayuanbao June
5, 2007. See also the case studies reported in Zou Shubin, “Zhuzhai xiaoquzhong de minzhu (Democracy in Residential
Neighborhood)” in Chengshi shequ yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu (Studies of the Development of Homeowners’
Committee in Urban Communities), edited by Tang Juan, Chongqin: Chongqin chubanshe (2005), pg.3-7. The plight of
homeowners also receives sympathetic coverage in official media, among them the paramount “mouthpiece of the
party” –the People’s Daily. In June 2006 the newspaper published a series of articles highlighting the difficulties
homeowners in Beijing were dealing with. Appendix 7.1 summarizes these press reports.
254
The homeowners’ committee is the major organizational form of the
homeowners’ rights-defense movement. Theoretically speaking, the homeowners’
committee is not an “autonomous” organization; it is the executive body of the
homeowners’ assembly.440 Nevertheless, since the assembly only meets infrequently
(whereas the homeowners’ committee operates on a daily basis), it means that in daily
life the more important body is the homeowners’ committee.
The first homeowners’ committee was established in Shenzhen in 1991. Since
then, the number of homeowners’ committees has grown. However, the complicated
procedural obstacles of establishing a homeowners’ committee have thwarted their
growth. As Table 7.1 shows, in most Chinese cities (with the exception of Shanghai and
Nanjing441), only 20% to 30% of the qualified neighborhoods are successful in
establishing a homeowners’ committee. Many property developers and property
management companies resist the establishment of homeowners’ committees.442 These
companies are also frequently (but not always) backed by local housing and property
authorities (some of these property officials sit on the board of the industry association of
these companies).
440
Important matters regarding the interest and welfare of the homeowners, such as the signing of a service contract
with the property management company, the use of homeowners’ collective fund, and the imposition of special
assessments for a particular project in the neighborhood, require the approval of at least half or two-thirds of the
homeowners in a meeting of the assembly. See Articles 8 to 17 of the “Regulations of Property Management”.
441
The reason why Shanghai is an exception is its emphasis of the party leadership of the homeowners’ committees,
therefore guaranteeing that the homeowners’ committees would not be too autonomous. See Zhang Nian, “Shanghaishi
cong zhidu he caozuo cengmian jiaqiang yeweihui gongzuo (Shanghai Strengthens the Work on Homeowners’
Committees through Institutional and Operational Aspects),” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese Property Management)
11 (2007), pg. 52-53, and in a section below I will discuss more about the Shanghai case. In the case of Nanjing, many
homeowners’ committees were established by the property management companies on their behalf. See Chen Long,
Zhou Caixia, Zhu Xiancheng, “Nanjing yezhu weiyuanhui zizhi zhidu de diaocha yanjiu (An Investigative Study of the
Homeowners’ Self-Governance System in Nanjing),” Zhongguo fangdichan (Chinese Real Estate) 4 (2004), pg. 70. We
can assume that in such instance the homeowners’ committee is a weaker force in the protection of homeowners’
rights.
442
Tang Juan, “Chengshi shequ jiegou bianqianzhong de chongtu yu zhili (Conflicts and Governance in the Structural
Changes of Urban Communities)” in Chengshi shequ yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu, pg. 61.
255
7.3.2A Procedural Difficulties in Establishing a Homeowners’ Committee
The procedure of establishing a homeowners’ committee is very complicated.443
According to the Regulations of Property Management, each xiaoqu444 is allowed only
one homeowners’ committee. Generally speaking, when one of the following conditions
is present within a xiaoqu: (1) more then 50% of the units are sold; (2) the occupancy rate
reaches 50%; (3) the total surface footage of homeowners’ property reaches 50% of the
development plan, the homeowners can demand the establishment of a homeowners’
committee (exactly which condition is applicable differs from place to place).
Alternatively, without fulfilling any of the “50%” conditions above, some
provincial governments also permit homeowners’ request to establish a homeowners’
committee after one or two years the first unit was sold or occupied. But not all local
governments permit this alternative. One of the problems then is that the total
development project of a xiaoqu could be divided into several phases, sometimes over
more than ten years. The request to establish a homeowners’ committee can be easily
turned down, the reason being that not enough units have been sold or occupied (not even
built yet!). Thus, the early occupants in a newly developed xiaoqu tend to be
disadvantaged as they would have to wait for many years before one of the “50%”
condition is met.
443
Unless otherwise noted, the following discussion is based on Cai Yi, “Yezhu weiyuanhui yunzuo shiwu (A Practical
Guide to the Operation of Homeowners’ Committee)” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 2 (2003), pg. 58; Shu Kexin, “Yezhu weiyuanhui shibanan (Eighteen Obstacles of Homeowners’ Committees),” Xiandaiwu ye
(Modern Property Management) 4 (2004), pg. 50-55; Wang Jian, Tang Luyong, “Yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan
zhuangkuang yanjiu (A Study of the Development of Homeowners’ Committee),” Shanghai fangdi (Shanghai Real
Estate) 7 (2007), pg. 44-46; Zheng Chao et al. “Yeweihui chengli chengxu guoyu fuza (The Establisment Process of
Homewners’ Committee too Complicated),” Huaxia shibao January 16, 2006.
444
The term used in the Regulations is property development area (wuye guanli quyu). See “Wuye guanli tiaoli
(Regulations of Property Management),” Shequ (Community) 14 (2003), pg. 51-53.
256
After having met this first condition, the homeowners can request the
establishment of a homeowners’ committee through the convening a homeowners’
assembly, from which members of the homeowners’ committee are elected. There are
two hurdles to be overcome at this stage. National and provincial regulations stipulate
that a preparation committee has to be first formed to organize the convention of the
homeowners’ assembly and the election of the homeowners’ committee. The preparation
committee generally includes officials from the local housing and property authorities
and the street office, members of the residents’ committee445, representatives of the
property developer (or the property management company attached to the developer),
homeowners’ representatives, and sometimes public security officers. Uncooperative
attitude on the part of any of the said persons can easily frustrate homeowners in forming
a preparation committee. The composition of the preparation committee also tends to be
influenced by the developer. Homeowners’ representatives sitting on the preparation
committee tend to be those who have received special discounts or favors from the
developer or its property management company.446
The second hurdle is the technical issues involving the election of the
homeowners’ committee. The voting right of homeowners (unless otherwise stated,
tenants are disenfranchised) is not based on the “one person, one vote”, and not even
“one household, one vote” principle, but rather on the calculation of the surface footage
of the purchased unit. For example, the weight of the vote of a homeowner whose
property surface area is 200 square meters is counted as double the weight of the vote of
445
446
For the role played the residents’ committee in property management, see Appendix 7.2.
For the problems of the preparation committee, see Yang Buo, Cong chongtu dao zhixu, pg. 93, 97-99.
257
a homeowner whose property surface area is 100 square meters.447 The problem is that
the developer also claims the ownership rights of the surface areas of the unsold units (or
yet-to-built units!) and of common property areas, giving it significant ballot power until
all most or units are sold. Based on a provision in the Regulations of Property
Management, many local regulations stipulate that a homeowners’ committee has to be
elected by homeowners whose combined surface footage of their property is at least 66%
of the total surface footage of their xiaoqu. The developer can use its ballot power, based
on the surface footage of the unsold and yet-to-be constructed units, to deny the
homeowners the target of 66%. The ballot power of the developer is reduced over the
years as units are being sold, but it can claim that all these units belong to a development
project that is yet to be finished. In such instance, it can still calculate its ballot power
based on the surface areas of those undeveloped areas. It is through this technique that a
developer in Beijing has been able to thwart the establishment of a homeowners’
committee within its development project for more than 14 years.448
On the other hand, even if the ballot power of a developer is reduced (as more
units are sold), it is still very difficult to achieve the two-thirds criteria. Many
homeowners are busy businesspersons or professionals. Some of them are real estate
investors and never appear in the neighborhood. One homeowner-activist recounts that
she and several activists had to go door-to-door for weeks to collect the necessary two-
447
Note that the voting right of American homeowners in the elections of board of directors of their residential
community associations is also similarly qualified by the size of the owned property. See Dilgor, Neighborhood
Politics, pg. 34-35.
448
Xu Hao, “Zhiyushanzhuang yezhu: 14nian nanshe yeweihui (The Homeowners of Zhixushan Villa: 14 Years of
Difficulty in Establishing a Homeowners’ Committee)” Zhongguo jingji zhoukan (China Economic Weekly) 11 (2007),
pg. 32-33. A similar situation is reported in a case by Yongshun Cai, “China’s Moderate Middle Class,” pg. 784.
258
thirds ballots.449 The 2007 revision of the Regulations of Property Management reduces
(indirectly) the two-thirds requirement to 50%, but it is still a major task to collect the
votes of half of the homeowners in a neighborhood.
7.3.2B The Legal Status of the Homeowners’ Committee450
There is some ambiguity in the legal nature of the homeowners’ committee, and
this has made its efforts to protect homeowners’ rights much more difficult, especially in
courts. Under the Chinese civil litigation law, a lawsuit can only be brought by a
“litigation subject.” A litigation subject could be a natural person, a corporate person, a
registered (dengji) social organization, or “other organizations” (qita zuzhi). The main
condition of being a litigation subject is that it must be able to fulfill “civil responsibility”
(minshi zeren) in the courts, i.e. to be able to compensate when it lost a lawsuit.
The homeowners’ committee does not register (dengji) as a social organization,
instead it files a record (bei’an) with the local housing and property authority (see
Appendix 7.3). Without the “social organization” status, many courts (but not all) have
thrown out lawsuits brought by homeowners’ committees. The courts do not consider
them a “litigation subject”. Some provincial regulations have made it easier for the
homeowners’ committee to become a litigation subject, but so far these are only the
exceptions. The 2007 Property Law might effect a change in the legal status of the
449
Hou Xiaoling, “Tang Peizhen: Tangjihede de dangdai nuxingban (Tang Peizhen, a Modern Female Version of Don
Quixote),” Renmin fayuanbao July 28, 2006; see also Song Yunxia, “Qianxi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui
chenglinan de yuanyin (A Preliminary Analysis of the Difficulty in Establishing Homeowners’ Assembly and
Homeowners’ Committee),” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 7 (2008), pg.
94-95.
450
For issues related to the legal status of the homeowners’ committee, see Cui Yehu, “Chengshi shequ yezhu
weiyuanhui falu diwei yanjiu (A Study of the Legal Status of the Homeowners’ Committee in Urban Communities),”
Hubei shehui kexue (Social Sciences in Hubei), 8 (2008), pg. 145-148; Zhang Zhuo, “Yezhu weiyuanhui falu dingwei
yu xingzhi (Legal Status and Nature of the Homeowners’ Committee),” Renmin fayuanbao October 26, 2005.
259
homeowners’ committee, but so far the impact of the Property Law is unclear.451 The
inability of the homeowners’ committee to pursue legal action remains one of the most
contentious issues in the homeowners’ rights-defense movement.
7.3.2C Homeowners’ Committees as Targets of Homeowners’ Resistance
Homeowners’ committees could also be violators of homeowners’ rights and
interests. Sometimes a property management company manages to buy off some of the
members in the committee. In other instances, some committee members have personal
agenda when making decisions. For example, there are cases in which a homeowners’
committee worked hard to push out a property management company that was actually
providing a good service, only to be found later that the newly hired company has ties to
some of the committee members. Incompetence, alleged abuses of power, manipulation
of elections, and corruption (such as misuse of homeowners’ funds) among members of
the homeowners’ committee also increasingly become common complaints by
homeowners.452 In these situations, homeowners’ committees are the targets of
homeowners’ resistance.
7.4 Institutional Innovations and the Homeowners’ Self-Governance
451
In an analytical piece published in a major property management magazine, a Chinese lawyer argues that the
Property Law secures a “conditioned litigation right” for the homeowners’ committee. See Ding Min, “Mingque
yeweihui shusong zhuti zige shi yingshi zhixu (Ascertaining the Litigation Rights of the Homeowners’ Committee is
Necessary),” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management-New Proprietor) 12 (2008), pg. 30-31. In the
2008 session of the Chinese Peoples’ Political Consultative Conference, a proposal that would ascertain the “social
organization” status of the homeowners’ committee was tabled, but to date it had not yet transpired into the legislative
institution. Yang Bingling, Gao Yicun, “Li Maofeng weiyuan tichu: jiang yezhu weiyuanhui mingquewei ‘shetuan
faren’ (Deputy Li Mao Feng Proposes: Give the Homeowners’ Committee the ‘Social Organization Corporate
Personality’),” Zhongguo shehuibao March 18, 2008.
452
For some of the examples of conflicts between homeowners and homeowners’ committees, see Song Ancheng,
“Guanjia nanding quliu, jiazhang mianlin ‘fenjia’ (Undecided about the Housekeepers, Owners are Divided),” Xiandai
wuye (Modern Property Management) 10 (2005), pg. 46-50; Wang Gang et al., “Dushi zhong de minzhu ‘mafan’ (The
Democratic ‘Problematic’ in Cities),” Zhongguo xinwen zhoukan (China Newsweek) 8-14 (2006), pg. 20-22; Shu
Kexin, “Cong Meiliyuan shijian kan yeweihui de xingwei houguo chengdan (The Responsibilities of Homeowners’
Committees from the Perspective of the Meiliyuan Incident),” Xiandai wuye –xin yezhu (Modern Property
Management –New Proprietor) 2 (2009), pg. 13-14; Wang Jianjun, “Mofan xiaoqu de yeweihui xuanju fengbo
(Turbulences in the Homeowners’ Committee Election at a Model Neighborhood),” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern
Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009), pg. 9-12.
260
Homeowners in China thus face numerous obstacles and problems in their rights’
defense movement. Nevertheless, homeowners are also among the more innovative and
creative groups in pursuing collective action and rights-defense. For example, some
homeowners are the pioneers and most active groups to use internet forums to discuss
their issues, exchange tactics, connect with each other, influence government’s actions,
and generate pressures on their targets. Participants in homeowners’ online forums are
some of the most active online activists that regularly discuss issues related to not only
property management, but sometimes to governance of the country as well.453
In the efforts to reduce conflicts and improve the governance of their
neighborhoods, homeowners sometimes also come up with some creative institutional
innovations in homeowners’ self-governance. Below I will briefly discuss three cases.
7.4.1 Shangdixili Homeowners’ Representatives’ Assembly, Beijing454
Shangdixili xiaoqu is an affluent neighborhood in Beijing. In 2004-2005, the
homeowners of this neighborhood successfully established their homeowners’
committee. What was unique about Shangdixili neighborhood was that it also created a
number of institutions to check and supervise the homeowners’ committee. One of them
is the homeowners’ representatives’ assembly (yezhu daibiao dahui). The
representatives’ assembly is established as the standing committee of the homeowners’
453
For homeowners’ online forums, see Hu Weihua, “Xiaoqu yezhu luntan de zuoyong yu jianshe (The Functions and
Contributions of Neighborhood Homeowners’ Forums),” Xiandai yezhu (Modern Property Management) 2 (2006), pg.
30-31; Wu Gongsun, “Wuye gongsi bufang changshi yixia zai wangshang yu yezhu goutong (Property Management
Companies should Interact with Homeowners through the Internet),” Shequ (Community) 7 (2007), pg. 23; Zhu Dahui,
“Yezhu luntan yu wuye guanli (Homeowners’ Forums and Property Management),” Xiandai wuye –xin yezhu (Modern
Property Management –New Proprietor) 2 (2009), pg. 6-7
454
Based on Wei Jian, Meng Qian, “Bei ‘yezhu daibiao dahui’ zhidu tongling de yige xiaoqu (A Neighborhood
Governed by the ‘Homeowners’ Representatives Assembly’),” Shequ (Community) 7 (2007), pg. 6-9; Guo Weijiang,
“Chengshi shequ zizhi de kunjing, shijian, fangxiang he duice (The Difficulty, Practice, Direction, and
Countermeasures of Urban Community Self-Governance),” Xiandai wuye –xin yezhu (Modern Property Management –
New Proprietor) 9 (2007), pg. 35-37.
261
assembly, and is empowered to make important decisions when the homeowners’
assembly is not meeting.
The representatives’ assembly has 27 representatives. All of them are elected
(some of these representatives are also members of the residents’ committee in this
neighborhood). The representatives cannot serve concurrently as members of another two
institutions: the homeowners’ committee and the homeowners’ oversight council (yezhu
jianshihui, discussed below). Since its creation, the representatives’ assembly had met 8
times in 2 years, issued 6 public announcements, and made important decisions, such as
approving a new service contract with a property management company, approving a
parking arrangement plan, drafting the rules for the use of homeowners’ collective fund,
and hiring the staff to do administrative work.
In addition, homeowners can directly contact these representatives if they have
any concerns or opinions. Based on these opinions and concerns, these representatives
would then draft and table “bills” in meetings of the representatives’ assembly. The
“bills” passed by the representatives’ assembly are then carried out by the homeowners’
committee. The representatives’ assembly can also temporary suspend any member of the
homeowners’ committee if he or she is found to be guilty of corruption. It also receives
and examines frequently the work report of the homeowners’ committee.
Finally, the oversight council has 3 members and its primary responsibility is to
ensure that all homeowners, homeowners’ representatives, and homeowners’ committee
members are following the homeowners’ covenant and other relevant rules and
regulations.
262
In a sense, the institutional design of the homeowners’ organization in this
neighborhood is similar to the division of three branches of power common in democratic
systems. The representatives’ assembly acts as a legislative institution, the homeowners’
committee being an executive institution, while the oversight council performs certain
adjudicative responsibilities. It prevents the homeowners’ committee from being
unaccountable to the homeowners. This system is reported to be working effectively,
with most of the homeowners satisfied with the performance of the homeowners’
committee and the property management company. The residents’ committee and the
homeowners’ committee also maintain a healthy working relationship.
7.4.2 Yueliangwan pianqu People’s Congress Deputy Work Station, Shenzhen455
The Peoples’ Congress Deputy Work Station (renda daibiao gongzuozhan,
hereafter Work Station) is located in Yueliangwan pianqu, a big shequ consisting of 12
neighborhoods in Nanshan district in Shenzhen. In 2001, the district government
approved a project to locate a waste incinerator/power generator near Yueliangwan
pianqu. The homeowners of Yueliangwan pianqu were infuriated. The homeowners’
committees in the area quickly joined together to lead a campaign in an attempt to force
the district government to reverse this decision. They organized protests, collective visits
to the complaints bureau, and sit-ins at the site of the incinerator.
Facing the tense situation, a party official at the street level that oversees
Yueliangwan pianqu contacted the people’s congress deputies in this area and asked these
deputies to speak to the homeowners. Using this channel (the people’s congress
deputies), the homeowners and the district and city governments were able to resolve this
455
Based on Tang Juan, “Yueliangwan de yezhu weiquan xinmoshi (A New Model of Homeowners’ Rights-Defense in
Yueliangwan),” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 3 (2006), pg. 5-7.
263
matter amicably. The successful conclusion of this episode led the government and
homeowners to realize that a liaison mechanism that could link the residents and the
people’s congress deputies is necessary. From the government’s perspective, such
mechanism ensures that government-citizens conflicts at least would be first channeled to
a proper and established mechanism of conflict resolution. From residents’ perspective,
this mechaniam ensures that their voices and concerns will be properly reflected in
government decision making process. In 2002, with official blessing, a homeowneractivist established the Work Station. Directors of the homeowners’ committees in
Yueliangwan pianqu all became the liaison officers of the Work Station.
The work station organizes a monthly meeting between people’s congress
deputies and residents. It is also empowered by the people’s congress deputies to refer
public issues and problems to relevant government authorities, and to check on the
progress of the authorities’ handling of these issues. The work station also organizes
consultative meetings between homeowners, party and government officials, the media,
and scholars on important issues. Each liaison officer is individually responsible for
collecting the opinions and concerns of the homeowners in his/her respective xiaoqu.
These opinions and concerns are then organized and reported to the people’s congress
deputies. Residents can contact the work station anytime through visit, emails, phone,
fax, etc.
The operation of the work station is reported to be very effective. It was able to
solve more than 50 public issues involving transportation, environmental pollution, and
public security in the 12 xiaoqus of Yueliangwan pianqu. Since the establishment of the
264
work station, open confrontations have been visibly absent, while the cost of
homeowners’ rights-defense has been brought down considerably.
7.4.3 Pinge Community Service Center Limited Company, Beijing456
Pinge xiaoqu is a relatively small xiaoqu in Beijing, with only 148 households.
The homeowners’ committee in this neighborhood was formed after its property
management company, citing its unsustainable business operation, suddenly withdrew
from the xiaoqu. The first decision the committee had to make thus was whether to rehire
the previous property management company (probably with higher fees), hire another
one, or take care of property management by the homeowners themselves. After a poll
among the homeowners, a majority of them picked the last option.
The homeowners then decided to create their property management company “Pinge Community Service Center Limited Company,” which is owned and operated by
the homeowners themselves. This is the first time that homeowners of a xiaoqu directly
take responsibility of property management, rather than follow the predominant model of
hiring a property management company. The company is registered with the commercial
bureau of Beijing.
According to the manager of the Company, all 148 homeowners in the xiaoqu are
shareholders of the company, the homeowners’ committee acts as a board of directors of
the company, while the manager answers to the homeowners’ committee. The
homeowners’ committee itself answers to all the homeowners in the homeowners’
assembly, which is also the shareholders’ general meeting.
456
Based on He Zhongzhou, “Pinge xiaoqu: ‘zizhi’ xinfu shenghuo (Pinge Neighborhood: ‘Self-Manufacturing’ Happy
Life),” Zhongguo xinwen zhoukan (China Newsweek) July 23 (2007), pg. 35-37.
265
Since the company is owned by the homeowners, all homeowners have an
incentive to keep the company’s finance healthy. Many homeowners volunteer to help
the company and pay property fees on time. They discuss various ways to cut costs. The
book of the company is open to any interested homeowner. With prudent cost
management, the company is able to generate a profit of 50,000 yuan annually. The use
of this money is divided into three parts: one-third as bonus to the employees of the
company, one-third as contribution to homeowners’ collective fund, and one-third as
payment to property fees in the coming year.
The operation of the company is reported to be hugely successful. The quality of
life of the xiaoqu improved substantially, while disputes between homeowners and the
property management company have been basically non-existent.
7.4.4 Discussion
The three cases of institutional innovations are remarkable in that all of them were
creative responses, initiated by private actions, to deal with difficult situations, without
the direction or involvement of government officials. They point to the growing selforganizing capability of the Chinese citizenry. In designing these institutional
innovations, the goal was to avoid being confrontational with the authorities over their
grievances and dissatisfactions. The Work Station is also remarkable for it is a private
citizens’ initiative to engage with the relevant government authorities in a cooperative
manner to solve problems and disputes. The result is at least as effective as a more
confrontational tactic.
These institutional innovations could be watched by higher authorities, and once
proved successful, could be recommended to other areas as well. In this sense, these
266
institutional innovations share some similar characteristics with some of the bottom-up
reform policies that are the hallmarks of the reform-era China, such as the rural
household responsibility system. While the practical effects of these homeowners’
institutional innovations on the political system do not equal the importance of the
household responsibility system to the economy, there is a similar pattern here –local
social initiatives that symbolize, and strengthen, societal autonomy and the growth of
civil society in China.
7.5 The Homeowners’ Committee, Civil Society, Democratic Development
The mainstream perspective on civil society is that it is a “realm of organized
social life,” which is based on private, voluntary and collective action in the public
sphere.457 Minimally speaking, civil society refers to citizens’ and societal self-organizing
efforts. Being free from state’s penetration and control is viewed as a crucial factor
distinguishing a genuine civil society from a politicized society. Civil society also implies
that this “realm of organized social life” is capable of self-regulation and selfregeneration. Moreover, the pluralistic conception of state-society relations also contends
that civil society organizations are principal articulators of different interests in the
society. Interest groups in this sense are part of the civil society, and they seek to
influence government policy to tilt toward certain social interests.458 The state is a neutral
ground in which different civil society organizations compete for influence and access to
policymakers, and in such a way political power is diffused through the political system
and society.
457
Larry Diamond, Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press
(1999), pg. 221.
458
Charles Taylor, “Models of Civil Society,” Public Cultures 3:1 (1991), pg. 95-118.
267
The application of the concept of “civil society” in China studies registered a
substantial growth during and after the 1989 Tiananmen students’ movement. The
students’ confrontation with the party leaders was often interpreted as a struggle between
the autonomous forces of “civil society” and the authoritarian “party-state”.459 The more
recent scholarship, however, tends to see a different picture of civil society development
in China –one in which the state plays a critical role in forming and guiding civil society
development. Frolic alludes to the notion of “state-led civil society” in China, which
refers to the “social organizations and quasi-administrative units created by the state to
help it manage a complex and rapidly expanding economy and changing society.”460
Ogden points out that many interest associations in China perform a “dual role,” –
representing the interests of their members at the same time regulating them to confirm to
state’s policies.461 Moore argued that while the Chinese government is increasingly
reliant on social organizations to provide social services, it is at the same time wary of
their politically disruptive potentials and thus attempts to extend “its own tentacles into
the ‘nongovernmental’ sector in an effort to reassert its control.”462
The form of civil society that is taking shape in China, therefore, is different from
civil society in liberal democracies in at least two crucial aspects: the non-confrontational
nature of the civil society groups toward the political authorities, and the monitoring of
such groups by the state and party organizations in China. There always remains,
459
For example, see Thomas Gold, “Party-State versus Society in China,” in Building a Nation-State: China after Forty
Years, edited by Joyce K. Kallgren, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California-Berkeley
(1990), pg. 124-151.
460
B. Michel Frolic, “State-led Civil Society,” in Civil Society in China, edited by Timothy Brook and B. Michael
Frolic, Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe (1997), pg. 48.
461
Suzanne Ogden, Inklings of Democracy in China, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center (2002), pg. 266.
462
Rebecca R. Moore, “China’s Fledging Civil Society: A Force of Democratization?” World Policy Journal 18:1
(2001), pg. 59.
268
however, a tension between the attempts of social organizations to maintain and enlarge
its autonomy from the party-state, and the party-state’s efforts to continue controlling,
penetrating, or at least leading these social organizations in a paternalistic manner.
7.5.1 The Homeowners’ Committee as a Civil Society Organization463
From the perspective of social self-organizing activities and capabilities, the
largely self-initiated homeowners’ “rights-defense” movement, the emergence of
homeowners’ committees, and the institutional innovations in homeowners’ selfgovernance, can be read as signs of a developing civil society in China. They also
indicate the increasing “decentralization and pluralization of power bases”464 in Chinese
society. In addition, “[homeowners’ committees] can be highly autonomous bodies with
which the state and other interlocutors have no choice but to deal and negotiate. They
constitute a new model for private associations in [China] as well as an attractive
laboratory for activists who have ambitions for far-reaching political change.”465 The
homeowners’ movement therefore is different from the traditional interest associations in
China such as unions and writers’ associations which are under the direct control of the
party-state. In other words, the homeowners’ movement signifies a process of civilsociety in making.
7.5.1A Homeowners’ Committees as Lobbyist Groups
463
For general Chinese discussions of the relationship between homeowners’ committee and civil society and
democratic development in China, see Xia Jianzhong, “Zhongguo gongmin shehui de xiansheng: yi yezhu weiyuanhui
weili,” pg. 115-121; Fei Meiping, “Yezhu weiyuanhui yu Zhongguo de shimin shehui (Homeowners’ Committee and
Civil Society in China),” Huadong ligong daxue xuebao (Journal of East China University of Science and Technology),
2 (2001), pg. 57-64; Zou Shubin, “Zhuzhai xiaoquzhong de minzhu,” pg. 1-19.
464
Ogden, Inklings of Democrac, pg. 222.
465
Benjamin L. Read, “Inadvertent Political Reform via Private Associations: Assessing Homeowners’ Groups in New
Neighborhoods,” in Grassroots Political Reform in Contemporary China, edited by Elizabeth J. Perry and Merle
Goldman, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (2007), pg. 150.
269
Increasingly homeowners are also capable of doing what interest groups normally
do –lobbying. Perhaps the most dramatic example is the 2007 PX plant (a chemical plant)
incident in Xiamen, a city in Fujian province. The local government approved the
construction of the plant near the city. Residents in the city, many of them homeowners,
were deeply concerned with the environmental impact of the operation of the plant, and
they staged a dramatic “collective walk” on the streets in city’s downtown. The collective
walk reportedly drew more than ten thousands of concerned residents. Under strong
pressure, the local government finally agreed to suspend the project. A similar incident
occurred in Shanghai (over the construction of a magnetic levitation train) in early
2008.466 That the homeowners were successful in forcing local governments to reverse
decisions, even temporarily, pointed to the potential of homeowners as a lobbying force.
Nevertheless, the homeowners’ committee as an organization is actually not
allowed to do lobbying work. All laws and regulations mentioned above state that the
homeowners’ committee can only engage in activities within its neighborhood.467 But it
does serve as the organizational facilitator for homeowners to pursue collective lobbying
actions. By having a homeowners’ committee, homeowners come into regular contact
with each other and discuss issues that could impact the neighborhood.
7.5.1B Homeowners’ Committees and Democratic Development
Civil society is generally regarded to have democratic implications: the more
powerful the civil society is, the more likely is the political system to be democratic. This
466
For discussion of these incidents, see Chen Jiaxi, “Cong tulu dao ‘shanbu’: yezhu lixing weiquan de xin quxiang
(From Road-blocking to ‘Walking’: The New Trend in Homeowners’ Rational Rights-Defense),” Xiandai wuyexinyezhu (Modern Property Management-New Proprietor) 5 (2008), pg. 31-33; George J. Gilboy and Benjamin Read,
“Political and Social Reform in China: Alive and Walking” Washington Quarterly 31:3 (2008), pg. 143-164.
467
Thus different from its counterpart in America, in which the Residential Community Associations are powerful
lobbying forces in local governance.
270
democratic potential of civil society is underpinned by three principal considerations.
First, civil society monitors and checks the growth of state power. As a buffer zone
between individuals and the state, it protects individuals from state’s illegitimate
intrusion, while also limiting the concentration of political power in the hands of the
state. Second, civil society serves as a training ground for citizens to learn and practice
political skills (organizing, getting elected, deal-making, lobbying) that are necessary in a
democratic system. Third, civil society also serves as an arena for the “public sphere” in
which citizens can discuss, debate, and deliberate on public issues. This would foster a
critical citizenry that is conducive to democratic norms and ideals.
Thus, we can evaluate the democratic potentials of homeowners’ committees
according to these three considerations: (1) social buffer, (2) training ground, and (3)
public sphere. Below I will first discuss the democratic potentials of homeowners’
committees according to the latter two considerations. The question of homeowners’
committees being a “social buffer” is more complex and will be discussed in the
subsequent subsection.
Like the shequ residents’ committee, the homeowners’ committee also provides a
channel for homeowners-residents to participate in democratic elections. However, the
electoral process of the homeowners’ committee is even less institutionalized and
regularized than the electoral process of the residents’ committee (see Chapter 4). There
are even more opportunities for certain actors (principally the developer) to manipulate
and influence the electoral process. Nonetheless, in comparison to residents’ reactions to
electoral abuses in residents’ committee elections, homeowners’ reactions are much more
forceful. There are numerous cases of rights-conscious homeowners challenging the
271
validity of a homeowners’ committee election, in which they often cite higher laws and
regulations against local ones.468 While it is undeniable that homeowners’ electoral
participation remains unsatisfactory in many aspects, in general it is still better than
residents’ participation in residents’ committee elections. Despite the lack of
institutionalization, many homeowners take seriously the elections of their homeowners’
committees. Electoral participation thus has the effect of socializing the participants in
the process of procedural democracy.469
By providing a platform to discuss both residential and public issues, the
homeowners’ committee is itself developing from a narrow focus on defending
homeowners’ rights to broader issues that sometimes converge with other “rightsdefense” discourses and movements. More and more homeowners-activists are now
discussing the nature of citizens’ rights, the problems and inadequacies of Chinese laws,
corruption and power abuses, environmental pollution, and issues in urban planning. The
homeowners’ committee as an organization does not deal with such issues, it nevertheless
provides the organizational groundwork for homeowners (especially the activists among
them) to interact, discuss and deliberate on these issues. In this sense, the homeowners’
committee also has the potential to become part of an emerging Chinese “public sphere”
that is critical for the formation of a democratic civil society.
468
See Wang Jianjun, “Mofanxiaoqu de yeweihui xuanju fengbo (Disputes of a Homeowners’ Committee Elections in
an Exemplary Neighborhood),” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009),
pg. 8-12; Tang Juan & Yu Pinchi, “Shequ yeweihui xuanju zhidu shizheng yanjiu [shang] (An Empirical Study of the
Election System of Homeowners’ Committee [first part]),” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –
New Proprietor) 2 (2009), pg. 28-33; Tang Juan & Yu Pingchi, “Shequ yeweihui xuanju zhidu shizheng yanjiu [zhong]
(An Empirical Study of the Election System of Homeowners’ Committee [second part]),” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu
(Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009), pg. 20-25.
469
Bai Yang, “Xuanju de yishihua gongneng: cong yeweihui xuanju laikan chengshi jiceng minzhu shijianzhong de
boyi (The Ritualization Function of Election: Urban Grassroots Democratic Practice from the Perspective of
Homeowners’ Committee Elections),” Shehui kexue (Social Sciences) 5 (2003), pg. 71-75.
272
7.5.2 Homeowners’ Committees as Civil Society Organizations with “Chinese
Characteristics”
While the preceding discussions point to the democratic potentials of
homeowners’ committees, we should also pay attention to some factors that complicate
such potentials. As observed by a foreign scholar, “the homeowner revolution has
unleashed social and economic forces whose autonomy the [party] has not anticipated
and against which they are now imposing new constraints.”470 Heavier government’s
regulations and penetration of the homeowners’ committee, interestingly, does not mean
that inevitably it is becoming less capable of protecting homeowners’ rights. In fact, there
are cases in which the involvements of party or government officials are indispensable in
successful defense of homeowners’ rights and in better neighborhood governance. But
such regulations and involvement also mean that the potential of homeowners’
committees to become a powerful force acting as a “social buffer” against party-state
encroachment is limited.
7.5.2A Restrictions on Organizing an Association of Homeowners’ Committees
Homeowners’ committees are small, localized, fragmentized, and grassrootsbased. Generally speaking, there is no coherence, coordination, or organization among
homeowners’ committees in the homeowners’ “rights-defense” movement. Each
committee basically struggles on its own. Other homeowners’ committees can only show
moral support, share experience and legal knowledge, and recommend certain tactics or a
good lawyer.
470
Deborah S. Davis, “Urban Chinese Homeowners as Citizens-Consumers,” in The Ambivalent Consumer:
Questioning Consumption in East Asia and the West, edited by Sheldon Garon and Patricia L. Maclachlan, Itacha, NY:
Cornell University Press (2006), pg. 286.
273
Attempts to form an “Association of Homeowners’ Committees” (yezhu
weiyuanhui lianhehui) that unites the homeowners’ committees within an administrative
area have been consistently thwarted. Lacking an official government sponsor (required
by Chinese law in the registration of a social organization) is the principal reason for the
unsuccessful registration of these associations.”471 Although housing and property
authorities are the obvious candidate to serve as the official sponsor, many authorities
refuse to serve as the sponsor. Fearing the growth of organizational power and influence
of the homeowners, the local authorities tend to resist the formation of these
associations.472
Homeowners however are not merely passive force in the face of this obstacle.
More entrepreneurial homeowners-activists are experimenting different ways to achieve
official recognition, or at least official tolerance. Some associations of homeowners’
committees have been formed and began to operate through subterfuge, as for example,
using names such as the “application committee for the association of homeowners’
committees” or “friendship society of homeowners’ committees.” Appendix 7.4
summarizes the experiences of an unofficial association in Guangzhou.
7.5.2B Control and Regulations
471
Homeowners’ committees are required to apply for bei’an but not register (dengji), but if these committees are to
join together as an Association of Homeowners’ Committees, then the Association has to register (dengji) as a social
organization.
472
See the press reports on the failures to form the association in the cities of Chongqing, Guangzhou, Xiamen,
Chengdu and Beijing. Wang Xiaoxia, “Yezhu weiyuanhui xiehui heyi nanchan (Why the Association of Homeowners’
Committee Failed to Form),” Zhongguo jingji shibao Sept 20, 2006; Li Chunwei, “Chongqing ‘yezhu weihuanhui
xiehui’ ganga choubei (The Awkward Preparation of the ‘Association of Homeowners’ Committee’),” 21shiji jingji
baodao May 14, 2007; Zhang Zhaoguo, “Jianli xiehui: Yeweihui de youyibo quanli zhizheng (Establishing the
Association: Another Battle for Rights of the Homeowners’ Commitees),” Renmin fayuanbao January 26, 2007.
Shenyang remains the only city to have an association of homeowners’ committees successfully formed, at the shequ
level. See Zhao Xupu, “Chengli yezhu weiyuanhui xiehui de jidian sikao (Several Points about the Establishment of an
Association of Homeowners’ Committees),” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor)
5 (2007), pg. 60-61.
274
The second factor is the increasing efforts by local governments to control and
regulate homeowners’ committees. In Shenzhen, a city that has one of the most active
homeowners’ movements in China, the city government in 2005 issued a new
regulation/instructional guidance (“The Rules of Conduct for the Homeowners’
Assembly and the Homeowners’ Committee”)473 that puts homeowners’ committees
under the supervision and guidance of the residents’ committee and the street office. The
regulation also gives local property and housing authorities the power to dissolve any
homeowners’ committee that is found to be in violation of the “Rules.” It also strongly
suggests that a “joint meeting” on property management be institutionalized, purportedly
for better coordination. The participants of the meetings include the shequ residents’
committee, the street office, local housing and property authorities, the district party
committee on politics and law, the shequ work station, public security bureaus, the
property management company and the homeowners’ committee. With many more actors
participating in property management, the influence of homeowners are significantly
diluted. The clerk hired by the homeowners’ committee to do administrative work is to be
paid by the property management company. This could have the effect of making the
clerk work for the interest of the property management company more than the
homeowners’ committee. Many homeowners in Shenzhen expressed concerns that this
new regulation will diminish the autonomy of the homeowners’ committee, and are
strongly against it.474
473
“Shenzhenshi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize (Guidance Rules for the Homeowners’ Assembly and
Homeowners’ Committee in Shenzhen),” Xiangdai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor)
5 (2005), pg. 24-27.
474
Tang Juan, “Chengshi shequ jiegou bianqianzhong de chongtu yu zhili (Conflicts and Governance in the Structural
Changes of Urban Communities)” in Chengshi shequ yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu, pg. 64-69; Ni Binlu, “Ruhe
jieding yeweihui zhuguan bumen de xingzhengquan (How to Determine the Administrative Authority of the
275
Since the decree of this regulation, the city’s complaints bureau had received
fewer cases of petitions regarding property management. The number of these cases
decreased 30% from 2004 to 2005, and 21% from 2005 to 2006. There were no more
large-scale collective visits to the complaints bureau. One could attribute this
improvement to this regulation. More involvement by the street office and the residents’
committee may actually lead to better coordination between different organizations and
better solutions to the conflicts in neighborhood.475 On the other hand, this phenomenon
can also be interpreted as the successful taming of the homeowners’ movement since the
decree of this regulation.
The regulations similar to the one in Shenzhen have also been decreed in other
cities: Jinan (2007), Zhengzhou (2007), and Beijing (2009).476 Not all provisions of these
regulations are meant to restrict homeowners’ rights and autonomy. For example, the
Beijing regulations remove one of the common restrictions of homeowners running for a
post in the homeowners’ committee –failure to pay property fees. Greater control through
regulations of homeowners’ committees by local government therefore can be seen as a
double-edge sword –the regulations dilute societal autonomy, but in some instances they
also lead to better governance.
7.5.2C Party’s Cooptation and Penetration
Government Agency Overseeing the Homeowners’ Committee)?” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property
Management –New Proprietor) 5 (2005), pg. 7-8.
475
Wu Chunxing, Tian Zuo, “Pobing zhiju, chuangxin zhilu (Ice-breaking Action, Innovative Path),” Zhongguo wuye
guanli (Chinese Property Management) 9 (2007), pg. 36-37.
476
Jiang Xingwei, “Yezhu guan xiaoqu youle ‘quanzhang’ (Scepter of Homeowners’ Authority in Neighborhood)”
Jinan ribao April 5, 2007; “Zhengzhoushi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize [shixing] (Rules of Conduct
for Homeowners’ Assembly and Homeowners’ Committee [Trial Version])” Zhengzhoushi renmin zhengfu gongbao
(Public Records of the City Government of Zhengzhou) 10 (2007), pg. 33-39; Zhu Haiyan, “Beijing chutai guize guifan
yeweihui yunxing (Beijing Issues Rules to Regulate the Operation of Homeowners’ Committees)” Chengshi kaifa
(Urban Development) 3 (2009), pg. 42-43; “Beijingshi zhuzhaiqu yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize
[shixing] (Rules of Conduct for Homeowners’ Assembly and Homeowners’ Committee in Beijing Residential Areas
[Trial Version])” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property Management-New Proprietor) 3 (2009), pg. 88-90.
276
The third factor is the cooptation and penetration of homeowners’ committees by
the party. Shanghai is the prime example of this tactic. As pointed out before, the rate of
establishing homeowners’ committees in Shanghai is far higher than other the rate in
other cities. This accomplishment nevertheless is conditioned by the integration of the
homeowners’ committees integrated with the shequ party building policy,477 specifically
under a program called “property management party building” (wuye guanli dangjian).
Below I will describe several elements of this party building program in a shequ in
Shanghai.478
Party members are encouraged to run for homeowners’ committee elections, and
to establish a party cell within the homeowners’ committee. Retired party cadres within
neighborhoods are especially encouraged to become directors of homeowners’
committees. If a committee does not have enough members to establish organizational
presence, the shequ party organization will send a liaison officer to establish link between
the party and the homeowners’ committee. As for the property management company, the
shequ party organization also directs the formation of a party cell in the company, or
alternatively sends a liaison officer to the company. If both the director of the committee
and the manager of the property management company were party members, they both
would be included in the leadership of the neighborhood party branch. In addition, a joint
meeting between the homeowners’ committee, the property management company, and
the party organization is regularly held to coordinate and resolve neighborhood issues.
477
Zhang Nian, “Shanghaishi cong zhidu he caozuo cengmian jiaqiang yeweihui gongzuo (Shanghai Strengthens the
Work on Homeowners’ Committee through Institutional and Operational Aspects),” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese
Property Management) 11 (2007), pg. 52-53.
478
He Haibing, Yu Mengmiao, “Wuye dangjian lianjian rang shequ jumin de haochu (Property Management Party
Building Benefits Community Residents),” Shequ (Community) 18 (2007), pg. 13-14.
277
“Dual leadership” mechanism is also established in local property and housing
authorities. Horizontally, the party committee in a local housing and property authority is
put under the leadership of the district party committee, while vertically it also answers to
the party committee at the higher level within the same bureaucratic hierarchy. In such a
way, there will be better coordination between work of property management and party
building work. Assessment of the performance of shequ party leaders now includes their
work in the area of “property management party building.” The aim of this “property
management party building” is to create a “holy trinity” of the homeowners’ committee,
the property management company, and the party organization, through the extensive
network of party members in the neighborhoods.
Some district authorities in Shanghai have also stated that leadership positions of
the homeowners’ committee must be occupied by party members.479 The party’s
penetration of a non-governmental organization is reminiscent of the party’s efforts to
insert itself into every social sector and organization in the past. The argument for such
party’s penetration and cooptation of the homeowners’ committee is that it would
strengthen the committee and improve neighborhood governance. In a 2006 consultative
meeting between Shanghai municipal people’s congress deputies and representatives
from residents’ committees and homeowners’ committees, some homeowners’ committee
479
See Zhou Meiyan, Yan Rui, “Cong Shanghai Xiqu Huading xiaoqu yezhu weiyuanhui xuanju kan yezhu zizhi
xianzhuang yu qianjing (The Present Situation and Prospect of Homeowners’ Self-Governance from the Perspective of
a Homeowner’s Committee Election in Huading Neighborhood, West District of Shanghai” in Chengshi shequ yezhu
weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu, pg. 252; see also the policy directive circulated by the Pudong New District government,
“Pudong xinqu guanyu jiaqiang dui yezhu weiyuanhui gongzuo zhidao he guanli de ruogan guiding (Some Measures to
Strengthen Work Guidance and Management of Homeowners’ Committee in Pudong New District)” Pudong kaifa
(Pudong Development) 8 (2001), pg. 57-58, in which Article 4 of that directive states that the party members are to
play a major role in the homeowners’ committee.
278
directors felt that those xiaoqus that were conflict-ridden or badly managed tended to be
places in which the party organization was particularly weak.480
Conclusion
This chapter focuses on the homeowners’ committee, an organization that is
smaller than the residents’ committee but is arguably a more autonomous organization.
With the emergence of property markets in Chinese urban areas, more and more urban
residents are now homeowners. As homeowners they are concerned about their rights and
interests in their own neighborhood. Homeowners’ committees primarily exist to protect
the rights and interests of homeowners, and they face a number of obstacles and
challenges in their actions. Nationally, there are Property Law of China, Regulations of
Property Management, and Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly. Provincial and city
governments also enact their own regulations regarding property management and
homeowners organization. The complex legal system is not always on their side. Property
management companies and developers, the two main adversaries of homeowners, are
also frequently backed by the local housing and property management authorities. The
procedural difficulties in establishing a homeowners’ committee, and the homeowners’
committee’s status (as an unqualified litigant) in the courts, demonstrate some of the
frustrations and problems encountered by the homeowners rights-defense movement.
On the other hand, homeowners are also quite innovative and experimental in
their efforts to defend their own interests, as was noted in several case studies. They
sometimes engage with local authority to solve common problems, institute checks and
balance among themselves, and come up with new ideas to improve their neighborhood,
480
Wang Haiyan, “Jiaqiang yeweihui gongzuo ying naru shequ dangjian (Strengthening the Work of Homeowners’
Committees should be Brought under Community Party Building)” Jiefang ribao August 8, 2006.
279
without guidance from officials. In this instance, they are clearly signs of civil society
development in China.
Homeowners’ organizations in Western countries are normally not thought as a
force for democracy. The narrow focus on homeowners’ interests and property prices
may actually be counterproductive to democracy.481 In China, however, the development
of the homeowners’ “rights-defense” movement and homeowners’ committees signify
the extraordinary self-organizing efforts among members of the more affluent Chinese
strata, their increasing demand for fairness and justice, and their willingness to engage in
collective actions, including protests and lobbying. It is something the government has
not expected. The government has tried to limit the power and influence of this
movement by regulating homeowners’ organizations, limiting their growth, and co-opting
them with party penetration. But still, the government has not suppressed the movement,
and to a certain extent, has even encouraged it. This again, is another angle in the
complex picture of citizens’ interaction with the party-state in China.
481
Daniel A. Bell, “Residential Community Associations: Community or Disunity?” in The Essential Communitarian
Reader, edited by Amitai Etzioni, Lanham, MD: Rowman &Littlefield (1998), pg. 167-176.
280
Table 7.1: Homeowners’ Committees in 12 Chinese Cities
City
Xiaoqus
Beijing
Guangzhou
Shenzhen
Zhengzhou
Shanghai
Haikou
Nanjing
Chongqing
Chengdu
Changsha
Wuhan
Guiyang
3077
About 4000
2003
1237
8661
About 600
1275
3350
2824
About 800
1200
571
Homeowners’
Committee
360
580
721
102
6786
210
599
1124
932
About 200
About 400
39
Percentage (%)
11.7%
15%
36%
8.2%
78.3%(2007)
35%
47%
33.6%
33%
25%
33.3%
6.83%
Notes: Unless otherwise noted, the data are collected in 2004 -2006.
Sources: Yang Yi, “Zhongguo yixian chengshi yezhu weiyuanhui xianzhuang diaocha (A Survey of the Present
Condition of Homeowners’ Committee in Important Cities in China)” Zhuzhai yu fangdichan (Housing and Real
Estate) 11 (2006), pg. 7-9; Wu Liping, “Guanyu Guiyangshi zhuzhai xiaoqu [daxia] yezhu weiyuanhui de diaocha (A
Study of the Homeowners’ Committee in the Residential Neighborhoods in Guiyang)” in Chengshi shequ yezhu
weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu (Studies of the Development of Homeowners’ Committee in Urban Communities), edited by
Tang Juan, Chongqin: Chongqin chubanshe (2005), pg. 271; Zhang Nian, “Shanghaishi cong zhidu he caozuo
cengmian jiaqiang yeweihui gongzuo (Shanghai Strengthens the Work on Homeowners’ Committee through
Institutional and Operational Aspects)” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese Property Management) 11 (2007), pg. 52.
281
Chapter 8: Conclusion and Discussion
The previous chapters have documented, analyzed and discussed the politicalinstitutional reforms at the grassroots-level in China’s urban communities. Chapter 4 is
focused on the election procedure of the residents’ committee, while Chapter 5 describes
and analyzes the governance and administration of shequ. Chapter 6 discusses and
evaluates the role of the party organization and its relationship with democratic
development, and Chapter 7 introduces a non-governmental organization that plays an
important role in the politics and governance of shequ –the homeowners’ committee. But
what theoretical and practical conclusions should we draw from these developments?
How will they impact on the wider polity? What would be the main implications for the
Chinese political system? In this concluding analysis, I argue that three theoretical
interpretations can be applied to the shequ democratic reforms: 1) a societal democracy
that will “spillover” to state democracy; 2) authoritarian resilience and strengthening, and
3) embodiment of a “Chinese-style” democracy.
8.1 From “Societal” Democracy to “State” Democracy
As noted in Chapter 3, the Chinese official understanding and thinking of local
autonomy and democracy conceptualize them as belonging to the sphere of societal
democracy (represented by grassroots organizations such as the residents’ committee and
the villagers’ committee), in contrast to the sphere of “state” democracy (exemplified by
the people’s congresses at various levels). According to this understanding, societal-level
democracy does not determine the personnel or policies of the government, which are left
to the state, at least nominally. Therefore, the people’s congresses at different levels pass
laws and elect officials, whereas institutions in the societal level do not. The primary
282
purpose of societal democracy is to allow ordinary residents to directly manage their own
affairs and improve their own quality of life.482
This view allows Chinese officials to have some flexibility in terms of
experimenting with political reforms. Political reforms can be experimented in the
societal arena first. If experimentations in political reforms at the grassroots/societal level
fail, it will not have a serious impact on the whole political system. If they succeed, the
state has the option to adopt some of these policy innovations, but is not obliged to do so.
The dissolution of the Soviet state (together with the economy and the ruling party)
particularly makes the Chinese leadership worried about any bold political reforms at the
state level. They allow political reforms at the societal level to respond to citizens’
demand for increased participation, but these reforms would not affect the overall
political system.
However, if societal democracy has no substantial impact on the state institutions,
then this also implies that the democratic reforms at the grassroots level are basically just
grassroots reforms and no more than that. You could have a vibrant and robust
democratic life and institutions at the local and societal arena, but the state will remain
unaffected. Furthermore, this societal democracy is never secure without the state
democracy. This is because, as Giovanni Sartori argues, that although societal democracy
“[provides] the societal backbone and infrastructure of the political structure” and forms
the “the extra-political substratum and foundation of political democracy,” ultimately “if
482
Zhang Tao, Wang Xiangmin, Chen Wenxin, Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju yanjiu (A Study of Direct
Elections in Grassroots Urban China), Chongqin: Chongqin chubanshe (2008), pg. 180-181.
283
the enforcer of force, the state, is not a democracy, then all the infrastructures, all the
microdemocracies…are in mortal danger.”483
From Alex de Tocqueville’s and John Dewey’s perspective, however, democracy
within the local, societal, and associational arenas trains, secures and sustains the
necessary skills, attitudes, and relationships for a democratic political system.
Tocqueville wrote that “town-meetings are to liberty what primary schools are to science;
they bring it within people’s reach, they teach them how to use and how to enjoy it.”484
For Dewey, democracy is not just a matter of political system or constitutional design; for
in modern large-scale societies, the chances of people having regard for their distant
fellow citizens are limited, unless they have the “neighborhood experiences” to bring
them the “love and understanding” for each other. Therefore, “democracy must begin at
home, and its home is the neighborly community.”485 Other theorists also argue that
participation in democracy at the primary levels allows “individuals…to learn about key
issues in resource creation and control.” Thus, they will “be far better equipped to judge
national questions, assess the performance of political representatives and participate in
decisions of national scope when the opportunity [arises].”486
Chinese scholars and reformers also vigorously debate this issue. Some contend
that societal-level democratization should take precedence over state-level
democratization and echo the theoretical viewpoints expressed by the Western theorists
noted above. For example, a Chinese scholar argues that “if at the society level the
483
Giovanni Sartori. The Theory of Democracy Revisited, Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers (1987), pg. 8-9,
386, 161.
484
Alexis de Tocqueville, Alexis de Tocqueville on Democracy, Revolution and Society, edited by John Stone and
Stephen Mennell. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press (1980), pg. 54.
485
John Dewey. The Public and its Problems, Denver, CO: Alan Swallow (1954), pg. 213.
486
David Held, Models of Democracy, 2nd edition, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press (1996), pg. 269-270.
284
citizens were unable to establish…self-governing organizations that represent their own
interests…then their electoral rights at the state level [would be inconceivable].
Democracy of the state was founded upon the societal democracy.”487 Another one
argues that “if democracy can be implemented in villages and shequs, then the
representative institutions at the state level should be strengthened as well. The forces and
pressures generated from village and shequ self-governance can enhance democratic
construction at the state level.”488
On the other hand, from a more strategic point of view, the sensitivity of political
reforms in China means that democratization can only proceed along a cautious, gradual,
step-by-step and slow pace. A radical program of democratization could be disruptive
will risk another “Tiananmen Incident” that traumatizes the people. Rather,
democratization should be patiently pushed forward. It requires tactics, planning,
strategies. Some Chinese analysts thus advocate the building up of societal/grassroots
democracy (along with inner-party democracy, rule of law, public consultation, etc.) as
the foundations for a future democratic polity.489 Thus, even though societal democracy
and state democracy belong to two different spheres, they can affect each other’s
development in a cyclical, reinforcing ways. Eventually, there could be a “spillover”
from societal democracy to state democracy.
487
Wang Bangzuo et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi yanjiu (The Residents’
Committee and Community Governance: An Organizational Study of the Residents’ Committee in Urban
Communities), Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe (2003), pg.113.
488
Yang Zhuoru, “Nongcun he shequ minzhu dui jiceng renda xuanju de juda shifanli (The Great Demonstration Effect
on Grassroots Peoples’ Congress Election by Village and Community Democracy)” Zhongguo shehuibao September
16, 2004, pg. T00.
489
Xiao Lihui, “Tuijin minzhu de zhanlue yu celue (Tactics and Strategy to Push Forward Democracy)” Xuexi shibao
October 9, 2006, pg. 005.
285
From this perspective, the institutional democratic developments in shequ
presented in this dissertation are remarkable. They contain the seeds of liberal democracy
(exemplified by the competitive elections of residents’ committees), deliberative
democracy (residents’ participation and deliberations in the various decision-making and
consultative bodies, in the drafting process of self-governance documents, and in the
evaluation and supervision meetings of officials), inner-party democracy (more open
participation by party members and non-party members in the election and evaluation of
party leaders), and civil society development and cooperation with the state
(homeowners’ committees). Eventually, residents’ participation in these grassroots
institutions may socialize them into democratic norms and practices, promote a culture of
accountability of officials, empower and train them critical citizenship skills, and
strengthen their political efficacy. Grassroots party organizations will be forced to adjust
to a more democratically lively populace, while homeowners’ committees will fulfill
their democratic potential as civil society organizations.
Deliberative democratic theorists will also find the deliberative and participatory
aspects of some of these shequ institutions exciting and conducive to democratic
development in China. Unsatisfied with the strong focus on electoral, representative and
aggregative institutions in the liberal democratic model, as well as its rational
individualist assumption and adversarial conception of relationship between society and
the state, deliberative democratic theory champions citizens’ deliberation and
participation in the policy and governance processes. Civil society, community
involvement, and deliberative institutions are therefore important elements of a
democratic polity. Deliberative theorists, however, also view deliberative democracy and
286
liberal democracy as supporting each other. Therefore, with the absence or
underdevelopment of liberal-democratic institutions in China, some deliberative
democratic theorists argue that “developing deliberative institutions is…a [sensible]
democratizing strategy, a step toward a more full-scale democracy.”490
Comparison with the experiences of Taiwan, another “Chinese” society, in which
its democratization was rooted in the local elections implemented in the 1950s, also
strengthens the argument that shequ democratic development will have a long-term
consequence. For many years grassroots elections in Taiwan were dominated by local
party bosses or strongmen connected to the ruling regime, but overtime it
institutionalized the principles of free and fair elections, and political legitimacy based on
democracy. It was also partly from these grassroots elections that an organized opposition
force (the dangwai) eventually emerged.
In recent years, there have been some cases in which shequ democracy does to a
certain degree affect democratization at the state’s institutions, the elections of local
people’s congresses. The elections of people’s congress deputies are overwhelmingly
“confirmative elections.” Voters are to vote for the nominees that have to be elected.491
In the recent election cycles, however, more and more “independent candidates,” the
candidates with no official blessing and support, have emerged.
490
Baogang He, “Western Theories of Deliberative Democracy and Chinese Practice of Complex Deliberative
Governance” in The Search for Deliberative Democracy in China, edited by Ethan J. Leib and Baogang He. New York,
NY: Palgrave Macmillan (2006), pg. 136. Although He was referring to other (but similar) participatory and
deliberative institutions in China, the same generalization can be applied here.
491
Tang Juan, “Cong querenxing xuanju dao jingxuanxing xuanju: dongying yu yiyi (From Confirmative Election to
Competitive Election: Factors and Implications) Nanjing shehui kexue (Social Sciences in Nanjing) 3 (2004), pg. 39-43.
287
Many of these “independent candidates” come from a background as
homeowners- activists in shequ.492 They were driven by motives that were relatively
novel in China –to protect and articulate their interests as homeowners (on this point, see
more discussion in Chapter 7).493 In this sense, these independent candidates are changing
the nature and logic of “one-party competitive elections.” Many “independent
candidates” also draw considerable support from shequ residents. They were supportive
of those candidates who have been a familiar face in promoting the interests and welfare
of shequ residents.494 Local people’s congress elections have, therefore, become more
competitive, challenging, and meaningful.
There were less than 100 “independent candidates” in China in the 2003 election.
The number has since exploded to around 40,000 in 2006/2007. The drastic increase in
the number of “independent candidates” has prompted John F. Thornton, the current
chairman of the board of Brookings Institution, to talk about the “prospects for
democracy” in China.495 As “democratic training grounds,” shequ could produce its fair
share of “independent candidates” for local people’s congress elections with governance
experiences through residents’ committees or homeowners’ committees. This is an
indication of how politics at the “societal,” grassroots level could “spillover” to the
politics at “state” institutions in China.
8.2 Political Reforms of a Resilient Authoritarian Regime
492
Zou Shubin, Tang Juan, Huang Weiping, “2003nian renda daibiao jingxuan de qunti xiaoying: Beijing yu Shenzhen
bijiao (The Mass Implications of Competitive Elections for Deputies to the People’s Congresses in 2003: Comparing
Beijing and Shenzhen)” in Zhongguo xianshi wenti yanjiu qianyan baogao 2005-2006 (A Report on the Frontier
Research on China’s Present Issues 2005-2006), edited by Li Huibin & Xue Xiaoyuan, Shanghai: Huadong shifan
daxue chubanshe (2006), pg. 282-285.
493
Fan Qing, “Zou Jiajian: yezhu wenzheng (Zou Jiajian: A Homeowner’s Political Participation)” Xin Jingbao
January 4, 2004.
494
Guo Hua, “Shenzhen: Shequ xuanmin tuidong jingxuan fengyun (Shenzhen: Community Voters Pushing for the
Eventful Competitive Elections) Shequ (Community) 9:17 (2003), pg. 6-11.
495
John L. Thorton, “Long Time Coming: The Prospects for Democracy in China” Foreign Affairs 87:1 (2008), pg. 8.
288
The second interpretation is in direct contrast to the first interpretation. In this
view, the democratization reforms at the grassroots level, though substantial, are not
intended to bring forth a total change of the political system, but rather aim to strengthen
and consolidate the one-party authoritarian rule. These reforms illustrate the resilience
and adaptability of a powerful and smart authoritarian regime, not the foundations for a
future democratic polity. In this analysis, the Chinese Communist Party survived the
global “third wave” of democratization by instituting a number of critical reforms, such
as the normalization of leadership succession politics, basing both recruitment and
promotion of the political elite on merit, turning officials into functionally specific
bureaucrats, and more importantly, establishing “institutions for political participation
and appeal that strengthens the CCP’s legitimacy at large.”496
This line of reasoning goes on to suggest that recent attention to the rule of law,
“socialist democracy,” the government’s transparency, and the party’s governing
capability, is “to buttress the party’s effectiveness and acceptability, not subject its rule to
challenge by nonparty outsiders.”497 Decentralization of power, a variable generally
correlated with democratic rule, has not made China more democratic, but has made the
regime more secure and led to strong economic development. Village elections are meant
to “grant authority to the best managers of local development, not to provide an
opportunity to elect national leaders from multiple parties.”498 Increased oversight of
power by the media and citizens exposes corruption. This may taint the party’s image in
496
Andrew J. Nathan, “Authoritarian Resilience,” Journal of Democracy 14:1 (2003), pg. 6-17.
Andrew J. Nathan, “China’s Political Trajectory: What Are the Chinese Saying?” in China’s Changing Political
Landscape, edited by Cheng Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press (2008), pg. 30.
498
Sophie Richardson, “Self-Reform Within Authoritarian Regimes: Reallocations of Power in Contemporary China,”
in Political Civilization and Modernization in China, edited by Yang Zhong & Shiping Hua. Singapore: World
Scientific (2006), pg. 160.
497
289
the short term, but it will strengthen the party’s legitimacy in the long term. Reforms in
governance, therefore, will make the regime more responsive, effective, and durable, but
will not necessarily transform the regime transform into a democracy.
Applying this interpretation to the shequ, the institutional and political reforms
could be interpreted as a strategy for consolidating the party’s position at the grassroots
level in the cities. Electoral reforms are premised on the ground that they will improve,
not erode, the party’s legitimacy and rule. Individual party cadres and members of the
residents’ committees will become more accountable to the people, but not the leadership
status of the party. The participatory and deliberative institutions in the processes of
democratic decision-making, democratic management and democratic supervision
exemplify what Baogang He terms “authoritarian deliberation.” As he notes,
contemporary authoritarian rule no longer relies on sheer force (and pure propaganda) to
secure compliance and consent from the ruled. It uses devices with democratic trappings,
such as deliberative institutions, to reduce conflicts, mobilize support for and
implementations of state policy, and overcome oppositions.499 Furthermore, as noted in
Chapter 5, many of the deliberative institutions have certain flaws. They are far from the
ideal deliberative institutions that promise “the maximization of communicative power”
and “the minimization of the influence of money and power.”500
Critically, the shequ jianshe (community construction) policy was immediately
followed by the shequ dangjian (community party building) policy. Reforms undertaken
by the shequ party organization are to reinforce the leading position of the party. For
499
Baogang He, “Western Theories of Deliberative Democracy,” pg. 134-136. He nevertheless contends that
“authoritarian deliberation” is inherently contradictory, since it also exhibits a “potential logic of democratization.”
500
Baogang He and Ethan J. Leib, “Editors’ Introduction” in The Search for Deliberative Democracy in China, pg. 4.
290
example, although the incorporation of the residents’ committee and the shequ party
leadership forces the latter to subject itself to popular scrutiny, more likely it will also
tighten the party’s control of the residents’ committee, making sure that it will never turn
into a popular base for organizing opposition force to the party, as the local elections in
Taiwan once did.
As for the homeowners’ committee, adherents of this interpretation will be
skeptical of the homeowners’ committee’s ability to realize the democratic potential of a
civil society organization. The self-organizing capability of the homeowners is
impressive, but China’s authoritarianism is no longer fearful of the growing power of the
society. Instead, it aims to utilize the societal energy and initiatives to solve the issues the
regime itself is unable or unwilling to solve. Chinese societal institutions, such as NGOs,
could, therefore, flourish, but they will not likely pose political dangers to the regime.
Moreover, as the analysis in Chapter 7 points out, in many cities in which the
homeowners’ movement is vibrant, the local governments have also, through regulations
and laws, successfully tamed or co-opted the homeowners’ committees. These
regulations and co-optations actually result in better governance of the neighborhoods,
but homeowners’ autonomy is also significantly reduced.
Finally, adherents of this interpretation will more likely agree with Sartori than
with Tocqueville, Dewey or Held. Grassroots, societal democratization are only reforms
at the margins of the political system. As long as the core of the system has not changed,
the marginal reforms are not truly democratizing reforms. Grassroots, societal
democratization could result in better governance. Good governance is, however, not
democracy. The institutional-political reforms in the shequ signify the adaptability,
291
adjustment, and mending of a resilient authoritarian regime, not a transformative
phenomenon that will lead to eventual democracy.
8.3 A Working Model for Socialist Democracy with Chinese Characteristics
The third interpretation does not necessarily disagree with the analyses made by
the first and second interpretations. But it differs from them in terms of their judgment.
China is democratizing, and is starting from the grassroots arena, as the first
interpretation asserts. But China is not necessarily progressing to an eventual liberal
democratic system, as Taiwan did. Furthermore, China is not, as the second interpretation
argues, democratizing along the lines of the liberal democratic model; but it is
“democratizing” toward a “Chinese-style” democracy. The third interpretation thus sees
shequ political reforms as part of the experimentations to construct a “socialist
democracy with Chinese characteristics.”
In recent years, some foreign observers have been buoyed by some prodemocracy statements made by Chinese leaders, including President Hu Jintao and
Primer Wen Jiabao. To be sure, the Chinese Communist Party has never renounced
democracy officially. However, early leaders such as Mao Zedong and Deng Xiaoping
always stressed the differences between the “bourgeois” form of democracy and
“proletariat” form of democracy, and rejected the former. What is interesting in the
speeches of recent Chinese leaders is the view that “democracy, law, freedom, human
rights, equality, and fraternity are not characteristics unique to capitalism. They are the
shared fruits of civilization that have come into being in the history of the whole world
292
and are among the values that mankind has collectively pursued.”501 In other words, the
universal language these Chinese leaders use might lead some foreign observers to
believe that the regime is committed to realizing a form of democratic rule that is similar
to other democratic systems in the foreseeable future. But this is not the case. Although
the Chinese leaders acknowledge the universal appeal of democratic values and systems,
they continue to emphasize that they want to construct a “socialist democracy” that is
conditioned by the social and historical characteristics of China. “Socialist democracy
with Chinese characteristics,” not liberal democratic model, is consistently put forth as
the form of democracy the party is pursuing.
As noted in the introduction chapter, the term “democracy” has been abused and
stretched to mask some of the worst regimes possible (such as the Democratic People’s
Republic of Korea). Might the “socialist democracy with Chinese characteristics” be just
another attempt to prolong and justify authoritarian rule rather than a genuine democratic
alternative to the mainstream liberal democratic model? The question whether there is a
genuine form of democracy that is different from the prevalent liberal democratic model
has long pre-occupied political scientists. In western societies, the development of the
deliberative and participatory theories of democracy, the persistence of “real democracy”
in several New England town-hall meetings502, the introduction of larger scale direct
democracy through initiatives and referenda, and the expansion of “advocacy
democracy” through increased citizens’ access to policy deliberation and formation –
501
Wen Jiabao in a 2005 press conference, cited in Dali Yang, “China’s Long March to Freedom,” Journal of
Democracy 18:3 (2007), pg. 61.
502
Frank M. Bryan, Real Democracy: The New England Town Meeting and How It Works. Chicago, IL: University of
Chicago Press (2004).
293
usually through public interest organizations503 –indicate some genuine democratic
innovations and efforts to bypass the liberal institutions of elected representative bodies,
political parties, and in some instances, elections as well. But all these non-liberal modes
of democracy essentially have to operate within a liberal democratic framework, so
analysts might question whether they signify genuine democratic alternatives or only
efforts to remedy the illnesses of the existing liberal system.
Chinese scholars are also in search of this genuine democratic alternative. In the
2009 Wuhan conference on “Chinese-style democracy,” a leading Chinese scholar
suggested the theoretical possibility of a democratic policy making process with
extensive public participation. In the policy formulation stage, the people are extensively
consulted through hearings, assessments, and other mechanisms that let the people
directly contribute their ideas and opinions, and in the final stage, the people also make
the final decision, within an environment of free flow of information. He finds the “massline” policies during Mao’s era to echo such a democratic process, even many Chinese
analysts had doubts about the democratic aspects of the “mass line” policies.504 Another
Chinese scholar at the conference alluded to a theoretical viewpoint in China in which a
“Chinese-style democracy” is already in place. This “Chinese-style democracy”
recognizes people’s sovereignty, uses a system of representation that emphasizes the
“delegate”505 nature of the representatives, incorporates democratic mechanisms in the
503
Russell J. Dalton, Susan E. Scarrow, and Bruce E. Cain, “Advanced Democracies and the New Politics,” in Annual
Editions: Comparative Politics 09/10, edited by O. Fiona Yap. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill (2010), pg. 15-22.
504
Wang Shaoguang, “Gongzhong juece canyu jizhi: yige fenxi kuangjia (Mechanism of Public Participation in
Decision Making: An Analytical Framework),” paper presented at the International Conference on “Chinese-Style”
Democracy, Wuhan University, China, November 13-15, 2009.
505
“Delegate” representation means the elected should always defer to the will of the elector, and recallable anytime,
whereas “trustee” representation means that the elector trusts the elected to make the best decisions. The elected
becomes accountable to the elector only in elections.
294
structures of both the ruling party and the state, and continues to experiment with ways to
improve the democratic character of itself.506 Some other Chinese scholars, instead of
following the official or Marxist lines of reasoning, seek to draw inspiration from
Chinese indigenous cultural and philosophical tradition to construct a “Chinese-style”
democracy based on tenets of Confucianism.507
Some Western scholars do take seriously the efforts by the Chinese to build a
genuinely democratic system different from liberal democracy. For example, one scholar
contends that although there had not been a drastic change of the socialist political
institutions built since 1949, increasingly “democratic content” has been added to the
“democratic form” of these socialist institutions as a result of significant decentralization
of political and economic power.508 Sensitive to the cultural tradition and the profound
socio-economic transformation taking place in China, she also contends that concepts
such as democracy, justice, and freedom need to be contextualized. Judged by it’s own
standards and compared to its own past, China is gradually becoming more democratic
and the Chinese people have gained many rights they previously lacked; but China’s
leaders are determined not to be hostage to standards and values about democracy created
by the Western liberal democratic system.509
Another argument for “theoretical possibility of a party-state democracy” in
China is that, although liberal democracy has been popular and effective for a long time,
in essence it neither expresses the will of the people nor produces the best leadership. A
506
Bo Zhiyue, “Zhongguo de minzhu moshi (Democratic Models of China),” paper presented at the International
Conference on “Chinese-Style” Democracy, Wuhan University, China, November 13-15, 2009.
507
These scholar include Bai Tongdong, Wang Guansheng, and Li Yinghua.
508
Suzanne Ogden, “The Changing Content of China’s Democratic Socialist Institutions,” in Establishing Democratic
Rule: The Reemergence of Local Governments in Post-Authoritarian Systems, edited by Ilpyong J. Kim & Jane Shapiro
Zacek, Washington, DC: Washington Institute Press (1993), pg. 137-156.
509
Suzanne Ogden, Inklings of Democracy in China, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (2002).
295
broader conceptualization of democracy that incorporated “consensus,” would allow for
the inclusion of a Chinese style democratic system. Democratic consensus, which
assumes benefits for the people, majority rule, and protection of minority rights and
interest, could exist under CCP leadership. Although the present system is not yet
qualified to claim the title democracy, a Chinese path of “party-state democratization,”
which theoretically can fulfill all three aspects of democratic consensus, could present a
genuine alternative democratic system. The theory of “three represents” by Jiang Zemin
and the Hu-Wen administration’s emphasis on the governing capability of the party could
be seen as the correct steps toward this “party-state democracy.”510
Other China specialists have argued that the communist tradition of “democratic
centralism” could become a coherent and defensible alternative to liberal democracy.
Democratic centralism is premised on mass participation and articulation of interests on
an equal basis at the “input” stage of policy-making. As an “input” democracy, it is not
necessarily weaker than the citizens’ control of policies through electing parties and
politicians in liberal democratic systems. Although the “centralism” part in democratic
centralism is more problematic, it does not necessary rule out public criticism and
dissent. Properly reformed and institutionalized, democratic centralism could fulfill
Rawls’ standard of a “decent” regime and China’s own standard of legitimacy. Although
the current political situation in China falls short of the standards of “decent democratic
centralism,” this again does not disqualify China from constructing a “decent democratic”
system different from the liberal system.511
510
Brantly Womack, “Democracy and the Governing Party: A Theoretical Perspective,” in Political Civilization and
Modernization in China, pg. 121-147.
511
Stephen C. Angle, “Decent Democratic Centralism,” Political Theory 33:4 (2005), pg. 518-546.
296
While the search for this “Chinese-style democracy” as an alternative democratic
system continues to intrigue scholars, the official model of “socialist democracy with
Chinese characteristics” has already been put in place for a number of years. The fullest
statement is the 2005 White Paper on the “Building of Political Democracy in China.”
The White paper asserts that the leadership of the ruling Chinese Communist Party is
indispensable in realizing the goal of people becoming the masters of their own state. The
people’s congress system, the system of ethnic autonomous regions, multi-party
cooperation and political consultation between political parties and social organizations
under the leadership of the Communist Party, grassroots democracy practiced in villages,
shequ, and state-owned work units, “inner-party democracy,” respect for human rights (in
particular the social and economic rights), “governmental democracy” (defined as an
administration based on laws and policy-making process that reflect public opinions
through mechanisms such as hearings), and “judicial democracy” (defined as the
accountability of the courts and the procurators to the people’s congresses), are the eight
elements that comprise the core of this model.
To be sure, this is not a complete model. The same White Paper acknowledges
that the “democratic system [in China] is not yet perfect.” It reckons that “there is still
a long way to go in China’s building of political democracy,” but continues to assert
that China will find its own path, in which “there is no one single and absolute
democratic mode in the world that is universally applicable.”512
As noted in the introduction chapter, the task of this dissertation is to examine and
analyze the institutions that embody “democratic” rule in the shequ in Chinese cities,
512
“China's 2005 White Paper: ‘Building of Political Democracy in China’” Asian Affairs: An American Review 33:1
(2006), pg. 34.
297
with the term “democracy” understood in the context of the official discourse. Seen
from this perspective, the political and institutional reforms in Chinese shequ are part
and parcel of the “Socialist Democracy with Chinese Characteristics.” We can infer
that a “democratic model” of Chinese shequ contain the following elements:
1. Sufficient, but not full, autonomy for the residents’ committee.
2. Direct residents’ committee elections that allow people to have choice and
nomination rights.
3. Electoral contestation that allows candidates to promote themselves on the basis
of capabilities and policy differences.
4. High level of voters’ participation in residents’ committee elections.
5. Residents’ right to recall elected members of the residents’ committee.
6. Active participation and deliberation by residents in residents’ small groups and
the residents’ assembly.
7. Autonomy and highest decision-making power of the residents’ assembly.
8. Clear accountability and responsibility between the residents’ committee and the
residents’ assembly.
9. Deliberation between different groups, and elite/expert consultation, through the
deliberative council.
10. Mass initiatives, through deliberation and participation, in the creation and
implementation of self-governing rules and regulations.
11. Open management by the residents’ committee to strengthen residents’
supervision.
12. Periodic public assessment and evaluation of the performance of government
officials and members of the residents’ committee.
13. High level of satisfaction with the fairness and performance of the shequ
officials.
14. Availability of channels for voicing opinions and suggestions.
15. Broad representation of diverse interests by the party organization.
16. The party’s commitment to serving the residents and neighborhood.
17. Institutionalized mechanisms that subject party leaders to popular scrutiny.
18. Sufficient, but not full, autonomy for non-governmental organizations, such as
the homeowners’ committee.
19. Close cooperation and coordination between non-governmental organizations,
the party organization, and the residents’ committee, to work together for the
common good and better governance.
This “democracy” certainly differs from the liberal emphasis on political contestation
based on different interests, opposition politics, separation of powers, aggregative
representation, freedoms of speech and association, alternative sources of information,
298
etc. The democratic content of public administration (decision making, management,
supervision) is as important as the election itself. Citizens’ direct participation and
deliberation in the decision and rule making process are encouraged. A deliberative body
is to involve the relevant stakeholders representing different sectors of the society in the
discussion of policy matters. Coordination replaces checks and balances, yet the need to
properly supervise the officials and leaders is recognized. One-party competitive
elections help to produce good and capable leaders, get rid of bad leaders, represent broad
interests of the masses, and ensure leadership accountability. The continuing leadership
of the communist party does not preclude it from broadly representing the different
interests of a diversifying society. Individual party leaders are also accountable to the
masses. Civil society organizations play a role too. They maintain cooperative
relationship with the authorities and form an integral part of the process that ensures good
governance. They also provide another channel for people to participate in public affairs.
In this style of democracy, policies are produced through a process that requires
participatory deliberation, community involvement and approval, and aims to achieve
broad consensus. Theoretically speaking, these policies could be as effective and
legitimate as the policies resulted from competitive multiparty elections. It differs, of
course, from the adversarial nature of politics in liberal democracies. It shares a lot more
similarities with the mode of deliberative democracy, but differs from the latter’s
emphasis on social autonomy from the political authorities.
Of course, one could argue that this democratic model, as good as it is, only
applies to shequ. But shequ/grassroots democracy is part of the overall “democratic
system” laid out in the 2005 White Paper. It testifies to the sophisticated structure of an
299
alternative democratic system. Furthermore, if such a model could work well at the
local/grassroots level, with proper changes and adjustment, it could be the path taken by
the center for the overall democratization of the political system, since this model is also
perfectly in tune with the central leadership’ promotion of “harmonious society” in recent
years. The White Paper acknowledges that “socialist democracy with Chinese
characteristics” is not static and will continue to be improved and perfected. In this sense,
the political reforms in shequ signify a working model of such a democracy.
This is not to say that the present political-institutional designs of shequ are
flawless. The above presentation of this democratic model is an idealized form and its
flaws and problems have been noted throughout this dissertation. But this does not
significantly affect the argument that the Chinese model of democracy could be
genuinely democratic yet different from the liberal systems. After all, the liberal systems
also have problems and continue to be reformed and improved.
Conclusion
In this final chapter, I discuss the three theoretical perspectives for the
interpretation of the political democratic reforms in the shequ. The first theoretical
perspective sees shequ reforms as providing “democratic preparation” and a “democratic
foundation” at the social and local arenas that will eventually make the political system
evolve to a full democracy comparable to the mainstream liberal systems in other
societies. Even if this were not the intention of the central leaders, these reforms
nevertheless contain such a logic that intention of the actors does not matter. This
300
theoretical perspective is therefore optimistic about the democratic future of China and
sees the democratization of shequ as playing a significant part in it.
The second perspective sees political reforms in shequ as necessary adjustments
and mending of the authoritarian system to prolong authoritarian rule, not to prepare for
democratic rule. This perspective is skeptical about the idealized democratic promises of
shequ political reforms; for nothing is more promising than opening up the political
system at the center, but this is not likely to happen any time soon. Shequ
democratization and self-governance ease some of the party-state’s burden of looking
after the daily lives of its city population, fulfill the demands of some participation by
urban residents, rationalize the urban governance system, make the cadres more
responsive and accountable to public opinion, and thereby diffuse social tensions and
instability. They only make the authoritarian rule more durable for the foreseeable future.
This perspective, therefore, is more pessimistic about the democratic future of China and
sees shequ reforms as playing no important role if democratization eventually occurs.
The third perspective sees democratic reforms in shequ as both the part and parcel
of a genuine democratic alternative implemented in China –the “socialist democracy with
Chinese characteristics.” Shequ democracy, together with village democracy and
workplace democracy in state’s work units, ensure the broadest level of citizen
empowerment and participation. Its own democratic development also suggests ways for
the whole system to improve. The more democratic election procedure in some residents’
committee elections could be the model of people’s congress elections. The relationship
between the residents’ committee, the residents’ assembly, and the deliberative council
could be seen as a microcosm of the relationship between the executive branch, the
301
people’s congress, and the people’s political consultative conference at different levels of
government. Shequ democratic reforms that rationalize the structure of relationship
between the three bodies and at the same time empower residents deliberative and
participatory powers suggest ways to reform these three bodies at the higher levels of
government. In short, according to this perspective, China has its own democratic future,
and shequ democracy is a crucial part of it.
My own inclination is toward the third interpretation. This does not mean that the
present political system is the best path for China to move along. The Chinese political
system continues to jail dissidents, limit freedoms of speech, press and association,
interfere in its own judicial process, and breed corruption. But many Chinese scholars
and officials also believe that a wholesale adoption of the liberal democratic system will
not solve China’s problems. In some instances, it will only exacerbate the existing
problems. Some of these scholars and officials, of course, also have something to lose if
China turns into a liberal democracy; but others see the liberal system as too disruptive
for a country the size of China. In their view, China might well have hundred of political
parties and a fragmented party system if it opens up its political system today. In a
parliamentary system, the fragile ruling coalition could be too weak to produce coherent
and effective policies and governance (witness India, at least until recently), whereas in a
presidential system, constant deadlocks between a president from one party and a
legislature with multiple strong opposition parties could happen (witness Ukraine).
Liberal democracy also runs the risk of national disintegration (witness the Soviet
Union).
302
If China today recognizes the flaws in its present system, but wants to improve it
on its own terms, to construct a system of democracy suitable to its own conditions, this
is laudable. A “socialist democracy with Chinese characteristics” may work better for
China than the liberal system. It may turn out to be a failure too, but again, we should not
determine such a regime is undemocratic and unworkable just because it is not a liberal
democratic system. In the long future, liberal democracies may still turn out to be the
ultimate “end of history” type of victor (just as the communists once believed they were
the “end of history” victors), but it cannot earn this victory uncontested. After all, if
liberal democracy is a system that is pluralistic and accepting of different ideas, it should
welcome the positive potential of the Chinese model of democracy.
303
Appendices
Appendix 2.1: Models of Shequ Jianshe513
Below are brief sketches of some of the more prominent models of shequ jianshe
in China. Other models not discussed here include the Beijing model, the Nanjing model,
and others.
Shanghai model
Shanghai was one of the earliest cities to initiate shequ reforms. This model aims
to bolster the street office, rather than only the residents’ committee. Confusingly for
outsiders, Shanghai defines shequ at the level of the street office, while not denying that
each the jurisdiction of the residents’ committee also constitutes a shequ. 1995 it
implemented an ambitious program to reform the street offices. The reform is called “two
levels of government, three levels of administration (liangji zhengfu, sanji guanli)”514,
which increased the authority of the street office, such as giving its more autonomous
control of finance and strengthening its ability to coordinate the district-level government
departments under its jurisdiction. The duties of the street office also expanded; it now
has to take care of local economic development as well.
513
Unless otherwise noted, the discussion in this Box is based on the following sources: Ren Yuan, Zhang
Zhigang, “Zhongguo chengshi shequ fazhan dianxing shijian moshi de bijiao yu fenxi (Comparison and
Analysis of the Basic Models in Urban China Community Development)” Shehui kexue yanjiu (Social
Science Research) 6 (2003), pg. 97-100; Robert Benewick, Irene Tong, Jude Howell, “Self-Governance
and Community: A Preliminary Comparison between Villagers’ Committees and Urban Community
Councils” China Information 18:1 (2004), pg. 19-22; James Derleth and Daniel R. Koldyk, “The Shequ
Experiment: Grassroots Political Reform in Urban China,” Journal of Contemporary China, 13:41 (2004),
pg. 747-777; Akio Takahara and Robert Benewick, “Party Work in Urban Communities” in The Chinese Communist
Party in Reform, edited by Kjeld Erik Brodsgaard and Zheng Yongnian, New York, NY: Routledge (2006), pg. 157172.
514
Two levels of government refer to the city government and the district government, and three levels of
administration refer to the city, district, and street office level. As mentioned in Chapter 2, technically the
street office is only a field office of the district government and does not constitute an independent level of
government itself. This reform thus aimed to strengthen the street office.
304
With the Ministry of Civil Affairs eagerly promoting the role of the residents’
committee, Shanghai later modified its model and added the residents’ committees as the
fourth level in a new formula of “two levels of government, three levels of
administration, and four levels of network” (liangji zhengfu, sanji guanli, shiji wangluo).
The new formula aimed to give more significance to the residents’ committee as
implementer of policies. At the street office level, Shanghai also introduced the
functional committee system as a way of coordinating the work of government bodies,
China’s “mass organizations” such as unions and women federations, and some social
organizations. One scholar commented that as a result of these reforms there was a “shift
in the role of street offices from a low-level administrative body obeying higher
government’s decisions to an entity representing local interest with more
independence.”515
Shenyang model516
Similar to Shanghai, Shenyang also began exploring ways to improve local
governance long before the central government pronounced shequ jianshe as a major
policy. The Shenyang model is especially well known for its far-reaching reforms that
received attention and praise from the officials at the Ministry of Civil Affairs. The first
major effort of Shenyang was the policy of consolidating residents’ committees. The
original residents’ committee was considered to be too small to command adequate
resources for constructing a shequ. The delineation of shequ was thus decided at a level
515
Tingwei Zhang, “Innovation in Chinese Urban Governance: The Shanghai Experience” in Governing
Cities in a Global Era: Urban Innovation, Competition, and Democratic Reform, edited by Robin
Hambleton and Jill Simone Gross, New York: NY: Palgrave Macmillian (2007), pg. 122.
516
Liu Xiaokang, “Zhengfu yu shehui hudong: Shenyang shequ zizhi moshi tanwei (Interaction between
Government and Society: An Inquiry into the Shenyang Community Self-Governance Model)” Guojia
xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of China National School of Administration) 5 (2000), 41-43, 84.
305
that is larger than the original residents’ committee but smaller than the street office.
Residents’ committees were then consolidated into the new shequ residents’ committees.
Shenyang also is also the first city to invent a four-layer authority structure in the shequ:
the decision making layer, the execution layer, the deliberation layer, and the leadership
layer (to be discussed further in Chapter 5). Shenyang also gave the shequs more
substantial autonomy rights in relation to the street office.
Qingdao model
Similar to Shanghai, Qingdao also broadly defines shequ both at the street office
level and at the residents’ committee level; and similar to Shenyang, Qingdao also
consolidated its residents’ committees and designed a four-layer authority structure in its
shequs. The Qingdao model however is notable for two aspects: in perfecting the existing
shequ fuwu (community services) schemes, and in the innovative reforms carried out in
Fushanhou shequ. In the former case, Qingdao established community service centers at
the street office level throughout the city so that residents of all background have access
to some form of services. In the latter case, Fushanhou gained national attention for its
radical organizational restructuring of the governance system. The area covered by
Fushanhou is as large as a street office. But instead of establishing a street office, the city
government experimented by constructing a new shequ-based governance system based
on the idea of a “grand shequ”. Under this new system, there are three work systems
independent of each other but connected through the shequ party work committee: a selfgovernance system consisting of self-governing organizations (a shequ committee and a
shequ representatives assembly at the “grand shequ” level, and several residents’
committees at the small shequ level); an administrative work system that consists of a
306
“shequ affairs handling center” (shequ shiwu shouli zhongxin) that handles administrative
duties such as tax collection, urban management, social welfare administration, and
others; and a community service system that consists of a shequ service center and
several service stations.517 Under this system, residents’ committees will no longer be
tasked to perform administrative and governmental functions, while shequ fuwu is carried
out independently of the residents’ committee by the service stations.
Jianghan model
Jianghan is a district in the city of Wuhan. A notable feature of Jianghan model is
the clear differentiation of responsibilities between the residents’ committee and
governmental bodies such as the street office and the functional departments of the
district government. Each item of work is categorized as either administrative work item
or shequ work item, and under this rule, the residents’ committee will not take up those
work items that are deemed as administrative, such as tax collection. Functional
departments can no longer command the shequs to do works that are supposed to be
completed by themselves. Instead these departments have to send their own field officers
into the shequs to do their job (see the “public evaluation of officials” under “democratic
supervision” in Chapter 5 for more in-depth discussion). Shequs are given the power to
manage their own finance, some decision-making autonomy, and the extraordinary right
to refuse any unreasonable imposition of works and duties from above.
Shenzhen model
517
Shu Shunlin & Liu Tongchang, “Fushanhou xiaoqu: xiaozhengfu, da zizhi (Fushanhou Community:
Small Government, Grand Self-Governance)” Zhongguo minzheng (Chinese Civil Affairs) 4 (2003), pg. 1113.
307
Due to its close proximity with Hong Kong, the Shenzhen model was notable for
its market features. Shenzhen is the first city in China to establish a private property
management company. Marketized property management in residential areas became an
essential component of shequ governance.518 The responsibilities of public security and
environmental cleanliness and maintenance are usually delegated to the property
management companies. The residents’ committee in this shequ will focus more on their
traditional responsibilities such as enforcement of family planning and mediation.
518
Guo Yajie, Zhou jie, “Shequ jianshe: beijing, moshi he fazhan qushi (Community Construction:
Background, Models and Trends)” Xuexi yu tansuo (Study and Exploration) 6 (2004), pg. 43.
308
Appendix 4.1 Translation of the Terms Deng’e xuanju and Cha’e xuanju
These two Chinese terms are notoriously difficult to translate. The literal
translations of these two terms are “equal-number election” (deng’e xuanju) and
“different-number election” (cha’e xuanju) respectively. “Equal-number election”
indicates an election in which the number of candidates equals (corresponds to) the
number of contested positions. “Different-number election” indicates an election in
which the number of candidates exceeds the number of contested positions.
Deng’e xuanju could be alternatively translated as “single-candidate election”,
“uncontested election”, and “noncompetitive election.” But each of these translations
carries a slight different meaning. “Single-candidate election” is misleading. In grassroots
elections, members of the residents’ committee or the villagers’ committee are all elected
at once (for example, electing 5 out of x number of candidates). Thus, there is basically
no “single-candidate” election to speak of. In an election in which the number of
candidates equals the number of contested positions (electing 5 out of 5 candidates), it is
still a “multi-candidate” election, but at the same time also a deng’e xuanju.
“Uncontested” and “noncompetitive” are the adjectives that normally describe the
characteristics of a deng’e xuanju, but they are not the essence of it. A deng’e xuanju can
be competitive if there are strong “write-in candidates” present.
The alternative translations of cha’e xuanju are “multi-candidate election”,
“contested election” and “competitive election.” The problem of “multi-candidate
election” is again that it could be misleading. A residents’ committee election or a
villagers’ committee election is in the literal sense a “multi-candidate” election, even if
the number of candidates equals the number of contested positions. “Contested” and
309
“competitive” are again the adjectives that generally characterize a cha’e xuanju, but not
the essence of it. “Competitive” election also might give the wrong impression that a
cha’e xuanju is by nature competitive, which is not always the case. Through
manipulation, a cha’e xuanju could be as uncompetitive as a deng’e xuanju.519
The official English version of the 2005 White Paper on democracy uses the term
“multi-candidate election” for cha’e xuanju. The China Daily, the major state-run
English newspaper, translates deng’e xuanju and cha’e xuanju into “single-candidate
system” and “differential voting system” respectively. For example, in a recent article
describing the elections of Chinese leaders in the legislature, it stated:
According to the rules of election and appointment adopted at the NPC session,
the elections of the chairman, vice-chairpersons and secretary-general of the 11th
NPC Standing Committee, President and vice-president of China, and chairman of
the CMC [central military commission] follow the single-candidate system. That
is, they are elected from an equal number of candidates.
The election of the NPC Standing Committee members follows the differential
voting system, with a seven percent margin to be eliminated.520
“Single-candidate” and “multi-candidate” elections, however, as stated above,
could be misleading. The literal translations “equal-number election” and “differentnumber election” are cumbersome. Not that I am excited to invent new terms, but
considering the deficiencies of these translated terms, I have decided therefore to use my
own translation “corresponding election” for deng’e xuanju, and follow/modify the China
Daily’s translation “differential voting system”/ “differential election” for cha’e xuanju.
519
Cui Guoqiang, Zhou Jing, “Dui woguo xuanju zhidu yuanze de shikao (Thoughts about the Principles of Election in
China)” Renda yanjiu (People’s Congress Study) 1 (2003), pg. 19.
520
“How These Leaders Come Into Being?” China Daily March 17, 2008.
310
Appendix 4.2: The Tuixuan Process
In a thorough account of the election process of a 1999 shequ residents’
committee election in Shanghai (apparently written by an internal participant), the
tuixuan process of the shequ election committee is described in detail.521 In preparing for
the coming election, the residents’ representatives’ assembly (in place of the usual
residents’ assembly) was convened by the residents’ committee for the purpose of
tuixuan-ing (“electing”) members of the shequ election committee. After announcing
general election rules and regulations as well as the qualifications to become an election
committee member, the presiding chair of the meeting of the assembly (a shequ party
leader) proposed to let the attending residents’ representatives nominate members of the
election committee, which was to consist of 7 to 9 people. None of the residents’
representatives made any suggestion and nomination. So the chair of the assembly
proposed that all nominations would be made by the residents’ committee. The
representatives agreed to this proposal. The residents’ committee then proceeded to
nominate and introduce seven candidates. All candidates were party members. The
representatives then voted for all of them, with show of hands.
This is the detailed process of a tuixuan, which is very informal and can be easily
manipulated. But for people unfamiliar with the difference between xuanju and tuixuan,
they might have the impression that tuixuan is basically same with xuanju, an election.
521
Lin Shangli & Ma Yili, Shequ zuzhi yu juweihui jianshe, Shanghai shequ jianshe yanjiu baogao chongshu zhiqi
(Community Organization and Residents’ Committee Construction, Volume 7 of Shanghai Community Development
Report Series), Shanghai: Shanghai daxue chubanshe (2000), pg. 193-194.
311
Appendix 4.3: Election Abuses through the Shequ Election Committee
An election controversy occurred in a shequ election in Wuhan in 2003 and was
reported in the Shequ magazine.522 In this election, all five members of the residents’
committee of the expiring term intended to run for the upcoming residents’ committee
election. Despite conflict of interest, three of them were also “elected” (tuixuan) as
members of the election committee, which consisted of nine persons. These three
members resigned from the election committee only after their candidacies were
officially announced. The remaining members of the election committee consisted of two
groups of people: recipients of a government subsidy fund for low-income families, and
representatives from a particular danwei (a shipyard factory) in this shequ.
The subsidy fund was managed and dispensed by the residents’ committee. So, all
the recipients basically wanted to cultivate and maintain good relationship with the
residents’ committee. Those serving in the election committee who were recipients of this
fund all had strong incentives to ensure that all five members of residents’ committee of
the current term be re-elected. As for the representatives from that particular danwei, the
factory is not the largest employer in the shequ. There was no particular reason why it
should have large presence in the election committee. It was later revealed that the
factory also had a close relationship with the residents’ committee.
The election committee was responsible for voters’ registration, distribution of
ballot papers, verification of voters’ identity, assisting voters during election, and ballot
counting. It recruited and trained many election workers to handle these tasks. It was
revealed that all election workers were the recipients of the same government subsidy
522
Zhang Mingyu, Liu Zhichang, “Shi shui zhai yingxiang juweihui zhixuan (Who is Influencing Residents’
Committee Election)” Shequ (Community) 5 (2005), pg. 30-31.
312
fund, and thus highly dependent on the current residents’ committee. The election
workers were indeed all acting to ensure the electoral victory of the members of the
current residents’ committee. The street committee was reported to be fully aware of the
biased acts committed by the election workers and the election committee, but since it
also preferred to work with the current residents’ committee, it decided not to intervene.
Superficially, this election fulfilled some standard democratic election criteria
(such as being a differential election and a direct election). But because of the
manipulation of and by the election committee, it undoubtedly was a manipulated, and
undemocratic, election
313
Appendix 4.4 Shequ Activists523
The shequ activists (shequ jijifenzi) are an important resource for the residents’
committee and local officials in shequ administration. They are willing to contribute their
time and efforts to serve the residents voluntarily, and to help the residents’ committee in
areas such as communication, publicity and mobilization. Shequ party members,
residents’ representatives, and block and small group leaders are by nature activists, but
not all the activists have to be in one of these positions, some of them are just ordinary
residents with “good voluntary spirit.” The authorities (residents’ committees and street
offices) generally consider the activists able to communicate and connect with the
residents better than themselves. The activists are thus highly relied upon to convey
information. In the words of a residents’ committee member, the activists are to “teach
and lead the residents in the discussion of important issues.”
During elections the activists become crucially significant in their role as agents
of mobilization. Without the mobilization efforts of the activists, and without them acting
as proxy voters, scribes for the illiterate, and carriers of roving ballot box, many
residents’ committee elections might not be able to secure a high voter-turnout rate and
claim success.
My interviewees told me that the relationship between ordinary residents and the
activists are generally good. Although the “elected” representatives and group leaders
tend to be activists favored and picked by the authorities, this does not necessarily mean
that the residents are distrustful of these activists. The residents know that these activists
523
The following discussion is based on my interviews with the members of two residents’ committees in Yangpu
district of Shanghai in Fall 2007, and Li Hui, “Shehui baochou yu chengshi shequ jiji fenzi (Social Compensation and
Urban Community Activists)” Shehui (Society) 1 (2008), pg. 97-117.
314
have the “ears” of the authorities well. They do not necessarily object to them being
“elected” so that the activists can convey the concerns of ordinary residents to the
authorities. Nevertheless, this should not lead to the conclusion that these residents’
representatives are, in name as well as in reality, genuine representatives preferred by the
residents.
On the other hand, the activists can also be an effective network of surveillance. It
is through the network of activists that the residents’ committee manages to monitor
potentially subversive elements. For example, rehabilitated members of the Falun Gong
spiritual group still receive multiple visits from the activists from time to time (rather
than directly by police officers or officials). Because of the non-official status of these
activists, the ex-members of Falun Gong tend to view them more positively. The
monitoring of their activities becomes easier and less intense.
Shequ activists are not necessarily the elite strata in a shequ. The social elite
(shehui jingying), such as the professionals and businessmen, are generally more
occupied by the things and life outside of the shequ. Most activists are retirees from
danwei. Many of them equipped with extensive organizational skills and have the leisure
time to do voluntary work. Young people are generally not interested to become activists.
According to my interviewees, each shequ generally has (or at least attempts to recruit)
around 15% of the people under its jurisdiction as activists, which translates into about
200-400 activists in a shequ of typical size. Most of them voluntarily take the initiative to
contact the residents’ committee to volunteer time and efforts, but some of the activists
have to be “discovered”. Some residents’ committees attempt to recruit or discover
activists from among the elite strata, such as doctors and teachers (especially those with
315
foreign language qualification), so that they can organize activities such as health and
“learn English” seminars for the residents. An interviewee pointed out to me that having
a group of activists with diverse background could help spread the message and influence
of the residents’ committee to every corner of the shequ.
316
Appendix 7.1: Reported Cases of Violations of Homeowners’ Rights in the Peoples’
Daily524
Report 1
The property company of Meirandongli neighborhood is established and owned
by the developer. The services it provided were below standard yet it was charging
unreasonable high service fees. In 2005, the homeowners successfully established a
homeowners’ committee. The committee decided not to renew the service contract with
the property management company. It hired another company through an open bidding
process. The old property management company however refused to leave the
neighborhood. It claimed that there were still unpaid fees waiting to be collected. The
homeowners’ committee proceeded to sue the company and won. The old property
management company then suddenly terminated its services in the neighborhood. It
turned off supplies of water and heat (during Beijing’s freezing winter) and withdrew
security guards and cleaning crew. The home of the director of the homeowners’
committee was then mysteriously vandalized and damaged. Fearing his own personal
safety, the director resigned from the committee.
A court order eventually forced the old company out. The new property company
was finally able to begin its service. However, more troubles were coming. The new
company was soon forced to terminate its services and withdraw from the neighborhood,
citing various technical issues that were very likely to be caused by deliberate
obstructions of the previous company (such as missing technical blueprints). A member
524
These stories were published from June 26 to June 30, 2006 in the People’s Daily and reproduced in the magazine
Real Estate Information of China. The sources I draw on here are from the magazine. See “Yezhu weiquan you duonan
(How Difficult to Defend Homeowners’ Rights” and “Anju leye you duonan (How Difficult to Live Peacefully)”
Zhongguo fangdi xinxi (Real Estate Information of China) 8 (2006), pg. 66-69; “Dangge yezhu you duonan (How
Difficult to be a Homeowner)”, “Huange wuye you duonan (How Difficult to Change a Property Management
Company)” Zhongguo fangdi xinxi (Real Estate Information of China) 9 (2006), pg. 68-71.
317
of the homeowners’ committee also alleged that the reason this new company was
withdrawing was that it was threatened by the old company. The contact person between
the homeowners and the new company was physically assaulted by unknown assailants.
This also put pressure on the employees of the new company.
The homeowners’ committee then organized another bidding process. Since the
ownership rights of the heating facilities and underground parking lots still belonged to
the developer, the committee requested that the bidders have to first secure the usage
rights from the developer. At the end, there was only one company that successfully
secured the usage rights from the developer. Nevertheless, one-thirds of the employees of
this company were former employees of the much hated old company. Some
homeowners alleged that this company is the old company, with a different name.
Report 2
The homeowners of Beijing’s Daxiyangcheng neighborhood were promised a
primary school and an activity center. The school was never built and the activity center
was rented out by the developer to a restaurant and a gym company, as well as to the
street office. In addition, some homeowners who renovated their units discovered that the
homeowners were using substandard materials. The developer continued to reap profits
by renting out the areas and facilities it claims to have ownership, while it also forces the
homeowners to share the ownership right of those facilities that are not profitable. The
developer also promised the homeowners that there would be a foreign invested property
management company providing hotel-quality services, therefore homeowners would be
paying for higher management fees. Instead the developer created its own property
management company, but continued to charge the same rate.
318
In the neighborhood of Tianxin jiayuan, the services of the property management
company were truly substandard. The running water it supplied contained debris and
smell. Every afternoon the company stopped providing water and electricity. Several
lanes within the neighborhood had no lights. The company never opened its book for
inspection; its security guards were seen to assault homeowners. Despite all these lousy
services, the company continued to charge high service fees. Later, the homeowners
discovered that the company actually failed to secure proper “service certification” from
the municipal government, meaning that the company was operating without appropriate
license. The homeowners also pointed out that when they signed the purchase agreement
with the developer, the developer did not show them the temporary property service
contract, but only when they went to collect keys that the developer showed them the
contract (with many unequal articles) and forced them to sign; those who refused to sign
the contract would not get the keys. Some homeowners were so upset about the poor
services they received that they refused to pay the management fees. The property
management company then sued them and won.
Report 3
In Tianxin jiayuan neighborhood, a garden that was promised by the developer
had been turned into paid parking lots by the property management company. Free street
parking also became metered parking. The elevators were full of commercial
advertisements. In short, the property management companies managed to earn millions
of dollars from common property areas and shared facilities, but never shared these
profits with the homeowners, the supposed owners and users of these common areas and
public facilities. This was the reason why withholding payment of service fees by
319
homeowners was unable to deter the company. The company was still able to make huge
profits.
Report 4
Homeowners in many neighborhoods were unable to change the unequal terms in
the temporary property service contract forced upon them. As long as a new
homeowners’ committee had not been established and a homeowner’ assembly had not
been convened, the temporary contract automatically renews every time it expires. Even
without a contract, a Beijing court had interpreted that as long as a property management
company was providing services, the homeowners were obliged to pay for its services.
Some homeowners had been fighting battle after battle to changes their property
management company for years without any achievement. Some property management
companies were also alleged to use physical assaults to deter homeowners from engaging
in “rights-defense” activities.
A prominent real estate lawyer made a calculation of the costs of homeowners’
“rights-defense”. Assuming that everything went smoothly, typically it would take up to
35 months and 700,000 yuan for a neighborhood of the size of a 1000 units to establish a
homeowners’ committee and to force out its property management company through
lawsuits.
320
Appendix 7.2: The Shequ Residents’ Committee and Property Management
The role of the shequ residents’ committee in property management is admittedly
awkward. Residents’ committees generally (but not always) refrain from advocating
homeowners’ concerns and issues, since they are seen as frictions resulting from two
parties in a private transaction (homeowners as consumers and property management
company and developer as providers) which the residents’ committee has no formal
responsibility to deal with.
Conceptually, there is no official relationship between the residents’ committee
and the two bodies related to property management –the homeowners’ committee and the
property management company. To reiterate briefly, the shequ residents’ committee is a
mass “self-governance organization” that serves and represents all residents, whether
they are homeowners or not. The homeowners’ committee is established on the basis of
private property rights; it does not answer to the residents’ committee, nor is its status
institutionally subordinate to any other governmental body. Its main purpose is to serve
and represent the homeowners.525 On the other hand, the property management company
is a commercial unit supposedly hired by the homeowners’ committee to perform
property management functions.
However, in effect, considerable overlapping of functions and responsibilities
occur in the governance of xiaoqu and shequ. The shequ jianshe policy calls for increased
residents’ committee’s involvement in promoting community health, environment,
culture, safety, etc., which overlap to a some degree with what a property management
company does. It is not uncommon for the residents’ committee and the property
525
“Yezhuhui yu juweihui shui caineng daibiao jumin qunzhong (Homeowners’ Committee or Residents’ Committee,
Who can Represent the Masses)” Shequ (Community) 2 (2001), pg. 22.
321
management company each fielding a team of safety patrols around neighborhood, or
performing similar tasks in street and building cleaning, as well as collecting the same
sort of fees from the residents for the similar tasks. The residents/homeowners in this
sense are being “taxed” twice for the same service because neither the property
management company nor the residents’ committee is willing to let go of some moneygenerating activities.
The relationship between the property management company and the residents’
committee is not without friction.526 In a sense, both bodies claim to be the “boss” in a
neighborhood. However, in some of the newly developed neighborhoods, the residents’
committee is marginalized (or not yet established) and could even be practically
subordinate to the property management company.527 The office space of the residents’
committee in these neighborhoods are generally provided by the developer and managed
by the property management company, and it is no surprise that the committee feels
beholden to the company and tend to side with them against homeowners in disputes.
Another issue is the relationship between the residents’ committee and the
homeowners’ committee. How both organizations coordinate their work and cooperate
with each other is crucial for the governance of both shequ and xiaoqu. Nevertheless,
disputes between them also often occur. The principal complains of the homeowners’
committee is that the residents’ committee is meddling in its internal affairs. Since both
526
A study of the property management situation in Urumqi, the provincial capital of Xinjiang Autonomous Region,
points out that conflicts between residents’ committees and property management companies are quite common. See
Zhu Yanfei, “Urumqishi wuye fuwu qiye, juweihui, yeweihui guanxi chutan (A Preliminary Inquiry into the
Relationship between Property Service Enterprises, Residents’ Committees, and Homeowners’ Committees in
Urumqi)” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese Property Management) 9 (2008), pg. 24-25.
527
Yongshun Cai, “China’s Moderate Middle Class: The Case of Homeowners’ Resistance” Asian Survey 45:5 (2005),
pg. 785.
322
organizations are designated as “self-governance” organizations, it is a misconception to
think of the homeowners’ committee and the residents’ committee as something of an
administrative subordinate-superior relationship.528 On the other hand, there is also the
argument that the residents’ committee should replace the homeowners’ committee. Not
only that having two grassroots organizations is redundant, it is also the source of
conflicts and disputes, as they both compete for the allegiance and support of residents
and for the same pool of resources. This redundancy could also sometimes lead to
evasion of and confusion over responsibilities.529
There is no definite official position on this matter, although the preference of
many local governments seems to be the integration of the homeowners’ committee into
the shequ jianshe policy, which in practice would make the homeowners’ committee a
subordinate organization to the residents’ committee. Theoretically speaking, the
government should maintain a neutral attitude toward both organizations. Nonetheless, it
surprises no one that the government prefers the homeowners’ committee being
subsumed under the residents’ committee. Many policy documents either suggest or
require that the residents’ committee should play an active role in the formation,
organization, and activities of homeowners’ committees. In Beijing, the establishment of
preparation committee of the homeowners’ committee in practice has to be pre-approved
by the residents’ committee.530 Also, according to Article 20 of the Regulations of
528
Meng Xiansheng, “Yeweihui buneng zhiyu diedaoban he juweihui de lingdao xia (Homeowners’ Committee Cannot
be Under the Leadership of Street Office and Residents’ Committee)” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 7
(2007), pg. 61.
529
Liao Zhongping, “Shequ juweihui ying qudai yezhu weiyuanhui (Community Residents’ Committee Should
Replace Homeowners’ Committee)” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 3 (2003), pg. 9.
530
Cui Xiaoyi, “Shequ jumin weiyuanhui yu yezhu weiyuanhui de quanli jiegou jiwi zai Beijingshi zhengce
zhixingzhong de yanhua (The Power Structure of Residents’ Committee and Homeowners’ Committee and its
Evolution in the Policy Execution in Beijing)” Beijing xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal Beijing Administrative
College) 6 (2008), pg. 1-7.
323
Property Management, the homeowners’ committee should (1) support the public
security bureau and cooperate with the residents’ committee in the area of public security
work; (2) actively coordinate with the residents’ committee in self-governance matters;
(3) be under the supervision and guidance of the residents’ committee; (4) inform the
residents’ committee regarding the decisions made by the homeowners’ assembly and the
homeowners’ committee, as well as consider the suggestions made by the residents’
committee on these decisions.
Homeowners in general do not welcome this role played by the residents’
committee. They fear that the residents’ committee will interpret “supervision and
guidance” as “regulation and interference”, or side with the adversaries of the
homeowners’ committee (especially in cases in which the office space occupied by the
residents’ committee is provided, for free, by the developer).
The major argument for residents’ committee’s “supervision and guidance” of the
homeowners’ committee is that no matter how many residents are homeowners, there are
still residents who are not homeowners. The life of these residents is affected by the
decisions made by the homeowners’ committee. The homeowners’ committee tends to
articulate the interests and concerns of the affluent middle class, and sometimes in the
process it also ignores the rights and interests of the lower class residents, especially the
migrant workers. In this case the residents’ committee could protect the rights and
interests of the poorer residents or migrant groups.
In addition, if a decision made by the homeowners’ committee is backed by the
residents’ committee, it is likely to carry much more weight than the one without. In
2004, a homeowners’ committee in Beijing fired its property management company and
324
hired a new one, with the residents’ committee fully aware and supportive of the
decision. As a result, the transfer of the property management company was handled
smoothly and amicably. This is a rare instance in the generally tense situation of property
management companies being fired.531
There is also a proposal to merge the two organizations. The advocates of this
proposal argue that in many of the new neighborhoods (xiaoqu), predominantly the
residents are homeowners. Even in older neighborhoods, the trend is that more and more
residents are becoming homeowners. Since both organizations are intended to serve the
residents/homeowners, both are designated as “self-organizations” by laws (one for
residents, one for homeowners), and both perform some overlapping functions, a merger
of these two organizations would not only reduce redundancy and unnecessary disputes,
it will also make governance of the neighborhood much more effective. The proposed
model is to scrap both homeowners’ committee and residents’ committee, and to create a
new association at the shequ level which would perform the tasks of both homeowners’
committee (hiring property management companies, dealing with issues regarding
property management) and residents’ committee (assisting governmental work, settling
neighborhood disputes, public safety, etc.). Its members are to be elected and answerable
to a shequ representatives’ assembly. Even if there is a minority of residents who are not
homeowners, their voting rights shall be guaranteed as well. Party organization should
also be established within this proposed association to perform “leadership” role.532
531
Miao Zhenghua, “Juweihui ruhe dui yeweihui ‘jiandu yu zhidao’ (How Residents’ Committee ‘Supervise and
Guide’ Homeowners’ Committee)?” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 1 (2006), pg. 32-34.
532
Lei Cuihong, “Yeweihui he juweihui nengfou he’erwweiyi (Can Homeowners’ Committee and Residents’
Committee Merge into One?)” Shequ (Community) 2 (2006), pg. 34-35; Chai Xiaohua, “Dang jumin chengwei yezhu –
lun chengshi shequ juweihui yu yeweihui de zhenghe (When Residents Become Homeowners –On the Integration
325
It remains to be seen how the relationship between the residents’ committee, the
homeowners’ committee and the property management company evolve. Some
interesting institutional innovations in grassroots governance might eventually emerge.
between Residents’ Committee and Homeowners’ Committee)” Ningbo daxue xuebao (Journal of Ningbo University)
18:5 (2005), pg. 105-110.
326
Appendix 7.3 Bei’an of the Homeowners’ Committee533
Once a homeowners’ committee is established, in order to gain official
recognition it has to file a record (bei’an) with the local housing and property
authority.534 Filing a record is technically different from “registration” (dengji, as is the
case of registering a social organization by the civil affairs department or establishing a
company in accordance with the Company Law); it is an act of having certain actions and
transactions being officially recognized and recorded. The legal nature of bei’an is ex
post facto and declarative. Nevertheless, without bei’an the legitimacy of a homeowners’
committee is much more limited. Bei’an thus could be said to be a halfway point between
official registration and non-registration.
A homeowners’ committee that is without bei’an will not be able to obtain an
official stamp (gongzhang) from the authorities. Without the stamp, the documents or
contracts signed by the homeowners’ committee do not have legal force. Bei’an is also
required for the homeowners’ committee to be recognized as the authorized organization
in dealing with external entities (for example, in negotiations with property management
companies).
In applying for bei’an, homeowners have to present several documents to the
local housing and property authorities. These documents include the homeowners’
covenant, resolutions passed by the homeowners’ assembly, homeowners’ list,
533
The following discussion on bei’an is based on Wang Zhanqiang, “Yeweihui bei’an zhidu de sheli bushi baishe (The
System of Homeowners’ Committee’s Record Filing is not Insignificant)” Xiandai wuye-xinyezhu (Modern Property
Management –New Proprietor) 12 (2008), pg. 42-45; Chen Wenqu & Zheng Ning, “Yezhu weiyuanhui chengli bei’an
zhidu yanjiu (A Study of the System of Homeowners’ Committee’s Record Filing)” Zhengzhi yu falu (Politics and
Laws) 2 (2009), pg. 154-161.
534
The exact body that deals with the homeowners’ committee differs from city to city. In Beijing there is a
“new neighborhood office” set up to deal with issues related to property management and homeowners’
committee in Beijing’s xiaoqu. In other cities, district-level housing bureaus or land resources bureaus are
more common. Collectively they are referred to in China as local housing and property authorities (difang
fangdichan xingzhen bumen).
327
development blueprint of the neighborhood, any other documents deemed necessary.
Since only the developer has a complete homeowners’ list and the development blueprint,
refusing to handover these documents to homeowners is a common tactic by developers
to frustrate homeowners’ rights-defense movement.
The local housing and property authority has to check the validity of these
documents before it agrees to the bei’an of the applicants. Disputes between homeowners
and the authority usually arise at this stage, when the authority considers the documents
inadequate or flawed. Sometimes the local housing and property authority neither
approves nor rejects the application of bei’an, letting the application lingering for
years.535
535
Chen Xiangming, “Lun woguo yezhu weiyuanhui zhidu de quexian jiqi wanshan (On the Inadequacies and Ways of
Improving the System of Homeowners’ Committee)” Qiye jingji (Enterprise Economy) 7 (2008), pg. 191.
328
Appendix 7.4: “Preparation Committee for the Society of Homeowners’ Committee” in
Guangzhou536
One of the most successful, but officially unregistered, associations of
homeowners’ committees is the “Preparation Committee for the Society of Homeowners’
Committees” (hereafter the “Society”) in the city of Guangzhou. It was organized in 2005
and aims to bring all homeowners’ committees in Guangzhou under one umbrella
organization. The official reaction was initially unfriendly. Developers and property
management companies in the city also exploited their ties with local governments to
prevent it from gaining an official status.
The “Society” however also responded with some tactically astute moves. It
enlisted the support of some party and government officials, cultivated friendship with
the officials in charge of housing affairs, campaigned for those people’s congress
deputies who had helped them in the past in people’s congress elections, pushed for
legislative agenda, and enlisted the support of the media. More interestingly, the
“Society” offered to help local governments in the implementation of some unpopular
policies. As one activist explained, “Many xiaoqus have become the fortress for some
homeowners to avoid the one-child policy. The residents’ committee is too weak to
penetrate inside it.” The “Society” offered to mobilize its network and influence to
enforce this policy. Through years of cultivating positive relationships with the local
government, the “Society” has indeed accumulated significant political and
organizational resources and achieved semi-official recognition.537 This example clearly
536
Zhang Jingen, Zhuang Wenjia, “Feizhengshi zhengzhi: yige caogen NGO de xingdong celue (Informal Politics: The
Action Strategies of a Grassroots NGO)” Shehuixue yanjiu (Sociological Studies) 2 (2008), pg. 133-150.
537
The experience of this “Society” in Guangzhou is interestingly different from the observation made by Benjamin
Read that unofficial homeowners’ groups tend to employ “more contentious tactics” toward their adversaries (including
local officials) in the hope that these adversaries will compromise with them. See Benjamin Read, “Property Rights and
329
illustrates one aspect of the nature of “civil society with Chinese characteristics” –that
organizations with hostile relationship with the state cannot survive. A civil society
organization (in this case the homeowners’ organizations) can originate from private
citizens’ actions, but its success, growth, and power to a large extent depends on it having
a healthy, cooperative relationship with the state.
Homeowner Activism in New Neighborhoods” in Privatizing China: Socialism from Afar, edited by Li Zhang and
Aihwa Ong, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press (2008), pg. 54.
330
Works Cited
In addition to the articles and books listed below, this dissertation also uses press reports
and commentaries from the following newspapers in China and the United States.
21 Shiji jingji baodao (21st Century Economic Reports)
Chengdu ribao (Chengdu Daily)
China Daily
Dalian ribao (Dalian Daily)
Henan ribao (Henan Daily)
Huaxia shibao (Huaxia Times)
Huangshi ribao (Huangshi Daily)
Hunan ribao (Hunan Daily)
Jiefang ribao (Liberation Daily)
Jinhua shibao (Jinhua Times)
Lanzhou ribao (Lanzhou Daily)
Nanjing ribao (Nanjing Daily)
Ningbo ribao (Ningbo Daily)
Renmin daibiaobao (People’s Represenstatives Daily)
Renmin fayuanbao (People’s Court Daily)
Renmin fayuanbao –fazhoukan (People’s Court Daily –Legal Weekly)
Renmin ribao (People’s Daily)
Qingdao ribao (Qingdao Daily)
Shantou ribao (Shantou Daily)
Shenzhen tequbao (Shenzhen Special Zone Daily)
Sichuan ribao (Sichuan Daily)
Taizhou ribao (Taizhou Daily)
Tianjin ribao (Tianjin Daily)
Washington Post
Wuxi ribao (Wuxi daily)
Xuexi shibao (Learning Times)
Xi’an ribao (Xi’an Daily)
Xinhua meiri dianxun (Xinhua Daily Wires)
Xinjinbao (Xinjin Daily)
Zhongguo funubao (China Women Daily)
Zhongguo gaigebao (China Reform Daily)
Zhongguo jingji shibao (China Economic Times)
Zhongguo shehuibao (China Society Daily)
Zhongguo xinxibao (China Information Daily)
Zhonghua gongshang shibao (China Industrial and Commercial Times)
Zhongwai fangdichan daobao (Chinese and Foreign Real Estate Times)
Zuzhi renshibao (Organizational and Personnel Daily)
2006 Zhongguo shehui tongji nianjian (2006 China Social Statistical Yearbook). Beijing:
Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 2006.
331
Akio, Takahara, and Robert Benewick. “Party Work in Urban Communities.” The
Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by edited by Kjeld Erik Brødsgaard
and Zheng Yongnian. New York, NY: Routledge, 2006.
Angle, Stephen. “Decent Democratic Centralism,” Political Theory 33:4 (2005): 518546.
Bai, Yihua, “Chengshi, juweihui, lingdao (Cities, Residents’ Committees, Leadership).”
Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems) 6 (1990): 60-64.
Bai, Yang. “Xuanju de yishua gongneng (The Ritualization Function of Elections).”
Shehui kexue (Journal of Social Sciences) 5 (2003): 71-75.
Ban, Baosheng. “Chengxu minzhu de hanyi, tezheng yu gongneng (The Meaning,
Features and Functions of Procedural Democracy).” Heilongjiang shehui kexue
(Heilongjiang Social Sciences) 6 (2006): 143-147.
Baum, Richard. “Political Implications of China’s Information Revolution: The Media,
the Minders, and Their Message.” In China’s Changing Political Landscape:
Prospects for Democracy, edited by Cheng Li. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 2008.
Beijing chenshi shequ dangjian ketizu. “Beijingshi chengshi shequ dangjian zhuangkuang
diaocha (A Survey of Party Building in Beijing’s Urban Communities).”
Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems) 4 (2003): 66-68.
“Beijingshi Xisibeitoutiao shequ jumin weiyuanhui zhangcheng (Residents’ Committee
Charter in Xisibeitoutiao Community, Beijing).” Shequ (Community) 3 (2003):
33-34.
“Beijingshi zhuzhaiqu yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize [shixing] (The
Rules of Conduct for the Homeowners’ Assembly and the Homeowners’
Committee in Beijing [Trial Version]).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern
Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009): 88-90.
Bell, Daniel A. “Residential Community Association: Community of Disunity?” In The
Essential Communitarian Reader, edited by Amitai Etzioni. Lanham, MD:
Rowman & Littlefield, 1998.
Benewick, Robert, Irene Tong, and Jude Howell. “Self-Governance and Community: A
Preliminary Comparison between Villagers’ Committees and Urban Community
Councils.” China Information 18:1 (2004): 11-28.
332
Bernstein, Thomas P. Up to the Mountains and Down to the Villages: The Transfer of
Youth from Urban to Rural China. New Have, CT: Yale University Press, 1977.
Blecher, Marc J., and Gordon White. Micropolitics in Contemporary China: A Technical
Unit During and After the Cultural Revolution. White Plains, NY: M.E. Sharpe,
1979.
Bo, Zhiyue. “Zhongguo de minzhu moshi (Democratic Models of China).” Paper
presented at the International Conference on “Chinese-Style” Democracy, Wuhan
University, China, November 13-15, 2009.
Bray, David. “Building ‘Community’: New Strategies of Governance in Urban China.”
Economy and Society 35:4 (2006): 530-549.
Bryan, Frank M. Real Democracy: The New England Town Meeting and How It Works.
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2004.
Cai, Dingjian, ed. Zhongguo xuanju zhuangkuang baogao (A Report on the Present
Situation of Elections in China). Beijing: Falu chubanshe, 2002.
Cai, Yi. “Yezhu weiyuanhui yunzuo shiwu (A Practical Guide to the Operation of the
Homeowners’ Committee).” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 2
(2003): 5-8.
Cai, Yongshun. “China’s Moderate Middle Class: The Case of Homeowners’
Resistance.” Asian Survey 45:5 (2005): 777-799.
Chai, Xiaohua. “Dang jumin chengwei yezhu –lun chengshi shequ juweihui yu yeweihui
de zhenghe (When Residents Become Homeowners –On Integrating the
Residents’ Committee and the Homeowners’ Committee).” Ningbo daxue xuebao
(Journal of Ningbo University) 18:5 (2005): 105-110.
Chen, Chen, and Ted King. Come Watch the Sun to Go Home. New York, NY: Marlowe
& Company, 1998.
Chen, Jiaxi. “Cong tulu dao ‘shanbu’: yezhu lixing weiquan de xinquxiang (From RoadBlocking to ‘Walking’: The New Trend in Homeowners’ Rational Rights-Defense
Movement).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor) 5 (2008): 31-33.
Chen, Jiaxi, and Liu Jun. “Jiedao banshichu: Lishi bianqian yu gaige quxiang (The Street
Office: Historical Changes and Trends of Reform).” Chengshi wenti (Urban
Problems) 6 (2002): 52-55.
333
Chen, Hui. “Woguo chengshi jumin weiyuanhui de huigu yu sikao (A Review of and
Reflection on the Residents’ Committee).” Zhonggong dangshi yanjiu (Journal of
Chinese Communist Party History) 6 (1999): 26-31.
----, and Xie Shicheng. “Jianguo chuqi jumin weiyuanhui yanjiu (A Study of the Urban
Residents’ Committee in the Early History of the PRC).” Dangdai zhongguoshi
yanjiu (Contemporary China History Studies) 9:4 (2002): 43-48,126.
Chen, Long, Zhou Caixia, and Zhu Xiancheng. “Nanjing yezhu weiyuanhui zizhi zhidu
diaocha yanjiu (An Investigative Study of the Homeowners’ Self-Governance
System in Nanjing).” Zhongguo fangdichan (China Real Estate) 4 (2004): 70-73.
Chen, Ming. “Yezhu ying zhongshi sange ‘daibiaoxing’ wenjian (Homeowners Should
Pay Attention to the ‘Three Authoritative’ Documents).” Xiandai wuye (Modern
Property Management) 8 (2006): 49-51.
Chen, Mingxian. “Zhizheng nengli: wending fazhan yu minzhu zhizheng de liangnan
(Governing Capacity: The Dilemma of Stable Development and Democratic
Governing).” In Hu Wen tizhi de pingheng zhanlue: siwei yu zhengce (The
Balancing Strategy of Hu-Wen Administration: Modes of Thinking and Policies),
edited Chu Shin-min. Taipei: Yuanjin jijinhui, 2005.
Chen, Weidong. “Minpingguan rang jumin chengwei gongmin (Public Evaluation of
Officials Let Residents Become Citizens).” Shequ (Community) 4 (2004): 11-12.
Chen, Weidong, and Wu Meng. “Shequ zizuzhi yu zhixuan chengben (Community SelfOrganization and the Costs of Direct Election).” Dangdai shijie shehui zhuyi
wenti (Issues in Contemporary World Socialism) 2 (2005): 11-18.
Chen, Wenqu, and Zheng Ning. “Yezhu weiyuanhui chengli bei’an zhidu yanjiu (A
Study of the System of Homeowners’ Committee’s Record Filing).” Zhengzhi yu
falu (Politics and Laws) 2 (2009): 154-161.
Chen, Yu. “Chengshi shequ juweihui xuanju jumin canyu shixiao de diaocha he sikao (A
Study and Some Thoughts on the Effects of Residents’ Participation in Residents’
Committee Elections).” Guangdong xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of
Guangdong Institute of Public Administration) 18:4 (2006): 36-39.
Chen, Zhiwei, and Dai Zhiwei. Shequ jianshe lilun yu shijian tansuo (An Inquiry into
Community Theory and Practice). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe, 2005.
Cheng, Gang. “The Neighborhood Committee –Residents’ Own Organization.” Beijing
Review 33:15 (1990): 30-32.
Cheng, Nie. Life and Death in Shanghai. New York, NY: Grove Press, 1986.
334
“China’s 2005 White Paper: ‘Building of Political Democracy in China.’” Asian Affairs:
An American Review 33:1 (2006): 3-36.
Chu, Jianyi. “Goujian shequ dangzuzhi lingdao hexin de baozhang jizhi (Constructing the
Mechanisms to Ensure the Core Leadership Role of Community Party
Organizations).” Lilun tantao (Theoretical Investigation) 5 (2005): 151-153.
Cohen, Jerome. The Criminal Process in the People’s Republic of China, 1949-1963: An
Introduction. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1968.
Cui, Guoqiang, and Zhou Jing. “Dui woguo xuanju zhidu yuanze de sikao (Thoughts on
the Election Principles in China).” Renda yanjiu (People’s Congress Study) 1
(2003): 17-20.
Cui Xiaoyi. “Shequ jumin weiyuanhui yu yezhu weiyuanhui de quanli jiegou jiwi zai
Beijingshi zhengce zhixingzhong de yanhua (The Power Structure between the
Residents’ Committee and the Homeowners’ Committee and its Evolution in
Policy Execution in Beijing).” Beijing xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal
Beijing Administrative College) 6 (2008): 1-7.
Cui, Yehu. “Chengshi shequ yezhu weiyuanhui falu diwei yanjiu (A Study of the Legal
Status of the Homeowners’ Committee in Urban Communities).” Hubei shehui
kexue (Social Sciences in Hubei) 8 (2008): 145-148.
Dahl, Robert. Polyarchy: Opposition and Participation. New Have, CT: Yale University
Press.
Dalton, Russell, Susan E. Scarrow, and Bruce E. Cain. “Advanced Democracies and the
New Politics.” In Annual Editions: Comparative Politics 09/10, edited by O.
Fiona Yap. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 2010.
Davis, Deborah S. “Urban Chinese Homeowners as Citizens-Consumers.” In The
Ambivalent Consumer: Questioning Consumption in East Asia and the West,
edited by Sheldon Garon and Patricia L. Maclachlan. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press, 2006.
Deng, Enyuan, and Zhao Xuechang, eds. Shequ jianshe zhengce yu fagui (Policies and
Laws of Community Construction). Beijing: Zhongguo qinggongye chubanshe,
2003.
Deng, Mingfen. “Lun shequ zizhin jinchengzhong chengshi jiceng zuzhi jianshe xinsilu
(New Ideas of Urban Grassroots Organizational Construction in the Process of
Community Self-Governance).” Xuexi luntan (Tribune of Study) 1 (2007): 42-45.
335
Deng, Quanguo. Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi (Community Residents’ SelfGovernance in Urban China). Shenyang: Liaoning renmin chubanshe, 2004.
Deng, Quanguo, and Meng Yinghui. “Nongcun cunmin minzhu juece yu chengshi jumin
minzhu juece bijiao (Comparing Democratic Decision Making in Rural Villages
and in Urban Areas).” Guizhou shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Guizhou Normal
University) 5 (2007): 1-5.
Derleth, James, and Daniel R. Koldyk. “The Shequ Experiment: Grassroots Political
Reform in Urban China.” Journal of Contemporary China 13:41(2004): 747-777.
Dewey, John. The Public and its Problems. Denver, CO: Alan Swallow, 1954.
Diamond, Larry. Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation. Baltimore, MD: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1999.
----, and Ramon H. Myers, eds. Elections and Democracy in Greater China. New York,
NY: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Dickson, Bruce J. “The Future of the Chinese Communist Party: Strategies of Survival
and the Prospects for Change.” In Charting China’s Future: Political, Social and
International Dimensions, edited by Jae Ho Chun. Lanham, MD: Rowman &
Littlefield, 2006.
Dilgor, Robert Jay. Neighborhood Politics: Residential Community Associations in
American Governance. New York, NY: New York University Press, 1992.
Ding, Chao. “Chengshi shequ yanjiu zhiyi: Chuantong chengshi shequ xiang xiandai
shizheng zuzhi de zhuanxing (A Study of Urban Community [Part 1]: The
Transition from Traditional Urban Communities to Modern Municipal
Administrative Organizations).” Zhongguo fangyu (Chinese Territories) 3 (2001):
6-9.
----. “Chengshi shequ yanjiu zhi’er: Quanneng zhuyi jiangou zhong de shequ yu danwei
(A Study of Urban Community [Part 2]: Communities and Work Units in the
Totalistic Framework).” Zhongguo fangyu (Chinese Territories) 4 (2001): 3-6.
Ding, Lei, and Zhonghua. “Shanghaishi Luwanqu ‘jumin gongyue’ xuandeng (Selected
Compilations of ‘Residents’ Agreements’ in Luwan District, Shanghai).” Shequ
(Community) 4 (2003): 38.
Ding, Min. “Mingque yeweihui shusong zhuti zige shi yingshi zhixu (Ascertaining the
Litigation Rights of the Homeowners’ Committee is Necessary).” Xiandai wuye –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 12 (2008): 30-31.
336
Domes, Jürgen. “The Emergence of the People’s Republic of China.” In China: Seventy
Years after the 1911 Hsin-Hai Revolution, edited by Hongdah Chiu & ShaoChuan Leng. Charlottesville, VA: University of Virginia Press, 1984.
Engels, Friedrich. The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State, New York,
NY: Penguin Books, 1985.
Etzioni, Amitai. The New Golden Rule: Community and Morality in a Democratic
Society. New York, NY: Basic Books, 1996.
Fairbank, John King. The United States and China, 4th ed. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1979.
Fei, Meiping. “Yezhu weiyuanhui yu Zhongguo de shimin shehui (Homeowners’
Committees and Civil Society in China).” Huadong ligong daxue xuebao (Journal
of East China University of Science and Technology) 2 (2002): 57-64.
Frazer, Elizabeth. “Communitarianism.” In New Political Thought: An Introduction,
edited by Adam Lent. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1998.
Frolic, B. Michael. Mao’s People: Sixteen Portraits of Life in Revolutionary China.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1980.
----. “State-led Civil Society” In Civil Society in China, edited by Timothy Brook and B.
Michael Frolic. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997.
Gao, Hanrong. “Shequ dangjian yu woguo jiceng shehui zizhi zuzhi de chonggou
(Community Party Building and the Reconstruction of Grassroots SelfGovernance Organizations).” Gansu shehui kexue (Gansu Social Sciences) 3
(2003): 42-44.
Giddens, Anthony. The Third Way: The Renewal of Social Democracy. Cambridge, UK:
Polity Press, 1998.
Gilboy, George J., and Benjamin Read. “Political and Social Reform in China: Alive and
Walking.” Washington Quarterly 31:3 (2008): 143-164.
Gold, Thomas. “Party-State versus Society in China.” In Building a Nation-State: China
after Forty Years, edited by Joyce K. Kallgren. Berkeley, CA: Institute of East
Asian Studies, University of California-Berkeley, 1990.
Gu, Jianjian. “Zhuanxingqi shequ dangjian gongzuo de zhelidian: juminqu dangzhibu
jianshe (The Main Aspects of Urban Community Party Building Work in the
Transition Era: Building of Party Branches in Residential Areas).” Shanghai
337
dangshi yu dangjian (Party Histroy and Party Building in Shanghai) 6 (2001):
53-56.
Guan, Xinping & Julian Chow. “The Development of Urban Community Welfare
Services in China.” Social Development Issues 25:3 (2003/2004): 51-61.
Gui, Yong. “Lingli zhengzhi (Neighborhood Politics).” Shehui (Society) 6 (2007): 102126.
----, et al. “Zhixuan: shi shehui ziben kaifa haishi xingzheng tuixiao minzhu (Direct
Elections: Utilization of Social Capital or Official Promotion of Democracy)?”
Shanghai chengshi guanli zhiye jishu xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Shanghai
Polytechnic College Urban Management) 6 (2003): 22-25.
----, Joseph Y.S. Cheng, and Weihong Ma. “Cultivation of Grassroots Democracy: A
Study of Direct Elections of Residents’ Committees in Shanghai.” China
Information 20:1 (2006): 7-31.
Gui Yong, and Cui Zhiyu. “XIngzhengchu jinchengzhong de chengshi juweihui tizhi
bianqian (The Changes of the Urban Residents’ Committee System in the Process
of Governmentalization).” Huazhong shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Huazhong
University of Science and Technology) 14:3 (2000): 1-5.
Guo, Hua. “Shenzhen: Shequ xuanmin tuidong jingxuan fengyun (Shenzhen: Community
Voters Pushing for the Eventful Competitive Elections).” Shequ (Community)17
(2003): 6-11.
Guo, Jiangang, and Xi Xiaoqin. “Quanneng zhuyi zai Zhongguo de xingqi, gaochao jiqi
weilai (The Rise, Climax, and Future of Totalistic Politics in China).” Zhejiang
xuekan (Zhejiang Academic Journal) 5 (2003): 157-159.
Guo, Shengli. Jumin weiyuanhui de chuangjian yu biange: Shanghaishi ge’an yanjiu
(The Establishment and Changes of the Residents’ Committee: A Case Study in
Shanghai). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe, 2006.
Guo, Shengli, and Gao Minzheng. “1958-1966: Jumin weiyuanhui gongneng de bianyi yu
huifu –yi Shanghaishi weili de lishi kaocha yu fenxi (1958-1966: Deviation and
Restoration of Residents’ Committee Functions: A History Analysis based on
Shanghai)” Shanghai shehui kexuanyuan xueshu jikan (Quarterly Journal of the
Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences) 3 (2002): 183-192.
Guo, Shengli, and Wang Yinong. “Cong liweihui dao geweihui: ‘wenge’ shinianzhong
juweihui de kaocha yu sikao (From Neighborhood Committees to Revolutionary
Residents’ Committees: Investigating and Reflecting on the Residents’
338
Committee in the Ten Years of Cultural Revolution).” Guangzhou daxue xuebao
(Journal of Guangzhou University) 3:7 (2004), 5-9, 92.
Guo, Weijiang. “Chengshi shequ zizhi de kunjing, shijian, fangxiang he duice (The
Difficulties, Practices, Directions and Solutions of Urban Community SelfGovernance).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor) 9 (2007): 35-37.
Guo, Yajie, and Zhou Jie. “Shequ jianshe: beijing, moshi he fazhan qushi (Community
Construction, Background, Models and Trends).” Xuexi yu tansuo (Study and
Exploration) 6 (2004): 42-44.
Han, Jun. “Xinshiqi shequ dangjian yu Zhongguo gongchandang de xiandaihua
(Community Party Building in the New Era and the Modernization of the Chinese
Communist Party).” Xinjiang shehui kexue (Social Sciences in Xinjiang) 3 (2005):
24-27.
Han, Quanyong. “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin zuzhi de fazhan yu qishi (zhiyi):
Xinzhongguo diyige dansheng shimo (The Development and Inspiration of Urban
Residents’ Organizations in Early History of the PRC [part 1]: The Beginning and
End of the First in New China).” Shequ (Community) 9 (2006): 34-36.
----. “Jianguo chuqi chengshi jumin zuzhi de fazhan yu qishi (zhi’er): Zhengti chiding,
juweihui zhongjie baoqiazhi lishi (The Development and Inspiration of Urban
Residents’ Organizations in Early History of the PRC [part 2]: Establishment of
the Regime: the Residents’ Committee System Ending the Baojia System).”
Shequ (Community) 11 (2006): 24-26.
He, Baogang. “Western Theories of Deliberative Democracy and Chinese Practice of
Complex Deliberative Governance.” In The Search for Deliberative Democracy
in China, edited by Ethan J. Leib and Baogang He. New York, NY: Palgrave
Macmillan, 2006.
----. Rural Democracy in China: The Role of Village Elections. New York, NY: Palgrave
Macmillan, 2007.
He, Baogang, and Ethan J. Leib. “Editors’ Introduction.” In The Search for Deliberative
Democracy in China, edited by Ethan J. Leib and Baogang He. New York, NY:
Palgrave Macmillan, 2006.
He, Haibing, and Yu Mengmiao. “Wuye dangjian lianjian rang shequ jumin de haochu
(Property Management Party Building Benefits Community Residents).” Shequ
(Community) 18 (2007): 13-14.
339
He, Xiaohui. “Woguo yezhu gongyue wenti zhi tantao (An Inquiry into the Issues of
Homeowners’ Covenant in China).” Gansu zhengfa chengren jiaoyu xueyuan
xuebao (Journal of Adult Education of Gansu Political Science and Law Institute)
1 (2006): 20-22.
He, Xiaoling et al. “Jiepin minxuan: hefahu? helihu (The Street Hires, the Residents
Elect: Legal? Reasonable)?” Shequ (Community) 20 (2002): 17-18.
He, Zhongzhou. “Pinge xiaoqu: ‘zizhi’ xinfu shenghuo (Pinge Neighborhood: Creating a
Happy Life).” Zhongguo xinwen zhoukan (China Newsweek) 26 (2007): 35-37.
Heberer, Thomas. “Institutional Change and Legitimacy via Urban Elections? People’s
Awareness of Elections and Participation in Urban Neighborhoods (Shequ).” In
Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China: Institutional Change and Stability,
edited by Thomas Heberer and Gunter Schubert. New York, NY: Routledge,
2009.
Held, David. Models of Democracy, 2nd ed. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press,
1996.
Henderson, Gail. The Chinese Hospital: A Socialist Work Unit. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press, 1984.
Hu, Hui. “Lun jumin zizhi shijiaoxia goujian chengshi shequ dangjian gongzuo xingeju
(On the Construction of a New Framework of Urban Community Party Building
from the Perspective of Residents’ Self-Governance).” Zhonggong gongchandang
(Communist Party of China) 10 (2007): 100-103.
Hu, Shensheng, ed. Shequ cidian (A Dictionary of Community). Shanghai: Shanghai guji
chubanshe, 2006.
Hu, Weihua. “Xiaoqu uezhu lintan de zuoyong yu jianshe (The Functions and
Contributions of Neighborhood Homeowners’ Forums) Xiandai wuye (Modern
Property Management) 2 (2006): 30-31.
Hu, Yong. “Jiedao banshichu yu shequ jumin weiyuanhui guanxi tantao (An Inquiry into
the Relationship between the Street Office and the Community Residents’
Committee).” Ningbo dangxiao xuebao (Journal of Ningbo Party School) 5
(2005): 55-58.
Hu, Yongqin. “Heilongjiangsheng chengshi shequ jumin canyu wenti yanjiu (A Study of
the Problems of Community Participation in Heilongjiang).” Ha’erbin shiwei
dangxiao xuebao (Journal of Harbin Committee School of the CCP) 52:4 (2007):
42-45.
340
Huntington, Samuel P. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century.
Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press, 1991.
Jacobs, J. Bruce. “Elections in China.” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 25
(1991): 171-199.
Jiang, Zemin. Jiang Zemin on the “Three Represents”. Beijing: Foreign Languages
Press, 2003.
Jiangsusheng dangde jianshe xuehui, Taizhou dangde jianshe xuehui. “Guanyu shequ
dangzuzhi lindao tizhi deng jige wenti de gaige gouxiang (Ideas for Reforming
the Community Party Organization Leadership System and Other Issues).”
Dangde shenghuo (Party’s Life) 2 (2007): 16-19.
Jin, Zhiwei. “Yezhu gongyue shibushi hetong (Is the Homeowners’ Covenant a
Contract)?” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor) 5 (2005): 37-39.
Jin, Zhu. “Jiaozhi shequ dangwu jiandu xiang ‘yiti’ zhuanbian (Jiaozhi Community
Oversight of Party Affairs Transitioning to a ‘Different Body’).” Shequ
(Community) 5 (2007): 20-21.
Jiujie quanguo renda changweihui zhifa jiancha baogao huibian (Compilation of Reports
of Law Implementation Inspection Team of the 9th Standing Committee of the
National People’s Congress). Beijing: Zhongguo minzhu yu fazhi chubanshe,
2003.
Kojima, Kazuko, and Ryosei Kokubun. “The Shequ Construction Programme and the
Chinese Communist Party.” In Brining the Party Back In: How China is
Governed, edited by Kjeld Erik Brødsgaard and Zheng Yongnian. Singapore:
Eastern Universities Press, 2004.
Kojima, Tomoyuki. “China’s Political Governance: Transformation from Jiang Zemin to
Hu Jintao.” In Restructuring China: Party, State and Society after the Reform and
Open Door, edited by Nakagane Katsuji and Kojima Tomoyuki. Tokyo: The
Toyo Bunko, 2006.
Lei, Cuihong. “Yeweihui he juweihui nengfou he’erwweiyi (Can the Homeowners’
Committee and the Residents’ Committee Merge into One)?” Shequ (Community)
2 (2006): 34-35.
Li, Chaoyang. “Chengshi shequ dangjian: jiaqiang dangde jianshe de zhanluexing xuanze
(Urban Community Party Building: A Strategic Choice to Strengthen Party
Building).” Tianjin shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of Tianjin Normal University) 5
(2005): 1-5.
341
Li, Fan. “Yige cong nongcun xuanju xiang chengshi xuanju guodu de chenggong shili (A
Successful Case of Transition from Rural Elections to Urban Elections).” Shequ
(Community) 11 (2002): 23-26.
----, ed. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju gaige (Direct Election Reform in China’s
Urban Communities). Xi’an: Xibei daxue chubanshe, 2003.
----. “Zhongguo dalu chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu fazhan beijing (The Background of
the Development of Community Grassroots Democracy in Urban China).” In
Zhongguo dalu chengshi jiceng minzhu yanjiu (A Study of Grassroots Democracy
in Mainland China), edited by Chu Shin-min. Taipei: Yuanjing jijinhui, 2004.
----, ed. Zhongguo xuanju zhidu gaige (Reform of the Electoral System in China).
Shanghai: Shanghai jiaotong daxue chubanshe, 2005.
----, ed. Zhongguo jiceng minzhu fazhan baogao 2005 (A Report on Grassroots
Democracy in China 2005). Beijing: Zhishi chanquan chubanshe, 2006.
----, ed. Zhongguo jiceng minzhu fazhan baogao 2006/2007 (A Report on Grassroots
Democracy in China 2006/2007). Beijing: Zhishi chanquan chubanshe, 2007.
Li, Hongmei. “Lun cunmin weiyuanhui xuanju yu jumin weiyuanhui xuanju de qubie yu
jingji xingxiang (On the Differences between Villages’ Committee Elections and
Residents’ Committee Elections and the Economic Causes).” Honghe xueyuan
xuebao (Journal of Honghe College) 3 (2004): 19-22.
Li, Huan. “Guanyu woguo chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu jianshe de jidian sikao (Several
Thoughts on the Grassroots Democratic Construction in China’s Urban
Communities).” Shaanxi shifan daxue jixue jiaoyu xuebao (Journal of Further
Education of Shaanxi Normal University) 21:2 (2004): 57-59.
Li, Huibin, & Xue Xiaoyuan, eds. Zhongguo xianshi wenti yanjiu qianyan baogao 20052006 (A Report on the Frontier Research on China’s Present Issues 2005-2006).
Shanghai: Huadong shifan daxue chubanshe, 2006.
Li, Lianyong. “Shequ minzhu heyi keneng (How Possible is Community Democracy).”
Zhonggong Zhejiang shengwei dangxiao xuebao (Journal of Zhejiang Provincial
Party School) 6 (2003): 94-96.
Li, Xiuyun, and Yang Shicen. “’Minpingguan’ dailai de xinqixiang (The New
Atmosphere Brought by the ‘Public Evaluation of Officials’)” Shequ
(Community) 5 (2005): 26.
Liang, Qidong. “Chengshi shequ jainshe guanli de tizhi quexian yu chuangxin gouxiang
(The System Defects and Innovative Thoughts in the Construction and
342
Management of Urban Communities).” Shehui kexue (Journal of Social Sciences)
6 (2001): 39-42, 46.
Liao, Zhongping. “Shequ juweihui ying qudai yezhu weiyuanhui (The Residents’
Committee Should Replace the Homeowners’ Committee).” Xiandai wuye
(Modern Property Management) 3 (2003): 9.
Lieberthal, Kenneth. Governing China: From Revolution to Reform, 2nd ed. New York,
NY: W.W. Norton & Co., 2004.
Lin, Shangli. “Jiceng qunzhong zizhi: Zhongguo minzhu zhengzhi jianshe de shijian
(Grassroots Mass Self-Governance: The Practice of Democratic Political
Construction in China).” In Haixia liang’an difang zhengfu yu zhengzhi (CrossStraits Local Government and Politics), edited by Chen Wei-chun. Kaohsiung:
Graduate Institute of Political Science, National Sun Yat-sen University, 1999.
----. Dangdai Zhongguo zhengzhi xingtai yanjiu (A Study of China’s Contemporary
Political Formation). Tianjin: Tianjin renmin chubanshe, 2000.
----. Gongchandang zhizheng fanglue (Governing Strategies of the Communist Party).
Shanghai: Shanghai shehui kexueyuan chubanshe, 2002.
----, ed. Shequ minzhu yu zhili: anli yanjiu (Community Democracy and Governance:
Case Studies). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 2003.
Lin, Shangli, and Ma Yili. Shequ zuzhi yu juweihui jianshe, Shanghai shequ jianshe
baogao chongshu zhiqi (Community Organization and Residents’ Committee
Construction, Volume 7 of the Shanghai Community Construction Report Series).
Shanghai: Shanghai daxue chubanshe, 2000.
Liu, Bo. “Waiji jumin ruxuan juweihui de xuanji loji yu shequ zhengzhi kongjian
zhuanhuan (The Electoral Logic and Transformation of Community Politics in the
Elections of Foreign Nationals into the Residents’ Committee).” Shehui kexue
(Journal of Social Sciences) 7 (2007): 124-131.
Liu, Chongshun. “Wuhanshi Chang’er shequ juweihui huanjie zhixuan kaocha baogao (A
Report on the Residents’ Committee Election in Chang’er Community, Wuhan).”
Shehui gongzuo (Journal of Social Work) 5 (2004): 22-26.
Liu, Feng. “Moba ‘yijiantiao’ biancheng ‘yidaoqie’ (Do not Make ‘One Shoulder
Carrying All’ Become ‘One Knife Cut’).” Zhongguo minzheng (China Civil
Affairs) 9 (2002): 45.
Liu, Feng, and Chang Jun. “Lun shehui zhuanxingqi shequ renmin neibu maodun de
chansheng yuanyin he tedian (On the Characteristics and Causes of the Internal
343
Conflicts in Communities during the Transitional Era).” Shanghai shehui
kexueyuan xueshu jikan (Quarterly Journal of the Shanghai Academy of Social
Sciences) 3 (2000): 57-64.
Liu, Jitong. “Zuzhixing dongyuan yu zhengzhi jingji yundong: 20shiji 60-70niandai
Zhongguo chengshi shequ gongzuo moshi (Organizational Mobilization and
Political-Economic Campaigns: The Community Work Model in Urban China in
the 1960s and 1970s).” Beijing keji daxue xuebao (Journal of Beijing University
of Science and Technology) 1 (2005): 30-35.
Liu, Jiyuan. “Shequ dangjian you liangde leiji xiang zhide tisheng jieduan zhuanbian
yanjiu (A Study of the Transition of Community Party Building from Quantitative
Accumulation to Qualitative Improvement).” Zhonggong Shijiazhuang shiwei
dangxiao xuebao (Journal of the Party School of Shijiazhuang Party Committee).
10:2 (2008): 11-16.
Liu, Xiaokang. “Zhengfu yu shehui hudong: Shenyang shequ zizhi moshi tanwei
(Interaction between Government and Society: An Inquiry into the Shenyang
Community Self-Governance Model).” Guojia xingzheng xueyuan xuebao
(Journal of China National School of Administration) 5 (2000): 41-43, 84.
Liu, Zhichang, and Chen Weidong. “Danweiren buyi xiangyou xuanjuquan (Work Unit
People Should Not Have Suffrage).” Shequ (Community) 24 (2004): 18-19.
Lu, Jimin. “Youle shequ zizhiquan, dangjia jiuneng zuozhule (With the Right to SelfGovernance, Residents Can Become Their Own Masters).” Shequ (Community)
12 (2001): 19-20.
Lu, Jing. Zhonggong dangzheng yanjiu lunwenji, shangji (Essays on the Study of the
Chinese Communist Party, First Volume). Taipei: Zhonggong yanjiu zhazhishe,
1999.
Lu, Xiaobo, and Elizabeth Perry, eds. Danwei: The Changing Chinese Workplace in
Historical and Comparative Prespectives. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997.
Luo, Feng. “Jiceng minzhu cong xiangcun dao chengshi (Grassroots Democracy from the
Countryside to the Cities).” Tansuo yu zhengming (Exploration and Free Views) 4
(2001): 21-23.
Luo, Fu. “City Dwellers and the Neighborhood Committee.” Beijing Review 23:44
(1980): 19-25.
March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen. “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors
in Political Life.” American Political Science Review 78:3 (1984): 734-749.
344
Marx, Karl. The Civil War in France. New York, NY: International Publishers, 1940.
----. Political Writings, Volume II: Surveys from Exile. Edited by David Fernbach. New
York, NY: Random House, 1973.
McKenzie, Evan. Privatopia: Homeowner Associations and the Rise of Residential
Private Government. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1994.
Meisner, Maurice. Mao’s China and After: A History of the People’s Republic, rev. ed.
New York, NY: The Free Press, 1986.
Meng, Fangwu. “Xieshang yishi: suantian kula zhenbuyi (Consultation and Deliberation:
Joys, Hardships, Difficulties).” Shequ (Community) 12 (2002): 21-22.
Meng, Hongli. “Ni quguo juweihui ma –dui shequ shenghuozhong juweihui zuoyong de
diaocha (Have You Been to Your Residents’ Committee –An Investigation of the
Role of the Residents’ Committee in Community Life).” Shequ (Community) 13
(2007): 12-14.
Meng, Xiansheng. “Yeweihui buneng zhiyu diedaoban he juweihui de lingdao xia
(Homeowners’ Committee Cannot be Put Under the Leadership of the Street
Office and the Residents’ Committee).” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property
Management) 7 (2007): 61.
Miao Zhenghua. “Juweihui ruhe dui yeweihui ‘jiandu yu zhidao’ (How the Residents’
Committee ‘Supervise and Guide’ the Homeowners’ Committee)?” Xiandai wuye
(Modern Property Management) 1 (2006): 32-34.
“Minzhengbu guanyu zai quanguo tuijin chengshi shequ jianshe de yijian (Opinion of the
Ministry of Civil Affairs on Promoting Community Construction Nationwide).”
In Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003 (China’s Community Construction
Yearbook 2003). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe (2004).
Minzhengbu jiceng zhengquan he shequ jianshe si ketizu (Special Group of the Bureau of
Base-level Government and Community Construction, Ministry of Civil Affairs).
“Guanyu ‘shequ gongzuozhan’ liqing naxie renshi (Several Clarifications
Regarding the ‘Community Work Station’).” Shequ (Community) 2 (2007): 6-9.
Moore, Rebecca. “China’s Fledging Civil Society: A Force of Democratization?” World
Policy Journal 18:1 (2001): 56-66.
Nathan, Andrew. Chinese Democracy. New York, NY: Alfred Knopf, 1985.
----. “Authoritarian Resilience.” Journal of Democracy 14:1 (2003): 6-17.
345
----. “China’s Political Trajectory: What Are the Chinese Saying?” In China’s Changing
Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by Cheng Li. Washington,
DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2008.
Ni, Binlu. “Ruhe jieding yeweihui zhuguan bumen de xingzhengquan (How to Determine
the Administrative Authority of the Government Agencies Overseeing
Homeowners’ Committees).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property
Management –New Proprietor) 5 (2005): 7-8.
“Ningboshi Haishuqu shequ zhuanzhi gongzuozhe guanli banfa [shixing] (Regulations of
Professional Community Workers in Haishu District, Ningbo [Trial Version]).”
Shequ (Community) 5 (2005): 20-21.
Ogden, Suzanne. “The Changing Content of China’s Democratic Socialist Institutions” In
Establishing Democratic Rule: The Reemergence of Local Governments in PostAuthoritarian Systems, edited by Ilpyong J. Kim and Jane Shapiro Zacek.
Washington, DC: Washington Institute Press,1993.
----. Inklings of Democracy in China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center,
2002.
----. “Governance in China.” In China in the Twentieth Century: Challenges and
Opportunities, edited by Shiping Hua and Sujian Guo. New York, NY: Palgrave
Macmillan, 2007.
Ou, Xiaoming. “Louyu dangjian yu shequ dangjian he hudong (Interactions between
Building Party Building and Community Party Building).” Dangzheng ganbu
luntan (Cadres’ Tribune) 11 (2005): 9-10.
Pan, Xiaojuan. “Shequ xingzhenghua wenti tanjiu (An Inquiry into the Problem of
Governmentalization of Community).” Guojia xingzheng xueyuan xuebao
(Journal of the National Institute of Administration) 1 (2007): 33-36.
Pei, Minxin. “Fighting Corruption: A Difficult Challenge for Chinese Leaders.” In
China’s Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by
Cheng Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2008.
Peng, Bo. “Democracy, Governance and Party Legitimacy: A Study of the Neighborhood
in Shanghai.” In China at the Turn of 21st Century, edited by Jørund Buen and
Björn Kjellgren. Stockholm: Nordic Association for China Studies, 2002.
----. Lujing yilai yu zhili xuanze: Dangdai Zhongguo chengshi shequ biange (Path
Dependence and Governance Choice: Changes in Contemporary Urban
Communities in China). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe, 2007.
346
Peng, Zheng, Pengzhen xuanji (Selected Works of Peng Zhen). Beijing: Remin
chubanshe, 1991.
Pu, Wanhong. “Lun shequ xuanju zhong xuanmin de zhiqingxuan jiqi shixuan (On the
Voters’ Right to Know and its Realization in Community Elections).” Yunnan
xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Yunnan Institute of Administration) 1
(2004): 47-50.
Pu, Xingzu, ed. Zhonghua renmin gongheguo zhengzhi zhidu (The Political System of the
People’s Republic of China). Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe, 2005.
“Pudong xinqu guanyu jiaqiang dui yezhu weiyuanhui gongzuo zhidao he guanli de
ruogan guiding (Some Measures to Strengthen the Work Guidance and
Management of Homeowners’ Committees in Pudong New District).” Pudong
kaifa (Pudong Development) 8 (2001): 57-58.
Qian, Xiaoping. “Yezhu gongyue falu xingzhi zhi tantao (An Inquiry into the Legal
Nature of the Homeowners’ Covenant).” Beijing gongye daxue xuebao (Journal
of Beijing University of Technology) 4:4 (2004): 78-82.
Qin, Jing. “Shanghai Luwan jianli le shequ ‘sanhui’ zhidu (Shanghai’s Luwan District
Established a Community ‘Three-Meeting’ System).” Shequ (Community) 1
(2002): 17-18.
Read, Benjamin L. “Revitalizing the State’s ‘Urban Nerve Tips’.” The China Quarterly
163 (2000): 806-820.
----. “Democratizing the Neighborhood? New Private Housing and Home-Owner Self
Organization in Urban China.” The China Journal 49 (2003): 31-59.
----. “Inadvertent Political Reform via Private Associations: Assessing Homeowners’
Groups in New Neighborhoods.” In Grassroots Political Reform in Contemporary
China, edited by Elizabeth J. Perry and Merle Goldman. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 2007.
----. “Property Rights and Homeowner Activism in New Neighborhoods.” In Privatizing
China: Socialism from Afar, edited by Li Zhang and Aihwa Ong. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, 2008.
Ren, Yuan, and Zhang Zhigang. “Zhongguo chengshi shequ fazhan dianxing shijian
moshi de bijiao fenxi (Comparison and Analaysis of the Basic Models in Urban
China Community Development).” Shehui kexue yanjiu (Social Science
Research) 6 (2003): 97-100.
347
Richardson, Sophie. “Self-Reform Within Authoritarian Regimes: Reallocations of
Power in Contemporary China.” In Political Civilization and Modernization in
China, edited by Yang Zhong and Shiping Hua. Singapore: World Scientific,
2006.
Salaff, Janet Weitzner. “Urban Residential Communities in the Wake of the Cultural
Revolution.” In The City in Communist China, edited by John Wilson Lewis.
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1971.
Samoff, John. “Single-Party Competitive Elections in Tanzania.” In Elections in
Independent Africa, edited by Fred M. Hayward. Boulder, CO: Westview Press,
1987.
Sartori, Giovanni. The Theory of Democracy Revisited. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House
Publishers, 1987.
Schmitter, Phillippe C., and Terry Lynn Karl. “What Democracy is…and is Not.” In
Annual Editions: Comparative Politics 09/10, edited by O. Fionna Yap. New
York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 2010.
Schubert, Gunter. “Village Elections, Citizenship and Regime Legitimacy in
Contemporary Rural China.” In Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China:
Institutional Change and Stability, edited by Thomas Heberer and Gunter
Schubert. New York, NY: Routlege, 2009.
Schurmann, Franz. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. Berkeley and Los
Angeles, CA: University of California Press, 1968.
Shao, Renwei. “Chenshi jumin sheu canyu de zuzhi tizhi fenxi (An Analysis of the
Organizational Structure of Community Participation by Urban Residents).”
Xiandai chengshi yanjiu (Modern Urban Research) 11 (2004): 22-25.
Shengwei zuzhibu zuzhichu. “Wosheng chengshi shequ dangjian gongzuo diaocha
(Survey of the Community Party Building Work in Guizhou Province).” Dangdai
Guizhou (Guizhou Today) 6 (2003): 30-31.
“Shenzhengshi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize (The Rule of Conduct for
the Homeowners’ Assembly and the Homeowners’ Committee).” Xiandai wuye –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 5 (2005): 24-27.
“Shequ minzhu de zizhi baohusan (The Protective Umbrella of Community Democratic
Self-Governance).” Shequ (Community) 13 (2002): 28-29.
Shi, Fayong. “Chengshi shequ minzhu jianshe yu zhiduxing yueshu: Shanghai juweihui
gaige ge’an yanjiu (Democratic Construction in Urban Communities and
348
Institutional Constraints: A Case Study of Residents’ Committee Reforms in
Shanghai).” Shehui (Society) 2 (2005): 50-77.
Shi, Jun. “Lun juweihui chongzu (On the Re-Organization of the Residents’ Committee)
Shehui kexue (Journal of Social Sciences) 1 (2001): 43-46.
Shu, Kexin. “Yezhu weiyuanhui shibanan (Eighteen Obstacles for Homeowners’
Committees).” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 4 (2004): 50-55.
----. “Cong Meiliyuan shijian kan yeweihui de xingwei houguo chengdan (The
Responsibilities of the Homeowners’ Committee from the Perspective of the
Meiliyuan Incident).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –
New Proprietor) 2 (2009): 13-14.
Shu, Shunlin, and Liu Tongchang. “Fushanhou xiaoqu: xiaozhengfu, dashehui
(Fushanhou Community: Small Government, Big Society).” Zhongguo minzheng
(China Civil Affairs) 4 (2003): 11-13.
Shue, Vivienna. The Reach of the State: Sketches of the Chinese Body Politic. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press, 1988.
Song, Ancheng. “Guanjia nanding quliu, jiazhang mianlin ‘fenjia’ (Undecided about the
Housekeepers, Owners are Divided).” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property
Management) 10 (2005): 46-50.
Song, Yunxia. “Qianxi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui chengli nan de yuanyin (A
Preliminary Analysis of the Difficulties in Establishing the Homeowners’
Assembly and the Homeowners’ Committee).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhyu (Modern
Property Management –New Proprietor) 7 (2008): 94-95.
Tan, Qingshan. Village Elections in China: Democratizing the Countryside. New York,
NY: Edwin Mellen Press, 2006.
Tan, Sufen, and Xu Shuling. “Jumin daibaio rixin ‘minpingguan’ (Residents’
Representatives are Enthusiastic about ‘Public Evaluation of Officials’).” Shequ
(Community) 2 (2004): 15.
Tang, Juan. “Cong querenxing xuanju dao jingxuanxing xuanju: dongying yu yiyi (From
Confirmative Election to Competitive Election: Factors and Implications).”
Nanjing shehui kexue (Social Sciences in Nanjing) 3 (2004): 39-43.
----, ed. Chengshi shequ yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan yanjiu (Studies of the Development of
Homeowners’ Committees in Urban Communities). Chongqin: Chongqin
chubanshe, 2005.
349
----. “Yueliangwan de yezhu weiquan xinmoshi (A New Model of Homeowners’ RightsDefense in Yueliangwan).” Xiandai wuye (Modern Property Management) 3
(2006): 5-7.
Tan, Juan, and Yu Pinchi. “Shequ yeweihui xuanju zhidu shizheng yanjiu [shang] (An
Empirical Study of the Election System of the Homeowners’ Committee [part
1]).” Xiandai wuyue –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor)
2 (2009): 28-33.
----. “Shequ yeweihui xuanju zhidu shizheng yanjiu [zhong] (An Empirical Study of the
Election System of the Homeowners’ Committee [part 2]).” Xiandai wuyue –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009): 20-25.
Tang, Yalin, and Chen Xianshu. “Shequ zizhi: chengshi shequ jiceng minzhu de fugui yu
zhangyang).” Xueshujie (Academics in China) 6 (2003): 7-22.
Tang, Zhenfang. “You shui zaihu shequ zhixuan (Who Cares about Community
Elections?)” Shequ (Community) 16 (2004): 12-14.
Taylor, Charles. “Models of Civil Society.” Public Cultures 3:1 (1991): 95-118.
Thorton, John L. “Long Time Coming: The Prospects for Democracy in China” Foreign
Affairs 87:1 (2008): 2-17.
Thornton, Patricia M. “Crisis and Governance: SARS and the Resilience of Chinese
Body Politic.” The China Journal 61 (2009): 23-48.
Tian, Hua. “Lun Zhongguo shequ fuwu qianshinian de fazhan guiji (On the Track of
Development of the Community Services in the First Ten Years).” Lilun yuekan
(Theory Monthly) 11 (2007): 87-89.
Tian, Menghai, and Wu Enyu. “Lun yezhu weiyuanhui de yuangao diwei (On the
Plaintiff Status of the Homeowners’ Committee).” Fazhi yanjiu (Rule of Law
Studies) 8 (2008): 61-66.
Tönnies, Ferdinand. Community and Civil Society. Edited by Jose Harris. New York, NY:
Cambridge University Press. 2001.
Tocqueville, Alexis de. Alexis de Tocqueville on Democracy, Revolution and Society,
edited by John Stone and Stephen Mennell. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press, 1980.
Tordoff, William. “Tanzania: Democracy and the One-Party State.” Government and
Opposition 2:4 (1967): 599-614.
350
Tu, Longke. “Shanghaishi S jiedao jiceng zhijie xuanju de diaocha (An Investigation into
the Grassroots Direct Elections in S Street in Shanghai).” Huadong ligong daxue
xuebao (Journal of East China University of Science and Technology) 3 (2005):
14-18.
Wakeman, Frederic, Jr. “Cleanup’: The New Order in Shanghai.” In Dilemmas of
Victory: The Early Years of the People’s Republic of China, edited by Jeremy
Brown and Paul G. Pickowicz. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2007.
Walder, Andrew. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese
Industry. Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press, 1986.
Wang, Bangzuo, et al. Juweihui yu shequ zhili: Chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zuzhi
yanjiu (The Residents’ Committee and Community Governance: An
Organizational Study of Urban Residents’ Committees). Shanghai: Shanghai
renmin chubanshe, 2003.
Wang, Dong. “Lun shequ guanlizhong jumin zizhi he zhengfu jigou de hudong (On the
Interactions between Residents’ Self-Governance and Government Organizations
in Community Management).” Sichuan xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of
Sichuan Administration College) 6 (2006): 60-62.
Wang, Gang et al. “Dushi zhong de minzhu ‘mafan’ (The Democratic ‘Problematic’ in
the Cities).” Zhongguo xinwen zhoukan (China Newsweek) 8:14 (2006): 20-22.
Wang, Hua. “Woguo chengshi shequ zhijie xuanju tanjiu (An Inquiry into Urban Direct
Community Elections in China).” Sichuan xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of
Sichuan Administration College) 4 (2008): 45-48.
Wang, Hua and Li Fenfa. “Chengshi shequ jumin weiyuanhui zhijie xuanju yanjiu (A
Study of Direct Elections of Urban Residents’ Committees).” Xiamen tequ
dangxiao xuebao (Journal of the Party School of CPC Xiamen Municipal
Committee) 3 (2008): 31-35.
Wang, Jian, and Tan Luyong. “Yezhu weiyuanhui fazhan zhuangkuang yanjiu (A Study
of the Development of Homeowners’ Committees).” Shangfai fangdichan
(Shanghai Real Estate) 7 (2007): 44-46.
Wang, Jianjun. “Mofan xiaoqu de yeweihui xuanju fengbo (Turbulences in the
Homeowners’ Committee Election at a Model Neighborhood).” Xiandai wuye –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 3 (2009): 8-12.
Wang, Qi. “‘Sanhui zhidu’ de shijian yu sikao (The Thought and Practice of the ‘ThreeMeeting’ System).” Shanghai dangshi yu dangjian (Party History and Party
Building in Shanghai) 11 (2007): 40-43.
351
Wang Shaoguang, “Gongzhong juece canyu jizhi: yige fenxi kuangjia (Mechanism of
Public Participation in Decision Making: An Analytical Framework).” Paper
presented at the International Conference on “Chinese-Style” Democracy, Wuhan
University, China, November 13-15, 2009.
Wang, Shihao. “Shequ juminj gongyue yu shequ jumin zizhi zhangcheng youshe qubie
(What are the Differences between Residents’ Agreements and Residents’ SelfGovernance Charter)?” Shequ (Community) 6 (2001): 24.
Wang, Tongxu. “Zai ‘minxuan jiepin’ zhong zhaozhun ziji de weizhi (Finding a Correct
Position in ‘Residents Elect, the Street Hires’).” Shequ (Community) 13 (2006):
27.
Wang, Ya Ping, and Alan Murie. “Social and Spatial Implications of Housing Reform in
China.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24:2 (2000): 397417.
Wang, Yicheng, and Yun Jie. “Gaige kaifang yilai de Zhongguo jiceng minzhu jianshe
(China’s Grassroots Democratic Building since the Reform Era).” Zhengzhixue
yanjiu (CASS Journal of Political Science) 2 (2004): 26-33.
Wang, Yin. Xinminzhu zhuyi geming shiqi xuanju zhidu yanjiu (A Study of the Electoral
System during the New Democratic Revolutionary Period). Beijing: Zhongguo
shehui kexue chubanshe, 2005.
Wang Zhanqiang. “Yeweihui bei’an zhidu de sheli bushi baishe (The System of
Homeowners’ Committee’s Record Filing is not Insignificant).” Xiandai wuye –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 12 (2008): 42-45.
Wang, Zhenhua, and Chen Yi. “‘Sansan zhi’: Shanghaishi Luwanqu shequ guanli moshi
xintansuo (The “Three-three” System: A New Approach to Community
Management in Luwan District, Shanghai).” Dangzheng luntan (Party and
Government Forum) 11 (2004): 35-36.
Wang, Zhenyao, and Bai Yihua. Jiedao gongzuo yu jumin weiyuanhui jianshe (The Work
of the Street Office and the Construction of the Residents’ Committee). Beijing:
Zhongguo shehui chubanshe, 1996.
Weatherly, Robert. Politics in China since 1949: Legitimizing Authoritarian Rule, New
York, NY: Routlege, 2006.
Wei, Jian, and Meng Qian. “Bei ‘yezhu daibiao dahui’ tongling de yige xiapqu (A
Neighborhood Governed by the ‘Homeowners’ Representatives Assembly’).”
Shequ (Community) 7 (2007): 6-9.
352
Wei, Kenan. “Lun shequ zizhi (On Community Self-Governance).” Sichuan daxue
xuebao (Journal of Sichuan University) 5 (2003): 48-52.
Whyte, Martin King, and William L. Parish. Urban Life in Contemporary China.
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1984.
Wirth, Loius. “Urbanism as a Way of Life.” In Neighborhood, City and Metropolis: An
Integrated Reader in Urban Sociology, edited by Robert Gutman and David
Popenoe. New York: Random House, 1970.
Womack, Brantly. “Democracy and the Governing Party: A Theoretical Perspective.” In
Political Civilization and Modernization in China: The Political Context of
China’s Transformation. Singapore: World Scientific, 2006.
Wong, Linda, and Bernard Poon. “From Serving Neighbors to Recontrolling Urban
Society: The Transformation of China’s Community Policy.” China Information
19:3 (2005): 413-442.
Wu, Chunxing, and Tian Zuo. “Pobing zhiju, chuangxin zhilu (Ire-Breaking Actions,
Innovative Path).” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese Property Management) 9
(2007): 36-37.
Wu, Deyu. “Zenyang danghao yiming louyuan dangzhibu zhuji (How to Become a Good
Party Secretary of a Building Branch)?” Shequ (Community) 24 (2006): 28-29.
Wu, Gongsun. “Wuye gongsi bufang shangshi yixia zai wangshang yu yezhu hudong
(Property Management Companies Should Interact with Homeowners through the
Internet).” Shequ (Community) 7 (2007): 23.
Wu, Jialin. Wu Jialin zixuanji (Collected Essays of Wu Jialin). Yinchuan: Ningxia renmin
chubanshe, 1996.
Wu, Wei. “Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi canyu buzhu de yuanyin yu duice (The
Causes of and Solutions to the Low Level of Participation in Residents’ SelfGovernance in Urban Communities).” Fujian xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal
of Fujian Institute of Administration) 3(2004): 34-38.
Wu, Wei, and Chen Richang. “Shequ dangjianzhong ‘tiaokuai chongtu’ maodun de
huajie (Resolving the Problem of ‘Vertical-Horizontal Conflicts’).” Gansu
xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Gansu Administration Institute) 3 (2002):
15-17.
353
Wu, Xiang. “Guanyu chengshi shequ dangjian de lilun sikao (Theoretical Thinking about
Urban Community Party Building).” Jinji yu shehui fazhan (Economic and Social
Development) 6:10 (2008): 64-66.
“Wuye guanli tiaoli (Regulations of Property Management).” Shequ (Community) 14
(2003): 51-53.
Xia, Jianzhong. “Zhongguo gongmin shehui de xiansheng: yi yezhu weiyuanhui weiki
(The Forerunner of Civil Society in China: The Homeowners’ Committee as an
Example).” Wenshizhe (Journal of Literature, History and Philosophy) 3 (2003):
115-121.
“Xiamenshi Huliqu Dianqian jiedao Xingleng shequ zizhi zhangcheng (The SelfGovernance Charter of Xingleng Community in Dianqian Street, Huli District,
Xiamen).” Shequ (Community) 2 (2001): 24-25.
Xie, Jian. “Louzhu jumin gongyue jumin ziji ding (Residents Draft Their Own
‘Residents’ Agreement’).” Shequ (Community) 23 (2006): 14.
Xie, Xiaochun, and Bu Dengxue. “Shequ dangjian: shequ jiceng minzhu jianshe de jishi
(Community Party Building: The Foundation of Community Grassroots
Democratic Construction).” Dangde jianshe (Party Building) 3 (2007): 26-27.
Xin shiji dangde jiceng zuzhi gongzuo shiweu shouce (A Practical Handbook of
Grassroots Party Organizational Work in the New Century). Shanghai: Shanghai
renmin chubanshe, 2003.
Xiong Chunmao. “‘Sanhui zhidu’ huajie shequ maodun (“Three-Meeting” System
Resolves Conflicts).” Shequ (Community) 7 (2006): 18-19.
Xiong, Yihan. “Shequ xuanju: zai zhengzhi lengmo yu gao toupiaolu zhijian (Community
Elections: In Between Political Indifference and High Turnout Rate).” Shehui
(Society) 28:3 (2008): 180-204.
Xu, Chongde, ed. Chengshi zhengzhixue (Urban Politics). Beijing: Guangmin ribao
chubanshe, 1988.
Xu, Daowen. “Yezhu weiquan heyi chengwei ‘yundong’ (How Homeowners’ Protection
of their Rights Become a ‘Movement’).” Nanfengchuang (Southern Wind) 10
(2005): 48-49.
Xu, Hao. “Zhiyushanyangzhuang yezhu: 14nian nanshe yeweihui (The Homeowners of
Zhixushan Villa: 14 Years of Difficulty in Establishing a Homeowners’
Committee).” Zhongguo jingji zhoukan (China Economic Weekly) 11 (2007): 3233.
354
Xu, Jiansu, and Wang Yan. “Xiaoqu yezhu weiquan de xiangguan wenti tantao
(Discussion of Issues Related to Rights-Defense among Neighborhood
Homeowners).” Hebei jingmao daxue xuebao (Journal of Hebei University of
Economics and Trade) 7:1 (2007): 35-38.
Xu, Kaiming. “Shequ zizhi de jiben neirong (The Basic Contents of Community SelfGovernance).” Shequ (Community) 20 (2003): 22.
Xu, Qingwen, Jianguo Gao, and Miu Chung Yan. “Community Centers in Urban China:
Context, Development and Limitations.” Journal of Community Practice 13:3
(2005): 73-90.
Xu, Qingwen, and John F. Jones. “Community Welfare Services in Urban China: A
Public-Private Experiment.” Journal of Chinese Political Science 9:2 (2004), 4762.
Xu, Qun, and Zheng Lu. “Shequ ‘yishi weiyuanhui’ neng daiti ‘juweihui’ ma (Can the
Community ‘Deliberative Council’ Replace the Residents’ Committee)?”
Liaowang (Outlook) 6 (2002): 30-31.
Xu, Yong. “Lun chengshi shequ jianshe zhong de shequ jumin zizhi (On Residents’ SelfGovernance in Community Construction).” Huazhong shifan daxue xuebao
(Journal of Central China Normal University) 40:3 (2001): 5-13.
----. “‘Luse jueqi’ yu ‘dushi tupo’: Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi yu nongcun cunmin
zizhi bijiao (‘Green Uprising’ and ‘Urban Breakthrough’: A Comparision of
Urban Community Self-Governance and Rural Villagers’ Self-Governance).”
Xuexi yu tansuo (Study and Exploration) 4 (2002); 32-37.
Xu, Yong, Chen Weidong et al. Zhongguo chengshi shequ zizhi (Community SelfGovernance in Urban China). Wuhan: Wuhan chubanshe, 2002.
Yan, Miu Chung, and Jian Guo Gao. “Social Engineering or Community Building:
Examination of Policy Process and Characteristics of Community Construction in
China.” Community Development Journal 42:2 (2007): 222-236.
Yan, Xiguang. “Shequ xuanju ying huanquan yu jumin (Community Elections Should
Return Powers to Residents).” Shequ (Community) 1 (2005): 19.
Yang, Bo. Cong chongtu dao zhixu: hexie shequ jianshe zhong de yezhu weiyuanhui
(From Conflicts to Order: Homeowners’ Committees in the Construction of
Harmonious Community). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe, 2006.
355
Yang, Dali. “China’s Long March to Freedom.” Journal of Democracy 18:3 (2007): 5864.
Yang, Hongtai, Wu Zhihua, and Shen Haiping, eds. Chengshi shequ tizhi gaige yu fazhi
jianshe yanjiu (System Reform in Urban Communities and A Study of its Legal
Construction). Shanghai: Shanghai Jiaotong daxue chubanshe, 2004.
Yang, Hui, and Zhang Genfu. “Lun chengshi jiceng zhengquan yu jumin zizhi youji
xianjie (On Organically Connecting the Urban Base-Level Government and
Residents’ Self-Governance).” Zhejiang shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of
Zhejiang Normal University) 3 (2003): 10-14.
Yang, Ji. “Neighborhood Committee: A Versatile Grassroots Organization.” Beijing
Review 39:49 (1996): 22-23.
“Yezhu dahui guize (Rules of the Homeowners’ Assembly).” Zhongguo jianshe xinxi
(Information of China Construction) 14 (2003): 15.
Yu, Jianrong. “Shifan de qiyue (An Ineffectual Contract).” Zhongguo nongcun guancha
(China Rural Survey) 1 (2001): 64-69.
Yu, Xianyang et al. “Chengshi shequ minzhu zizhi de tiaojian yu jizhi (The Conditions
and Mechanisms of Urban Community Democratic Self-Governance).” Jiangsu
xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Jiangsu Administration Institute) 2 (2004):
63-69.
Yu, Yanyan, Shequ zizhi yu zhengfu zhineng zhuanbian (Community Self-Governance
and Transformation of Government Functions). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui
chubanshe, 2005.
Yu, Yiqing. “‘Jumin gongyue’ de gongxindu weihe zubu xiangjiang (Why the Credibility
of ‘Residents’ Agreements’ has been Declining)?” Shequ (Community) 23 (2006):
10.
Yuan, Dayi. “Jumin zizhi yu jieju guanxi de yanjin (Residents’ Self-Governance and the
Evolution of the Street Office-Residents’ Committee Relations).” Fazhi lunchong
(Rule of Law Forum) 20:5 (2005): 16-18.
Zhan, Chengfu, ed. Shequ jianshe gongzuo jinzhan baogao (A Report on the Work
Progress of Community Construction). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe,
2005.
----, ed. Shequ juweihui xuanju gongzuo jincheng baogao (A Report on the Progress of
Election Work of Community Residents’ Committee). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui
chubanshe, 2006.
356
Zhang, Baofeng. Xiandai chengshi shequ zhili jiegou yanjiu (A Study of the Governance
Structure of Modern Urban Communities). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui chubanshe,
2006.
Zhang, Boli. The Long Journey from Tiananmen to Freedom. New York, NY:
Washington Square Press, 2002.
Zhang, Guixing. “Guanyu juweihui de diwei zuoyong he cunzai wenti (About the Status
and Problems of the Residents’ Committee).” Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems)
4 (1992): 62-65.
Zhang, Guoxiang. “Shequ zizhi yu shehui kongzhi (Community Self-Governance and
Social Control).” Shehui zhuyi yanjiu (Socialism Studies) 6 (2007): 96-98.
Zhang, Hao. “Shilun ‘haixuan’ dui zhengzhi minzhu de tixian (On the Realization of
Political Democracy by Community ‘Sea Elections’).” Shayang shifan gaodeng
zhuanke xuexiao xuebao (Journal of Shayang Teachers College) 3 (2005): 26-29.
Zhang, Hengshan et al. Fazhi yu dangde zhizheng fangshi yanjiu (The Rule of Law and
Governing Methods of the Party). Beijing: Falu chubanshe, 2004.
Zhang, Ji and Zhao Jie. “Makesi difang zizhi lilun yu 21shiji Zhongguo de shequ zizhi
(Marxist Theory of Local Self-Governance and Community Self-Governance in
21st Century China).” Zhonggong Yunnan shengwei dangxiao xuebao (Journal of
Yunnan Provincial Committee School of the CPC) 3 (2001): 16-20.
Zhang Jingen, Zhuang Wenjia. “Feizhengshi zhengzhi: yige caogen NGO de xingdong
celue (Informal Politics: The Action Strategies of a Grassroots NGO).” Shehuixue
yanjiu (Sociological Studies) 2 (2008): 133-150.
Zhang, Jinliang, and He Zhijun. “Juwu gongkai, daodi ying gongkai xiexe (Information
Disclosure: What Should be Disclosed)?” Zhongguo minzheng (China Civil
Affairs) 4 (2001): 41.
Zhang, Junfang. “Zhongguo chengshi shequ jumin zizhi chuyi (Opinions on the SelfGovernance of Urban Communities).” Tianjin shifan daxue xuebao (Journal of
Tianjin Normal University) 5 (2001): 27-31, 41.
Zhang, Mingyu, and Liu Zhichang. “Shi shui zhai yingxiang juweihui xuanju (Who is
Influencing Residents’ Committee Elections)?” Shequ (Community) 5 (2005): 3031.
Zhang, Nian. “Shanghaishi cong zhidu he caozuo cengmian jiaqiang yeweihui gongzuo
(Shanghai Strengthens the Work on Homeowners’ Committees through
357
Institutional and Operational Aspects).” Zhongguo wuye guanli (Chinese Property
Management) 11 (2007): 52-53.
Zhang, Suhui, and Zeng Gang. “Wanshan Changsha shequ zizhi de tanjiu (An Inquiry
into the Improvement of Community Self-Governance in Changsha).” Hunan
xingzheng xueyuan xuebao (Journal of Hunan Administration Institute) 5 (2005):
49-51.
Zhang, Tao, Wang Xiangmin, and Chen Wenxin. Zhongguo chengshi jiceng zhijie xuanju
yanjiu ( A Study of Direct Elections in Grassroots Urban China). Chongqin:
Chongqin chubanshe, 2008.
Zhang, Tingwei. “Innovation in Chinese Urban Governance: The Shanghai Experience.”
In Governing Cities in a Global Era: Urban Innovation, Competition, and
Democratic Reform, edited by Robin Hambleton and Jill Simone Gross. New
York, NY: Palgrave Macmillian, 2007.
Zhang, Yong. “Chengshi shequ tizhi gaige xianzhuang yu sikao (The Present Situation
and Some Thoughts on Urban Community System Reform).” Guangxi shehui
kexue (Guangxi Social Sciences) 6 (2001): 102-104.
Zhang, Zhifan. “Weiquan yundong tuijin hexie shequ (Rights-Defense Movement
Promoting Community Harmony).” Shequ (Community) 1 (2005): 22-23.
Zhao, Linmin.”Yezhu weiquan, zhenfu zenmeban (Homeowners Protecting Their
Rights,, What Should the Government Do)?” Nanfengchuang (Southern Wind) 7
(2005): 52-53.
Zhao, Xupu. “Chengli yezhu weiyuanhui xiehui de jidian sikao (Several Points about the
Establishment of an Association of Homeowners’ Committees).” Xindai wuye –
xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New Proprietor) 5 (2007): 60-61.
Zhao, Yi. “Zhengfu wei minzhong de minzhu quanli ‘maidan’ zhibuzhi (Is it Worthwhile
for the Government to Pay for People’s Democratic Rights)?” Shequ (Community)
22 (2002): 4-8.
Zheng, Quan. “Shequ juweihui xuanju huodong de xianzhuang, wenti ji duice (The
Present Situation, Problems, and Solutions of Community Residents’ Committee
Elections).” Shequ (Community) 11 (2006): 35-36.
Zheng, Yongnian. “Interest Representation and the Transformation of the Chinese
Communist Party.” In Brining the Party Back In: How China is Governed, edited
by Kjeld Erik Brødsgaard and Zheng Yongnian. Singapore: Eastern Universities
Press, 2004.
358
----. “Explaining the Sources of De Facto Federalism in China: Intergovernmental
Decentralization, Globalization and Central-Local Relations.” Japanese Journal
of Political Science 7:2 (2006): 101-126.
Zheng, Shiping. Party vs. State in Post-1949 China: The Institutional Dilemma. New
York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
“Zhengzhoushi yezhu dahui he yezhu weiyuanhui zhidao guize [shixing] (The Rules of
Conduct for the Homeowners’ Assembly and the Homeowners’ Committee in
Zhengzhou [Trial Version]).” Zhengzhoushi renmin zhengfu gongbao (Public
Records of the City Government of Zhengzhou) 10 (2007): 33-39.
Zhonggong Shanghaishi Jiading quwei zuzhibu.”Kaizhan ‘louzu dangjian’ jianshe hexie
shehui (Carrying Out ‘Building Party Building,’ Constructing Harmonious
Society).” Dangzheng luntan (Party and Government Forum) 9 (2007): 11-12.
Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian yanjiu ketizu, ed. Zhongguo chengshi shequ dangjian
(Community Party Building in Urban China). Shanghai: Shanghai renmin
chubanshe, 2000.
Zhongguo gongchandang zhangcheng (The Constitution of the Communist Party of
China). Beijing: Renmin chubanshe, 2007.
“Zhonghua renmin gongheguo chengshi jumin weiyuanhui zuzhifa (Organic Law on the
Urban Residents’ Committee).” In Zhongguo shequ jianshe nianjian 2003
(China’s Community Construction Yearbook 2003). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui
chubanshe (2004).
Zhou, Hongling, and Zhang Minwei. “Jumin zenyang na xianpiao quandian dangjiaren
(How Residents Vote for Their leaders)?” Shequ (Community) 17 (2002): 7-10.
Zhou, Ping. “Jiedao banshichu de dingwei: Chengshi shequ zhengzhi de yige genben
wenti (The Status of the Street Office: A Fundamental Issue in Urban Community
Politics).” Zhengzhixue yanjiu (CASS Journal of Political Science) 2 (2001); 7682.
Zhou, Qinghua, “Shequ zhixuan: jiceng mizhu jianshe lishixing kuayue (Community
Direct Elections: The Historic Breakthrough in Grassroots Democratic
Construction).” Qianyan (Forward Position) 5 (2006): 224-226.
Zhou, Yan. “Zai kongzhi yeahu zhijian feilixing weiquan zhong tisheng wuye guanli
binzhi (Improving the Quality of Property Management in the Control of
Irrational Rights-Defense Activities of Homeowners).” Zhongguo wuye guanli
(Chinese Property Management) 3 (2005): 62-63.
359
Zhu, Dahui. “Yezhu luntan yu wuye guanli (Homeowners’ Forums and Property
Management).” Xiandai wuye –xinyezhu (Modern Property Management –New
Proprietor) 2 (2009): 6-7.
Zhu, Guoming, “Shanghai: Cong feibaojia dao jumin weiyuanhui de dansheng (Shanghai:
From the Dissolution of Baojia to the Birth of the Residents’ Committee).”
Dang’an yu shixue (Archives and History) 2 (2002): 57-62.
Zhu, Haiyuan. “Beijing chutai guize guifan yeweihui yunxing (Beijing Issues Rules to
Regulate the Operation of Homeowners’ Committees).” Chengshi kaifa (Urban
Development) 3 (2009): 42-43.
Zhu, Jieming. “The Changing Mode of Housing Provision in Transitional China.” Urban
Affairs Review 35:4 (2000): 502-519.
Zhu, Yanfei. “Urumqishi wuye fuwu qiye, juweihui, yeweihui guanxi chutan (A
Preliminary Inquiry into the Relationship between Property Service Enterprises,
Residents’ Committees, and Homeowners’ Committees in Urumqi).” Zhongguo
wuye guanli (Chinese Property Management) 9 (2008), pg. 24-26.
360