Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Are America's Inner Cities Competitive? Evidence from the 2000s

2015, SSRN Electronic Journal

In the years since Michael Porter's paper about the potential competitiveness of inner cities there has been growing evidence of a residential resurgence in urban neighborhoods. Yet, there is less evidence on the competitiveness of inner cities for employment. We document the trends in net employment growth and fi nd that inner cities gained over 1.8 million jobs between 2002 and 2011 at a rate comparable to suburban areas. We also fi nd a signifi cant number of inner cities are competitive over this period-increasing their share of metropolitan employment in 144 out of 281 MSAs. We also describe the pattern of job growth within the inner city, fi nding that tracts that grew faster tended to be closer to downtown, with access to transit, and adjacent to areas with higher population growth. However, tracts with higher poverty rates experienced less job growth, indicating that barriers still exist in the inner city.

w o r k i n g p a p e r 15 03R Are America’s Inner Cities Competitive? Evidence from the 2000s Daniel A. Hartley, Nikhil Kaza, and T. William Lester FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment on research in progress. They may not have been subject to the formal editorial review accorded official Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland publications. The views stated herein are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Banks of Cleveland or Chicago or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Working papers are available on the Cleveland Fed’s website at: www.clevelandfed.org Working Paper 15-03R December 2015* Are America’s Inner Cities Competitive? Evidence from the 2000s Daniel A. Hartley, Nikhil Kaza, and T. William Lester In the years since Michael Porter’s paper about the potential competitiveness of inner cities there has been growing evidence of a residential resurgence in urban neighborhoods. Yet, there is less evidence on the competitiveness of inner cities for employment. We document the trends in net employment growth and find that inner cities gained over 1.8 million jobs between 2002 and 2011 at a rate comparable to suburban areas. We also find a significant number of inner cities are competitive over this period—increasing their share of metropolitan employment in 144 out of 281 MSAs. We also describe the pattern of job growth within the inner city, finding that tracts that grew faster tended to be closer to downtown, with access to transit, and adjacent to areas with higher population growth. However, tracts with higher poverty rates experienced less job growth, indicating that barriers still exist in the inner city. JEL Classification: R12, O18 Keywords: Urban Labor Markets, City and Suburban Employment Suggested citation: Hartley, Daniel A., Nikhil Kaza, and T. William Lester, 2015. “Are America’s Inner Cities Competitive? Evidence from the 2000s,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, working paper no 15-03R. Daniel A. Hartley is at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (daniel.a.hartley@ chi.frb.org); Nikhil Kaza is at the University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill ([email protected]); and T. William Lester is at the University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill ([email protected]). The authors extend special thanks for excellent research assistance to Daniel Kolliner. *First version March 2015. 1. Introduction In the years since Michael Porter’s seminal paper about the potential competitiveness of inner cities, two narratives have emerged about the overall pattern of urban economic development. The first, which we call the “comeback cities” narrative, states that the decades of the 1990s and 2000s were a renaissance for cities as flows of population, jobs and investment shifted back from suburbs and exurbs to urban areas, particularly downtowns The literature on gentrification, as well as the oft-cited creative class theories of Richard Florida underscore this narrative by highlighting the pro-urban preferences and consumption patterns of a new, rising middle class (R. Florida, 2003; Neil Smith, 2002; Zukin, 1982). The second narrative that has taken shape is that of an uneven geography of growth in the last few decades. The literature on high-technology regions argues that contemporary US economic development has taken on a distinctly uneven pattern that leads to a polarization between so-called “innovative” regions and “backward” regions, which in turn drives inequality and a divergence in outcomes across metropolitan areas (Moretti, 2012; Pastor, Lester, & Scoggins, 2009; Saxenian, 1994).i The implication of this second narrative is that the type of inner-city renaissance described in the first narrative will only occur in growing, innovative regional economies. However, is this necessarily the case? Can inner-city economic growth occur in declining regions? Recent research has demonstrated an empirical link between gentrification and neighborhood job growth (Lester & Hartley, 2014). Yet, is the type of consumption-based growth that is fueled by gentrification in growing regions like New York or the San Francisco Bay Area the only mechanism to bring jobs back to urban neighborhoods? Or can robust job growth stem from expansion of anchor institutions in non-tradable sectors such as universities and health care institutions (Adams, 2003; Harkavy & Zuckerman, 1999)? In addition to private market-driven development, policy makers have employed a host of economic development tools and distributed millions of dollars in funding targeted towards business development and job growth in inner-city neighborhoods. Have tools such as targeted tax credits (e.g. Empowerment 2 Zone/Enterprise Community designation, Low Income Housing Tax Credit (LIHTC)) influenced the pattern of inner city employment growth? In this paper, we explore these intertwined narratives by describing the pattern of neighborhood based employment changes at a national scale. We then test the validity of a number of competing claims about the competitiveness of inner-city neighborhoods in terms of economic development during the 2000s. First, using data at the census tract level from the Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) program at the US Census Bureau, we begin by providing an overview of the extent and broad characteristics of employment growth of inner-cities, CBDs, and suburban areas of all metropolitan areas in the U.S. Surprisingly, we find that the rate of job growth between 2002 and 2011 in innercities—defined broadly as non-CBD tracts in the largest principal city within a metropolitan area—was on par with that of suburban areas (6.1% versus 6.9%) and even surpassed suburbs in the post-Great recession recovery (2009-11). This trend is consistent across broad census regions. Yet, this trend is less pronounced—though still positive—when we focus only on portions of the inner city that were more economically distressed at the start of the 2000s. Next, we explicitly test the question of inner-city competitiveness by identifying metropolitan areas that had both net positive employment growth and an increase in the share of jobs located in the inner city (these two criteria form our working definition of competitive inner cities). We find 144 MSAs with competitive inner-cities using our broad definition of inner city tracts and 85 using the narrower method. These MSAs are diverse geographically, but, compared to other metropolitan areas, tend to have above average growth in high-wage jobs, less racial segregation, and less job sprawl. Finally, we provide a third, descriptive analysis of the spatial determinants of inner-city growth at the tract-level within inner-city areas. Specifically, we find that inner-city employment growth is positively associated with neighborhoods closer to downtown, with nearby population increases, recent 3 residential construction, and other indicators of gentrification. We also find that employment grew faster in areas with mixed uses and greater employment diversity. There is some evidence that empowerment zone designation is associated with more employment growth. However, tracts with high poverty levels have lower job growth. Within economically distressed inner city areas, these findings are very similar, although job growth is driven less by indicators of gentrification and are more closely associated with expansion of anchor institutions. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section two reviews the research on the competitiveness of inner cities, and puts our empirical analysis in the context of the literature inspired by Porter’s work. Section three describes the main datasets and analytical methods used in our analysis. Section four presents the descriptive analysis of the patterns of inner city job growth in aggregate and describes our analysis of the characteristics of regions with competitive inner cities. Section five, presents our model of tract-level correlates of inner-city employment growth. The final section concludes the paper and summarizes our rich descriptive analysis of the nature of inner-city job growth in the 2000s. 2. Literature Review Writing in 1997 in this journal, Michael Porter made a strong and influential argument that inner-city areas had important and “unrecognized” competitive advantages as a business location. Specifically, he called for a private-sector-led economic development strategy which leveraged the strategic location of inner city neighborhoods (near the CBD and key infrastructure), the integration with existing regional economic strengths, as well as the local purchasing power and human resources of inner-city residents (Porter, 1997). While he recognized a significant role for government (and nonprofits), he also helped to highlight regulatory barriers of high-taxes and red tape that prevented further 4 private sector investment. Looking back at his strategic recommendations and comparing them to current practice, it is easy to see how influential they have been, as few contemporary urban economic developers or planners would find much to disagree with. However, it is important to recall the context in which he was writing. While the mid-1990s was a period of significant economic growth for the U.S., it followed nearly two decades of economic restructuring which significantly altered the economic role of central cities and changed the geography of employment opportunities throughout most metropolitan areas in the country. The decades of the 1970s and 1980s were characterized by a pattern of economic restructuring that featured the dual trends of massive manufacturing job losses coupled with the continued suburbanization of population and employment. These trends significantly reduced the base of job opportunities for residents of inner city neighborhoods, which once housed many of the goods producing jobs and a predominantly working-class workforce. The problem of declining employment in older, inner-city neighborhoods and growth in emerging suburban areas was first recognized in the late 1960s by scholars like Kain (1968) who argued that housing discrimination coupled with lack of opportunity in urban areas led to a persistently high unemployment of minority workers in inner cities. While the “spatial mismatch” hypothesis has been a widely debated topic in the social sciences (see Chapple, 2006; Ihlanfeldt & Sjoquist, 1989; Teitz & Chapple, 1998), the declining employment within inner-city neighborhoods was widely viewed as a critical problem. To get a sense of how profoundly scholars viewed the problem of the inner-city in the mid-1990s, we recall here the opening lines of Galster and Killen’s (1995) article on the geography of metropolitan opportunity as follows: Horatio Alger lies dead in the streets of the inner city. For millions of Americans, the rags-toriches fable has been reduced to ashes just as surely as have many blocks in South Central Los Angeles and other desperate inner-city communities. What once was a spring board of socioeconomic mobility for generations…has for too many been transformed into a pit in which perpetual deprivation and social dysfunction reign. (Galster and Killen, 1995, 7) 5 Scholars from a wide variety of disciplines attempted to diagnose the problems associated with lack of inner-city employment opportunities, linking it broader issues of neighborhood decline including high crime, persistent poverty, segregation and changing attitudes toward work (Kasarda, 1993; Katz, 1993; Wilson, 1987, 1996). The issue of declining inner-city employment and population losses coupled with continued suburbanization and sprawl also spawned concerns that declining central cities could pose a drag to an entire region’s economic growth. This, in turn, ignited a series of studies specifically focused on the question of whether or not suburbs could prosper without their central cities (Hill, Wolman, & Ford, 1995; Ledebur & Barnes, 1993; Voith, 1992 1998). Pack’s (2002) comprehensive analysis of long-term trends in metropolitan economic performance bears this out. Between 1960 and 1990 the share of income earned by central city residents declined from 45% to 30% and rose in suburban areas from 55% to 70% (Pack, 2002, 3). Although a great deal of empirical work focused on the issue of inner city competitiveness and the inter-dependency of suburbs and cities, eventually a consensus emerged supporting the idea that the economic health of both areas was closely linked by regional factors. Voith (1992) concluded that “decline in central cities is likely to be associated with slow-growing suburbs. Even if the most acute problems associated with urban decline do not arise in the suburbs, central city decline is likely to be a long-run, slow drain on the economic and social vitality of the region.” (Voith, 1992, 31) Just as the attention of federal policy makers shifted away from defining economic challenges in in stark urban versus suburban terms, the academic literature shifted in the following decade to questions of the determinants of overall metropolitan economic competitiveness. The key question here was what factors explained the relative economic health and resilience of some metropolitan regions, particularly those with a growing, high-technology industrial base. The work of Saxenian (1994), Storper (1997) and others argued that metropolitan areas that featured regionally-based networks of 6 firms and supporting institutions that foster accelerated innovation were ultimately more resilient to economic restructuring and, as a result, are more competitive in terms of employment and income growth. This emphasis on innovation and regional competitiveness in the economic development literature had a profound impact on practice (Clark, 2013) and shifted the focus away from intrametropolitan disparities and instead highlighted the overall uneven pattern of metropolitan growth in the 1990s and 2000s. Starting in the early 2000s, a new narrative began to emerge on “comeback cites” as many scholars used newly available census data to identify a growing trend of residential growth particularly focused in the downtown and nearby areas of older central cities (Sohmer & Lang, 2001). Much of this research highlighted shifting demographics such as the aging of the population (i.e. empty nesters without children) and changing preferences for high-amenity locations like downtown as the causes of residential resurgence of downtown areas. This research is largely congruent with a pre-existing literature on the causes and consequences of gentrification. What began as a niche field that focused on select neighborhoods in places like the Lower East Side in New York (Niel Smith, 1996) or the South End in Boston and was initially considered a relatively small trend (Wyly & Hammel, 1999), has now grown to be an active literature drawing scholarship from a wide variety of disciplines. While much of the empirical debate in the gentrification literature focused on measuring the extent of displacement (Freeman, 2005; Marcuse, 1985; Vigdor, 2002) within individual cities, there is growing consensus that gentrification is part of a broader demographic shift that results in the influx of better educated and high income households to formerly low and moderate income inner-city neighborhoods. The drivers of this trend are seen to involve changes in the consumption and locational preferences of what some sociologists called a “new middle class” (Ley, 1996) and what Richard Florida (2002) later termed the “creative class.” Regardless of their moniker, members of this demographic sub-group favor urban living and the greater accessibility it affords over the suburban dream of previous generations. According to 7 these scholars, such preference shifts also drive gentrification by increasing demand for urban entertainment and consumption spaces for the new high-income residents (Lloyd & Clark, 2001; Zukin, 1982). While scholars continue to debate how widespread and significant gentrification is as a demographic trend and what it will ultimate mean for inner cities, there is a growing literature that has examined the impact of gentrification on employment within inner-city neighborhoods. Curran (2004; 2007) focused on a single neighborhood-Williamsburg in Brooklyn—and found that new residential growth led to displacement of nearby industrial jobs. Meltzer and Schuetz (2012) showed that neighborhood retail grew faster in New York City neighborhoods that experienced gentrification. More recently Lester and Hartley (2014) examined the impact of gentrification at the census tract-level using detailed employment data for 29 large cities in the US and found that gentrifying neighborhoods had faster employment growth and a more rapid shift between traditionally blue collar work and locally oriented services such as restaurants and entertainment. Beyond these studies, there have been relatively few papers that specifically look at the nature of employment growth in inner-cities. There have been individual case studies such as Hutton’s (2004) description of the emergence of new hightech industry clusters in Vancouver, BC. In addition, there are two new reports that focus on the longterm residential shifts of poor neighborhoods in U.S. metropolitan areas which suggest that the gentrification or “back to the city” trend may be limited, or is bypassing high-poverty neighborhoods. Specifically, Cortright and Mahmoudi (2014) find that 69 percent of census tracts with high poverty levels (30%) in 1970 still had high poverty levels in 2010. Aliprantis, Fee, and Oliver (2014) examine patterns of tract-level income change between 1980 and 2010 and find considerable stability in tractlevel income quartiles over time. However, they also find that tract-level income growth varied widely by metropolitan characteristics, as tracts that transitioned from poor to non-poor were more likely to be 8 located in growing metropolitan areas that were relatively large and densely populated and which experienced greater immigration. In addition to the gentrification literature, there is also a growing literature on the role of immigrants in reversing the declining population of inner cities and supporting the economic revitalization of urban neighborhoods. For example, Chicago’s small population increase between 1990 and 2000—a reversal of three decades of decline—was driven by large increases in foreign born populations. Some scholars highlight the positive impact of immigration for inner city neighborhoods. For example, Sampson (2008) shows that neighborhoods with a higher share of foreign born residents have lower rates of violent crime. Also, Portes and Zhuo (1992) find that high levels of social capital in tight immigrant ethnic enclaves can lead to greater entrepreneurship among some immigrant groups. However, as Bates (1997, 2011) points out, significant barriers remain that limit immigrant and minority entrepreneurship such as access to capital. Given the potentially conflicting evidence about demographic trends affecting the inner city and the relative paucity of research on recent inner city employment trends, we argue that there is a need for a comprehensive analysis of job growth in America’s inner cities over the past decade. Porter (1997) recognized this need early on, but lamented that there was no single source of localized, workplacebased employment statistics to track the changing economic role of inner city neighborhoods and to assess how much private investment “already recognized” the competitive potential of the inner city. Now we have such a data source; namely the Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) (see below). Ultimately, this paper will use a descriptive approach that revisits some of the key questions in the preceding literature. First, we assess the actual extent of job growth that has occurred in America’s inner cities relative to suburban areas and CBDs between 2002 and 2011, highlighting key differences by broad geographic regions, industrial sector, and tract poverty status. Next, we return to 9 the question of inner city competitiveness by defining a new methodology for identifying which regions have competitive inner cities and what distinguishes them from the rest of the metropolitan pack. Finally, we test some of the predictions of the gentrification literature and build a simple descriptive model of inner city job growth at the tract level. 3. Data Sources and Methodology We primarily use data from the US Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employment and Household Dynamics (LEHD) dataset. Specifically we use special tabulations of the LEHD data created for local transportation and workforce development analysis called the Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) program. The dataset is available at a 2010 block-group-level geography. Total employment and employment by broad industry sector from 2002 through 2011 is summarized to a tract level for the purposes of this analysis. While the dataset is available for the most of the United States, some states are missing from the analysis because of data non-availability for the full period of analysis. These include Arizona, Arkansas, the District of Columbia, Mississippi , New Hampshire and Massachusetts which began participation in the LEHD at various years throughout the period and therefore do not figure in the current analysis. While the LODES data is also available on a worker residence basis, we use workplace-based counts of employment as we are primarily interested in the changing geography of employment between inner-city tracts and other components of metropolitan areas. The LODES dataset is a synthetic dataset derived from confidential data sources such as unemployment insurance records, TIGER line files and additional administrative data from the US Census and the Social Security Administration. Noise is then infused into the workplace totals to protect employer and employee confidentiality. These data production methods and caveats should be considered while evaluating the evidence presented in this analysis. For a more complete description of the LODES dataset and its 10 differences with the standard Census products such as the American Community Survey (ACS) refer to Graham et.al (2014). While the LODES is a relatively new data source for examining employment dynamics at small geographic scales, there is no reason to believe that it is inaccurate or that the statistical “fuzzing” used to protect confidentiality would produce biased estimates. First, as Abowd et. al. (2009) describe the noise introduced to the data does not vary by geographic location in a way that is systematically correlated with our definition of inner-city verus suburab status.ii Second, the LODES is now widely used in transportation planning and in the transportation literature (see (see Owen & Levinson, 2015; Schleith & Horner, 2014). 3.1 Identifying the Inner City As discussed above, while there is significant research on the competitiveness of inner cities, it is very hard to find a commonly accepted definition in the literature as to what constitutes an inner-city area. Generally speaking, inner cities are understood as relatively poor areas with high concentration of minorities within large central cities. While nearly all scholars distinguish the inner city from suburban areas and traditional downtowns, there is little agreement on the essential characteristics of inner-city neighborhoods. Porter implies that these areas are “distressed neighborhoods, in which, in most cases, African Americans and other people of color represent the majority of the population (Porter, 1997. p. 11)”. Yet, more recent studies, such as Hutton (2004), simply look at all non-downtown portions of the central city. Ultimately, the literature lacks a systematic delineation of the geographic or jurisdictional extent of inner cities. As a first approximation, we define inner cities as areas of the largest central city or cities in a Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) that are not part of the Central Business District. To identify the main central cities in each MSA, we consider the official set of Principal Citiesiii within an MSA (as defined by the US Census) and select those principal cities that collectively make up more than 11 half of the principal city population within the MSA. Such identification of main cities in an MSA eliminates classifying older suburban satellite cities (e.g. Schamburg, IL) as inner cities but still retains the flexibility of having multiple inner city clusters within an MSA. For example, in Minnesota both Minneapolis and St. Paul are considered the main cities and the tracts that are not within the CBDs of these cities are considered inner city areas. In general, a vast majority of the 281 MSAs considered in this analysis have only one main central city from which we draw our definition of inner-city tracts. Given the lack of consensus on how to define the inner city for data collection purposes, we use two general methods. First, we take all census tracts within the largest(s) principal city that are outside of the CBD. We call this the “broad” definition of inner-city. Next, we follow Porter’s original definition and further narrow this set of tracts to those that meet the following criteria: a) the tract has a median household income that is below 80 percent of the MSA median income in 2000; and b) the tract also has an unemployment rate greater than 25% above the unemployment rate in 2000 (see Porter (1997), footnote 1). We refer to this narrower definition as the “Porter definition.” 3.1.1 Identifying the CBD In order to classify census tracts as inner-city or not, we needed to clearly define the central business district (CBD) or downtown of each principal city. In addition to lack of definition of inner city, there is also no accepted current definition and delineation of a CBD. The last known delineation of the CBD was done in 1982 by the Census of Retail Trade. To update this identification we first identify all employment centers in an MSA. We then identify the cluster of employment centers that overlap the point definitions of CBD provided by Fee & Hartley (2011) and call them the central business districts (CBDs) within the MSA. The employment centers are identified using methods detailed by McMillen (2001, 2003). Briefly, a locally weighted regression is constructed using the employment densities at a tract level. The 12 weighting function is a smoothing function that accounts for the spatially nearest 50 percent of the density values. A tract is identified as an employment center if the residuals are significantly greater than 0, accounting for the standard error of the estimate. This non-parametric method has been used to identify employment centers in a number of studies (Garcia-López, 2010; Suárez & Delgado, 2009). Once the tracts that have a higher than expected residuals are identified within an MSA, a contiguity matrix is constructed using ‘spdep’ (Bivand, 2015). The contiguity matrices converted to a graph, where nodes are the identified census tracts and a pair of nodes have an edge if the corresponding contiguity matrix element is non-zero using `igraph’ (Csardi & Nepusz, 2006). Once the graph is constructed, standard graph theoretic methods are used to decompose the graph into maximally connected components. If any of the census tracts within a maximally connected cluster overlaps with the CBD point, then we designate the entire cluster a central business district. [FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE] To conduct our descriptive analysis comparing metropolitan regions with competitive inner cities to other regions, and for our tract-level determinants of inner city job growth we also draw upon several other data sources. The two main sources of additional data beyond the LODES dataset are the Smart Location Database (SLD) produced by the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)iv and the Building Resilient Regions (BRR) database. The BRR database is a comprehensive dataset on demographic, economic, and policy variables for all metropolitan areas in the U.S. (mainly derived from Census data) and was produced by the MacArthur Foundation’s Building Resilient Regions research network (see Pastor et. al, 2009 for more information). 4. Employment Trends and the Competitiveness of Inner Cities 4.1 The Nature of Inner City Employment Change in the U.S. in the 2000s. 13 Compared to the preceding two decades, the 2000s was a period of relatively stable job growth for America’s inner cities. During the nine year period from 2002—just after a mild recession—to 2011 two years after the end of the Great Recession—inner city census tracts added 1.8 million net new jobs. Surprisingly, this rate of growth (6.1 percent) was roughly comparable to the rate of growth observed in suburban areas (6.9 percent). However, suburbs still added nearly twice as many total positions and maintain the preponderance of all metropolitan jobs Over the study period, inner city areas grew faster than non-metropolitan areas (2.3 percent) and CBDs, which declined by 1.6 percent. As indicated in Table 1 below, the post-Great Recession period (2009-2011) was particularly favorable to inner cities as its growth rate actually surpassed the suburban rate (3.6 versus 3.0) and nearly 1 in 3 jobs created during this period was located in the inner city. While the more economically distressed parts of inner cities, as identified by the Porter definition, experienced slower employment growth over the full period from 2002-2011, they almost kept pace with the rest of the inner city and did keep pace with the suburbs during the post-recession period, showing employment growth of 3%. [TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE] Given some concern in the literature that the “comeback cities” narrative is limited primarily to only a select set of coastal cities such as New York, Washington, and San Francisco, we examined the same employment trends in each of the nine census divisions across the country (see Figure 2a and 2b). Looking at the full period, this observation holds somewhat. Although inner city growth was positive in all divisions except the East North Central (which declined as a whole), it outpaced suburban areas in only the Mid Atlantic (which includes New York) and the Pacific census divisions. [FIGURE 2 ABOUT HERE] In the post-recession period however, inner cities were considerably more competitive vis-à-vis the suburbs throughout the country, growing faster in five out of nine divisions and rebounding strongly 14 even in the rust-belt East North Central area. In this chart (Figure 2b) the outlier region seems to be West South Central where suburban job growth consistently swamped both CBD and inner city areas. Although this is a relatively small period, the post-recession evidence is indicative of a relatively urbanbased recovery. While total employment increased within inner-city tracts in aggregate, there have been significant industrial shifts occurring within inner cities as they continue to transition away from goods producing sectors and towards relatively place-bound service sector industries. In Figure 3 we analyze net employment change for the full period (2002-11) and the post-recession period for all of the tracts defined as inner city for the U.S. as a whole. Not surprisingly, the greatest losses occurred in manufacturing (-782,000 jobs), followed by construction (-224,000), which was particularly hard hit by the housing crisis and recession. The strongest gaining industries were the so-called “eds and meds” sectors of Health Care and Social Assistance and Educational Services, which added 1.1 million and 633,000 jobs respectively. This finding makes sense since many institutions such as universities and hospitals were founded in the past century in inner-city neighborhoods, have remained in those neighborhoods, and have proved resilient to the wider economic changes that affected the inner city during the 1970s and 1980s. The economic role of universities and their expanding hospitals is critical in areas like West Philadelphia (home to the University of Pennsylvania and Drexel University) and Hyde Park (home to the University of Chicago). Inner city areas also saw strong growth in the Accommodation and Food Services (323,000) sector which includes restaurants and is consistent with the findings in the gentrification literatures on the changing economic role of inner cities from spaces of production to spaces of consumption. [FIGURE 3 ABOUT HERE] 15 Since our definition of inner city is quite broad, including all non-CBD portions of the largest principal city in each MSA, we also sought to understand if the net positive employment growth was limited to areas that were initially higher income enclaves within the city. To test this, we categorized each census tract by its poverty status in 2000. Since much of the literature in the 1990s focused on high poverty neighborhoods and declining employment therein, we also included the tract poverty status in 1990. [TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE] As Table 2 indicates, the large majority of inner city job creation occurred in areas where less than 20 percent of residents earned incomes below the poverty line (79% for 1990 and 73% for 2000). In addition, lower poverty areas maintained a much larger share of total jobs (by a factor of two) compared to high poverty tracts. What is interesting about this tabulation is that the figures for highpoverty tracts are positive at all, given all the preceding discussion of job flight and neighborhood decline. Most interestingly is the fact that, while they only have a small share of total jobs, the growth rate of tracts with extreme poverty (over 40 percent) was the faster than low-poverty tracts. 4.2 Inner city competitiveness at the metropolitan scale The decade of the 2000s was significant in the long term economic trajectory of inner cities over the past 40 years because it marked a reversal of the trend of large-scale job losses and decline. But does this necessarily mean that inner cities are now more competitive locations for business expansion and job growth compared to suburban areas? We revisit the question of inner city competitiveness by exploring the nature of inner city job growth in nearly all metropolitan areas in the U.S. and attempting to determine the extent of inner city competitiveness and the regional factors that influence the growing competitiveness of inner cities in certain MSAs. 16 However, the uneven pattern of metropolitan growth itself clearly plays a role for the prospects of inner city change. In general, larger MSAs experienced larger total employment growth over the study period. Places like San Antonio, TX and Los Angeles, CA experienced substantive growth in metropolitan employment change and also experienced significant growth in inner city employment. However, metropolitan area growth does not always coincide with employment growth in the inner city. For example, in places like Houston and Dallas, TX while the inner city employment growth is positive, suburban growth overshadows the inner city. Therefore, we wanted to develop a method of defining inner city competitiveness that accounted for overall metropolitan growth and identified MSAs where job growth was disproportionately focused on the inner city during the 2000s. [FIGURE 4 ABOUT HERE] To identify which inner cities are competitive over our study period, we examined the relative change in the proportion of inner city employment within its metropolitan area (see Figure 4). Within each quadrant we plot the 2002 inner city share and 2011 inner city share of total metropolitan area employment. We then divide the whole data set into four groups based on whether or not total employment in the metropolitan area grew or declined (horizontal axis) and whether there was net positive inner city job growth or not (vertical axis). While there are a few inner cities that have grown despite the overall metropolitan area decline (SE quadrant), the vast majority of observations with positive inner city employment growth also had positive regional growth. However, since we are interesting in “competitive” inner cities, we focus on those metropolitan areas where inner cities increased their share of jobs. These metros are above the 45° line in the bottom right corner of Figure 4. Specifically, we find that 120 out of a total set of 281 metropolitan areas (43 percent) have “competitive inner cities.” We label these metros as competitive inner cities and compare their characteristics with the other metropolitan areas in the sample. A complete list of these metropolitan 17 areas is provided in Appendix A. The metropolitan areas that are on this list are quite diverse ranging from large metros to more moderate size ones. In general, the change in the share of employment in the inner city is modest between 2002 and 2011, except in a few metropolitan areas. Next, we compared these metropolitan areas with competitive inner cities to the rest of the metros in the sample (see Figure 5). There is no difference between proportions of jobs in the concentrated employment sub-centers between the two groups (as defined using McMillen 2003’s method). However, high wage job growth both at the metro level and within the inner city stand out. Competitive inner cities, in general, have experienced significant high wage job growth. Further research is needed to address the question of whether this high wage job growth is a cause or an effect of “competitiveness”. [FIGURE 5 ABOUT HERE] Metropolitan areas that have a lower black-white dissimilarity index—an indicator of segregation at the metro-level—are more likely to have a competitive inner city. This is consistent with the work of Pastor (Pastor, Drier, & al., 2000) and others who argue that regions where segregation is less pronounced are more likely to produced balanced economic growth. We find that metros with competitive inner cities have lower average black-white dissimilarity indices in 2000s compared to their peers. However, the two groups have the similar distribution of dissimilarity indices with the foreign born and native born, suggesting smaller influence of cross-national migration on competitive inner cities. Competitive inner city metropolitan areas had higher poverty rates in 2000, suggesting higher poverty rates are not a constraint for economic development. There are only small differences in the means of the median household income between the two groups. However, the means tell only part of the story. The distributions are quite different. The median income distribution of the competitive 18 metropolitan areas is skewed to the left compared to the rest of the metros. Furthermore, higher poverty rates, especially in inner cities might suggest redevelopment opportunities. Metropolitan areas with competitive inner cities, on average, have higher average job accessibility. Accessibility is measured at the block group level as the percentage of the jobs in the metro that can be accessed within a 45 minute commute. This difference disappears when we compare the average block group accessibility based on transit service. While we should expect to see higher competitiveness of metros with high quality transit, this result is likely due to persistent low levels of transit provision and usage in the United States. Neither the population distribution, nor the proportion of creative jobs is significantly different in the competitive metropolitan areas from the rest of the metros. The Theil Index of population density represents skewness in the population density distribution. Higher Theil index metropolitan areas are metros with some tracts with large population densities and the rest very low population density, while a lower Theil index means the metropolitan area has relatively uniform population density. The results suggest that concentrations of density are not different between the two groups of the metropolitan areas. We repeated the metropolitan level competitiveness analysis using the narrower Porter definition of inner city tracts. Under this definition, there were fewer MSAs with competitive inner cities (85 compared to 144). We also repeated the difference of means tests described above and include the results in Appendix C. Figure 6 below illustrates the geographic distribution of MSAs with competitive inner cities using both definitions. [FIGURE 6 ABOUT HERE] 19 5. Tract-Level Drivers of Inner City Employment Growth What are the characteristics of inner city neighborhoods that experience employment growth? In this section, we present census tract-level regressions to examine the correlates of employment growth during the 2000s. Our sample consists of the non-CBD census tracts of 106 largest principal cities (within each metropolitan area) which had at least 30 census tracts once the CBD tracts were excluded. We use 2010 census tract boundaries and consider the degree to which changes in log employment from 2002 to 2011 are associated with a number of explanatory variables. [1] ∆empi,c = αc + βd distCBDi,c + βe empi,c + βr resi,c + βl loci,c + βp poli,c + ϵi , where the dependent variable, ∆empi,c represents the change in the log of census tract employment from 2002 to 2011 in tract,i, in city, c. The explanatory variables are, αc , a city fixed effect, distCBDi,c, the log of the distance (in miles) from the centroid of the tract to the centroid of the CBD, empi,c, the log of tract-level employment in 2002, resi,c, a vector of variables describing the residential characteristics of the tract, loci,c, a vector of location factors which measure the accessibility of the tract vis-à-vis the transportation network, poli,c, a vector describing whether certain place-based policies were in effect in the tract, and an error term, ϵi . The vector of residential characteristics, resi,c , includes the log of the tract population in 2000, the change in the log of the sum of the population in all contiguous tracts, the poverty rate in 2000, the change in the share of the population with a college or higher degree, the share of occupied housing units in which the residents moved in between 2000 and 2010, and the share of the housing units that were built between 2000 and 2010. These variables are included to capture both the overall socioeconomic characteristics of the tract itself as well as provide some indicators of gentrification by 20 accounting for recent building activity and recent changes in population around the tract in question. To assess the impact of immigration on job growth we also include a variable that measures the change in the share of the foreign born population between 2000 and 2010. The vector of location factors, loci,c, includes the gross residential density of the tract measured in housing units per acre, an entropy index of the industrial diversity of the tract, a measure of automobile accessibility (the number of automobile-oriented transit road links per square mile), a measure of pedestrian accessibility (the number of pedestrian-oriented road links per square mile), and an indicator of whether the tract contains any public transit stops. The public transit indicator variable is only available for 55 of the 106 cities in our sample. We set this variable equal to negative one for all observations in the cities for which it is missing. Inclusion of city fixed effects ensure that ensure that the estimation of the coefficient on this variable will be due to within-city variation in public transit stop presence in cities for which we do have public transit data. The vector of placed-based policies, poli,c, includes an indicator of whether the tract contains any Low Income Housing Tax Credit developments and an indicator of whether the tract has been designated an Empowerment Zone or Renewal Community.v Appendix B contains a table of descriptive statistics for all independent variables in our regression sample. Table 3 presents our tract-level regression results aimed at revealing some of the correlates of non-CBD inner city employment growth. The table shows four specifications, with an increasing number of explanatory variables. The specification in column (1) includes on the log of the distance from the centroid of the tract to the CBD. The coefficient of 0.066 means that tracts that are twice as far from the CBD have on average 4.6 more log points of employment growth (0.69 * 0.066 = 0.046). The specification in column (2) adds the log of initial year (2002) employment. This variable is added to help mitigate potential measurement error problems in the tract-level employment data. Adding this control 21 reduces the magnitude of the coefficient on the distance to CBD measure. Column (3) adds local demand variables in the form the log of the tracts own initial year population and the change in the log of the population of all of the tracts that share a border with the tract. In this specification, changes in the local area (neighboring tract) population are correlated with tract-level employment growth. The coefficient of 0.535 implies that, on average, a 10 log point increase in neighboring tract population is associated with a 5 log point increase in own-tract employment. [TABLE 3 ABOUT HERE] The specification in column (4) contains our full set of tract-level explanatory variables. The first thing that stands out is that the sign of the coefficient on the log of distance to CBD is now negative and is not statistically different from zero. Conditional on all the other explanatory variables, employment growth is negatively correlated with distance to the CBD. In other words, controlling for other factors, neighborhoods closer to downtown added jobs at a faster rate than those further away, indicating the importance of proximity to the largest concentration of employment in region. The log of initial year (2000) tract population is now positively related to employment growth. The change in the log population of neighboring tracts is still positively related to employment growth but conditional on all the other explanatory variables the coefficient has dropped to about half of its value in column (3). Higher poverty rate tracts are associated with less employment growth. All else equal, 10 percentage points higher poverty rate is associated with 2.4 fewer log points of employment growth. Thus neighborhood poverty still seems to be a deterrent to local employment growth. The coefficient on the change in the share with a college degree is positive but not statistically different from zero. While we would expect that this would be an important variable, given the literature on gentrification and then urban preferences of the creative class, it is likely that the effect of this variable is usurped by the next two variables, which are also indicators of residential changes. 22 Specifically, the share of occupied housing units with residents that moved in during the 2000s (an indicator or recent migration to the area) is positively correlated with employment growth. This higher residential turnover is consistent with urban re-development. Further evidence that employment growth and re-development are correlated comes from the positive coefficient on the share of housing units built during the 2000s. It appears that tracts with 10 percentage points higher share of units built during the 2000s have, on average, 6.6 logs point higher employment growth. Lastly, our measure of immigration is not significant in any specification. This is interesting given the literature on immigrant ethnic enclaves and business growth . While we can’t conclude that immigration does not lead to job growth in some neighborhoods, our analysis suggests that other factors outweigh the impact of recent immigration. The coefficient on residential density is negative, though not statistically significant. This is not surprising as tracts which have mostly residential uses (and thus higher density) have little room left for commercial land-uses and the jobs located therein. Industrial diversity –measured as the 5 category employment entropy index—is positively correlated with employment growth over the period. Automobile accessibility shows a positive correlation with employment growth while pedestrian accessibility is negatively correlated with employment growth. Finally, there is a statistically significant association between the presence of a public transit stop and employment growth. The coefficient implies that tracts containing public transit stops saw roughly 6.7 log-points higher employment growth than those without a public transit stop. There is no clear association between the presence of Low Income Housing Tax Credit developments and employment growth. There is a marginally statistically significant positive relationship between Empowerment Zone / Renewal Community status and employment growth. While we do not consider this strong causal evidence of the effectiveness of EZ/RC policies, it is consistent with 23 the findings of recent research (Busso, Gregory, & Kline, 2010) . On average, tracts in these programs saw about 5.3 log-points higher employment growth than other inner city tracts. The specification in column (4) has an R-squared of 0.23, meaning that our full set of explanatory variables can explain about a quarter of the variation in tract-level employment growth. In specifications without the city fixed effect (not shown) the R-squared drops to 0.19 and without the log of initial year employment it drops to 0.12. The R-squared drops slightly in our model using the narrower, Porter inner-city definition (0.21) shown in column 5. Column (5) presents estimates of the same specification as column (4), but the sample is limited to the set of economically distressed inner-city tracts which meet the Porter definition of having a median household income lower than 80% of that of the MSA and an unemployment rate greater than 1.25 times the MSA average in 2000. Most of the estimates in column (5) are similar to those shown in column (4) for the broadly defined sample of inner city tracts. There are 6 main differences. First, we observe an increased conditional correlation between employment growth and proximity to the CBD; the coefficient roughly doubles in magnitude. Second, there is an increased conditional correlation between year 2000 population. Third, we see a decreased conditional correlation with the poverty rate. This makes sense as there is less variation in poverty rates across the tracts in the Porter definition as it selects on lower income status. This means that among these distressed tracts, variation in the poverty rate is less predictive of employment growth than among the full sample. Forth, there is less of a conditional correlation between the change in the share of occupied housing with new residents; possibly indicating less of an association between gentrification and employment growth among distressed tracts. Fifth, the relationship between pedestrian accessibility and employment growth appears to be slightly more negative. Sixth, we observe an increased conditional correlation between employment growth and Empowerment Zone / Renewal Community status. Thus, among distressed 24 tracts, EZ/EC status is associated with 8.4 log points higher employment growth than other distressed inner city tracts. 6. Conclusion For America’s inner cities as a whole, the decade of the 2000s stands in stark relief compared to the 1980s and 1990s in terms of job growth. Using a dataset that was unavailable in the past (LODES), we show that inner city tracts (those in the non-CBD portions of the large central cities) added 1.8 million jobs between 2002 and 2011. This trend is not just limited to a few cities and regions, as inner city growth was positive in nearly all census divisions and even outpaced suburban growth rates in some areas. The post-recession period has been even stronger for inner cities. While the overall national trend is encouraging given the scale of job losses in previous decades, this growth is probably not enough to declare a “renaissance” in urban America. When we compare job growth between all inner-city tracts and only those inner cities tracts that exhibited higher levels of economic distress (i.e. Porter’s method), some interesting facts emerge. First, the positive growth trend is still evident, put is less pronounced. This means that distressed inner-city areas still face significant barriers, compared to similarly located, but less distressed urban neighborhoods. As our tract-level models indicate, these highly distressed areas are less likely to receive the positive effects of gentrification (i.e. increased local service sector jobs) and that the job growth that has occurred in these areas are tied to different drivers (as we discuss below). Turning to the question of competitiveness, regional growth differentials are clearly important, as the literature on city-suburban dependence indicates. It is not surprising that New York City and San Francisco have much higher inner city employment growth as they are located within strong, growing 25 metropolitan areas. However, in places like Dallas and Houston which also grew, suburban employment continues to outpace inner city employment, suggesting important differences in characteristics and policies of the metropolitan areas that result in competitive inner cities. Yet, places known for their suburban dominance such as Los Angeles and San Antonio showed strong inner city resurgence in the last decade. Thus, competitive inner cities emerged in some unlikely places. We find that while competitive inner cities are no longer the exception, they are also not universal. Two fifths (144 out of 281) of the metros studied in this analysis have seen both increases in overall employment as well as share of inner city employment. Much of the growth in these metropolitan areas is driven by growth in the high wage sectors. There are also important differences in the nature of job growth by sector. The inner city resurgence has been led by the so-called “Eds and Meds” of Health Care and Educational Services; at the same time losses in manufacturing and construction jobs continue in the inner city reflecting the twin trends of globalization and suburbanization of manufacturing. Within inner cities, access to physical infrastructure (e.g. proximity to CBD, transit), as well as social infrastructure (e.g. population increases nearby) confer significant advantage for job growth. However, if access to infrastructure is one of the competitive strengths of the inner cities, it is not reflected in the job growth in the sectors that largely depend on infrastructure (such as manufacturing). Instead, the job growth is driven by residentiary sectors such as food services supporting some claims from the gentrification literature that inner city job growth is fueled at least in part by recent residential growth. Yet for distressed inner-city areas, job growth is driven less by local consumption but rather by growth in anchor institutions that make up the “Eds and Meds” sector. However, our findings also indicate that inner city job growth tends to be greater in areas that are relatively less poor. Thus, high poverty neighborhoods still seem to have major barriers that limit 26 more robust employment gains. It is here that there may be a continued role for government intervention. Our finding that tracts designated as either an Empowerment Zone or Renewal Community grew faster, on average, than other tracts suggests that economic development strategies that are targeted to high-poverty areas can play a role. Our results suggest that, overall, inner city areas do have real advantages as locations for employment and are increasingly viewed as an attractive residential location. 27 References Abowd, J. M., Stephens, B. E., Vilhuber, L., Andersson, F., McKinney, K. L., Roemer, M., & Woodcock, S. (2009). The LEHD infrastructure files and the creation of the Quarterly Workforce Indicators Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data (pp. 149-230): University of Chicago Press. Adams, C. (2003). The meds and eds in urban economic development. Journal of Urban Affairs, 25(5), 571-588. Aliprantis, D., Fee, K., & Oliver, N. (2014). Which Poor Neighborhoods Experienced Income Growth in Recent Decades? Cleveland: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Bates, T. (1997). Financing small business creation: the case of Chinese and Korean immigrant entrepreneurs. Journal of business venturing, 12(2), 109-124. Bates, T. (2011). Minority entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 7(3-4). Bivand, R. (2015). Spatial Dependence: Weighting Schemes, Statistics and Models. R package (spdep) (Version version 0.5-81). Retrieved from http://CRAN.R-project.org/package=spdep Busso, M., Gregory, J., & Kline, P. M. (2010). Assessing the incidence and efficiency of a prominent place based policy: National Bureau of Economic Research. Chapple, K. (2006). Connection missed: Revisiting the spatial mismatch hypothesis in the new metropolitan reality. Journal of the American Planning Association, forthcoming. Clark, J. (2013). Working Regions: Reconnecting Innovation and Production in the Knowledge Economy: Routledge. Cortright, J., & Mahmoudi, D. (2014). Neighborhood Change, 1970 to 2010: Transition and Growth in Urban High Poverty Neighborhoods (pp. 22). Portland, OR: Impresa Economics. Csardi, G., & Nepusz, T. (2006). The igraph software package for complex network research. InterJournal, Complex Systems, 1695. Curran, W. (2004). Gentrification and the nature of work: exploring the links in Williamsburg, Brooklyn. Environment and planning.A, 36(Journal Article), 1243. doi: pmid: Curran, W. (2007). 'From the Frying Pan to the Oven': Gentrification and the Experience of Industrial Displacement in Williamsburg, Brooklyn. Urban Studies, 44(8), 1427-1440. doi: 10.1080/00420980701373438 Fee, K., & Hartley, D. (2011). Urban Growth and Decline: The Role of Population Density at the City Core. Florida, R. (2003). Cities and the Creative Class. City & Community, 2(1), 3-19. doi: 10.1111/15406040.00034 Florida, R. L. (2002). The rise of the creative class : and how it's transforming work, leisure, community and everyday life. New York, NY: Basic Books. Freeman, L. (2005). Displacement or Succession? Urban Affairs Review, 40(4), 463-491. doi: 10.1177/1078087404273341 Galster, G. C., & Killen, S. P. (1995). The geography of metropolitan opportunity: a reconnaissance and conceptual framework. Housing Policy Debate, 6(1), 7-43. Garcia-López, M.-À. (2010). Population suburbanization in Barcelona, 1991–2005: Is its spatial structure changing? Journal of Housing Economics, 19(2), 119-132. Graham, M. R., Kutzbach, M. J., & McKenzie, B. (2014). Design Comparison Of Lodes And Acs Commuting Data Products. Harkavy, I. R., & Zuckerman, H. (1999). Eds and meds: Cities' hidden assets: Brookings Institution, Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy. Hill, E. W., Wolman, H. L., & Ford, C. C. (1995). Can suburbs survive without their central cities? Examining the suburban dependence hypothesis. Urban Affairs Review, 31(2), 147-174. 28 Hutton, T. A. (2004). The new economy of the inner city. Cities, 21(2), 89-108. Ihlanfeldt, K., & Sjoquist, D. (1989). The impact of job decentralization on the economic welfare of central-city blacks. Journal of Urban Economics, 26, 110-130 . Kain, J. (1968). Housing segregation, Negro employment, and metropolitan decentralization. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82(2), 175–197 Kasarda, J. D. (1993). Inner‐city concentrated poverty and neighborhood distress: 1970 to 1990. Housing Policy Debate, 4(3), 253-302. Katz, M. B. (1993). The" underclass" debate: Views from history: Princeton University Press. Ledebur, L. C., & Barnes, W. R. (1993). "All in it Together": Cities, Suburbs, and Local Economic Regions. Resarch Report on America's Cities. Washington D.C.: National League of Cities. Lester, T. W., & Hartley, D. A. (2014). The long term employment impacts of gentrification in the 1990s. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 45(0), 80-89. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2014.01.003 Ley, D. (1996). The new middle class and the remaking of the central city Oxford University Press: Oxford. Lloyd, R., & Clark, T. N. (2001). The city as an entertainment machine. In K. Fox Gotham (Ed.), Critical Perspectives on Urban Redevelopment (pp. 357-378): Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Marcuse, P. (1985). Gentrification, abandonment, and displacement: Connections, causes, and policy responses in New York City. Washington University journal of urban and contemporary law, 28(Journal Article), 195. doi: pmid: McMillen, D. P. (2001). Nonparametric employment subcenter identification. Journal of Urban Economics, 50(3), 448-473. McMillen, D. P. (2003). Identifying sub-centres using contiguity matrices. Urban Studies, 40(1), 57-69. Meltzer, R., & Schuetz, J. (2012). Bodegas or Bagel Shops? Neighborhood Differences in Retail and Household Services. Economic Development Quarterly, 26(1), 73-94. doi: 10.1177/0891242411430328 Moretti, E. (2012). The New Geography of Jobs. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt. Owen, A., & Levinson, D. M. (2015). Modeling the commute mode share of transit using continuous accessibility to jobs. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 74, 110-122. Pack, J. R. (2002). Growth and convergence in metropolitan America. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press. Pastor, M., Drier, P., & al., e. (2000). Regions that Work: How Cities and Suburbs Can Grow Together. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota. Pastor, M., Lester, T. W., & Scoggins, J. (2009). WHY REGIONS? WHY NOW? WHO CARES? Journal of Urban Affairs, 31(3), 269-296. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9906.2009.00460.x Portes, A., & Zhou, M. (1992). Gaining the upper hand: Economic mobility among immigrant and domestic minorities. Ethnic and racial studies, 15(4), 491-522. Sampson, R. J. (2008). Rethinking crime and immigration. Contexts, 7(1), 28-33. Saxenian, A. (1994). Regional advantage : culture and competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Schleith, D., & Horner, M. (2014). Commuting, Job Clusters, and Travel Burdens: Analysis of Spatially and Socioeconomically Disaggregated Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics Data. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board(2452), 19-27. Smith, N. (1996). The New Urban Frontier: Gentrification and the Revanchist City. London: Routledge. Smith, N. (2002). New Globalism, New Urbanism: Gentrification as Global Urban Strategy. Antipode, 34(3), 427-450. doi: 10.1111/1467-8330.00249 Sohmer, R. R., & Lang, R. E. (2001). Downtown rebound. Redefining Urban and Suburban America: Evidence From Census 2000, 1, 63-74. 29 Storper, M. (1997). The Regional World: Territorial Development in a Global Economy. New York: Guilford. Suárez, M., & Delgado, J. (2009). Is Mexico City Polycentric? A trip attraction capacity approach. Urban Studies, 46(10), 2187-2211. Teitz, M., & Chapple, K. (1998). The causes of inner-city poverty: Eight hypotheses in search of reality. Citiscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research, 3(3), 33-70. Vigdor, J. L. (2002). Does Gentrification Harm the Poor? [with Comments]. Brookings-Wharton papers on urban affairs(ArticleType: research-article / Full publication date: 2002 / Copyright © 2002 Brookings Institution Press), 133-182. Voith, R. (1992 ). City and Suburban Growth: Substitutes or Compliments. Business Review- Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, September-October, 21-33. Voith, R. (1998). Do suburbs need cities? Journal of Regional Science, 38(3), 445-464. Wilson, W. J. (1987). The truly disadvantaged : the inner city, the underclass, and public policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Wilson, W. J. (1996). When work disappears : the world of the new urban poor (1st ed.). New York: Knopf : Distributed by Random House, Inc. Wyly, E. K., & Hammel, D. J. (1999). Islands of decay in seas of renewal: Housing policy and the resurgence of gentrification. Housing Policy Debate, 10(4), 711-771. doi: 10.1080/10511482.1999.9521348 Zukin, S. (1982). Loft living : culture and capital in urban change. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. 30 Tables and Figures Table 1. Employment Change in CBD, Inner City, Suburban and Non-metro tracts, 2002-11. Year Total Employment 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 CBD 9,806,579 9,466,413 9,368,606 9,391,107 9,502,148 9,462,838 9,422,301 9,405,450 9,599,146 9,654,338 Inner City 29,699,043 29,406,696 29,688,362 30,143,171 30,512,600 31,030,945 31,082,578 30,425,117 30,796,523 31,521,499 Inner CityPorter 9,163,969 8,959,707 9,040,566 9,140,514 9,137,376 9,279,914 9,181,937 9,025,946 9,175,827 9,292,356 Suburban 59,207,009 59,122,731 60,114,666 61,722,807 62,976,328 64,129,684 64,323,119 61,460,391 61,733,541 63,296,946 Non-Metro 15,401,902 15,351,324 15,481,987 15,711,700 15,969,935 16,113,194 16,120,592 15,426,231 15,466,790 15,758,332 Net Employment (152,241) 1,822,456 128,387 4,089,937 356,430 Change (2002-11) % Change -1.6% 6.1% 1.4% 6.9% 2.3% Post-Recession Net 248,888 1,096,382 266,410 1,836,555 332,101 Change (2009-11) % Change 2.6% 3.6% 3.0% 3.0% 2.2% Share of US Emp., 2002 8.6% 26.0% 8.0% 18.4% 51.9% Share of US Emp., 2011 8.0% 26.2% 7.7% 18.2% 52.6% Note: Authors analysis of LODES data by tract-type for states with full sample (2002-11). 31 Total 114,114,533 113,347,164 114,653,621 116,968,785 118,961,011 120,736,661 120,948,590 116,717,189 117,596,000 120,231,115 6,116,582 5.4% 3,513,926 3.0% Table 2. Inner city Employment Change by Tract Poverty Status Employment Measure Total Employment, 2002 % of Inner City Jobs, 2011 Total Employment, 2009 % of Inner City Jobs, 2011 Total Employment, 2011 % of Inner City Jobs, 2011 Net Employment Change (2002-11) % Change Net Employment Change (2009-11) % Change Tract Poverty Status, 1990 Low Poverty High Extreme (<20%) Poverty Poverty (>20%) (>40%) 19,843,121 9,855,922 2,879,470 66.8% 33.2% 9.7% 20,581,454 9,843,663 2,936,604 67.6% 32.4% 9.7% 21,296,609 10,224,890 3,183,065 67.6% 32.4% 10.1% Tract Poverty Status, 2000 Low High Extreme Poverty Poverty Poverty (<20%) >20% (>40%) 19,779,094 9,919,949 2,177,597 66.6% 33.4% 7.3% 20,440,333 9,984,784 2,206,598 67.2% 32.8% 7.3% 21,116,880 10,404,619 2,352,930 67.0% 33.0% 7.5% 1,453,488 368,968 303,595 1,337,786 484,670 175,333 7.3% 715,155 3.7% 381,227 10.5% 246,461 6.8% 676,547 4.9% 419,835 8.1% 146,332 3.5% 3.9% 8.4% 3.3% 4.2% 6.6% Source: Authors analysis of Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) data, 2002-2011. 32 Table 3: OLS Regression Results: Predictors of Tract-level Employment Growth, 2002-2011. (1) Variable log Distance to CBD (2) (3) (4) 0.066*** 0.037*** 0.006 0.029*** -0.062*** (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.012) (0.020) -0.152*** -0.15*** 0.202*** -0.223*** (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.013) log Employment 2002 log Population 2000 Change in log pop in neighboring tracts, 2000-2010 0.076 (0.014) (0.014) 0.535 *** (0.045) Poverty Rate, 2000 0.257 Change in Share with College Degree, 2000-2010 Share of occupied housing with new residents, 20002010 Share of housing units built between 2000 and 2010 Residential density (Units/Acre) Industrial diversity index (5 category entropy index) Pedestrian Accessibility (links per square mile) Public transit dummy (y/n) Empowerment Zone/Renewal Community (y/n) R N 33 0.291*** (0.086) -0.087 (0.107) (0.169) *** -0.089 (0.072) (0.128) 0.105 0.165 (0.099) (0.184) 0.247*** 0.091 (0.065) (0.112) 0.661*** 0.593*** (0.066) (0.156) -0.001 -0.001 (0.001) (0.001) *** 0.515*** (0.035) (0.061) 0.010*** 0.011*** (0.003) (0.004) 0.008*** -0.014*** (0.002) (0.003) 0.067 Low Income Housing Tax Credit Development (y/n) (0.031) -0.025 0.464 Automobile Accessibility (links per square mile) *** 0.18*** (0.042) -0.24 2 *** -0.007 Change in Share Foreign Born, 2000-2010 Tract Sample Definition: (5) * 0.149 (0.041) (0.152) 0.008 0.006 (0.014) (0.022) 0.053* 0.084** (0.031) (0.038) Broad Broad Broad Broad Porter 0.0753 0.1648 0.1864 11,837 11,837 11,837 0.2309 11837 0.2162 4518 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses below estimate. *Significant at 10%. **Significant at 5%. ***Significant at 1%. Figure 1. Delineation of Inner City Status in the Cleveland, MSA 34 Figure 2. Employment Change by Tract-Type and Census Division, Full Period and Post-Recession Employment Growth (2002-2011) 30.0% 25.0% 20.0% 15.0% 10.0% 5.0% CBD 0.0% Inner City Suburban -5.0% -10.0% Census Division 7.0% Employment Growth, 2009-2011 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% CBD 0.0% Inner-city -1.0% Suburban -2.0% -3.0% Census Division 35 Figure 3. Inner-City Employment change by Major Industry Sector (NAICS)- Full Period (2002-11) and Post Recession (2009-11). Net Employment Change (1,000,000) (500,000) - 500,000 1,000,000 1,500,000 Health Care and Social Assistance (62) Educational Srvs. (61) Accommodation and Food Srvs. (72) Professional and Technical Srvs. (54) Public Administration (92) Finance and Insurance (52) Other Services (81) Management of Companies and Ent. (55) Administrative and Support Srvs. (56) Arts, Entertainment, and Recreation (71) Full Period (2002-11) Mining and Extraction (21) Transportation and Warehousing (48-49) Post-Recession (2009-11) Agriculture (11) Utilities (22) Real Estate and Rental and Leasing (53) Retail Trade (44-45) Information (51) Wholesale Trade (42) Construction (23) Manufacturing (31-33) Source: Authors analysis of Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) data, 2002-2011. 36 Source: Authors analysis of Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) data, 2002-2011. Figure 4. Defining Inner City Competitiveness: MSA Employment Change and the Change in Inner city proportion of employment in 2002 and 2011. Source: Authors analysis of Local Origin-Destination Employment Statistics (LODES) data, 2002-2011. 37 Figure 5. Characteristics of Metropolitan Regions with Competitive Inner Cities (Broad Definition) Versus All other Metros 38 Notes: Figure presents the difference in distribution of various indicators for metropolitan areas with competitive inner cities and to the distribution for all other metropolitan areas. Sources: LODES (panel 1-3); Building Resilient Regions (BRR) Database (panels 4-8); EPA Smart Location Database (Panels 9-11). All variables calculated at the metropolitan (CBSA) level. N=281. Figure 6. Regions with Competitive Inner Cities using different definitions 39 A. Appendix: List of Regions with Competitive Inner Cities Share of Employment in the Inner City (Broad) Share of Employment in the Inner City (Porter) CBSA Name 2002 Competitive Inner City Regions in Both Definitions Ames, IA Athens-Clarke County, GA Blacksburg-Christiansburg-Radford, VA Morgantown, WV Lawrence, KS Columbia, MO Jackson, TN Bowling Green, KY Jackson, MI Chattanooga, TN-GA Springfield, IL Springfield, OH Atlantic City, NJ Sumter, SC Anchorage, AK New Haven-Milford, CT Salinas, CA Lexington-Fayette, KY New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-PA 2011 Difference in Shares 2002 2011 Difference in Shares 0.034 0.084 0.011 0.085 0.045 0.168 0.036 0.140 0.069 0.185 0.167 0.126 0.057 0.039 0.335 0.086 0.027 0.142 0.221 0.248 0.160 0.212 0.067 0.173 0.047 0.185 0.136 0.224 0.189 0.173 0.080 0.046 0.347 0.090 0.064 0.203 0.186 0.164 0.149 0.127 0.022 0.005 0.011 0.045 0.067 0.039 0.022 0.047 0.024 0.007 0.012 0.004 0.037 0.061 0.109 0.569 0.063 0.145 0.468 0.492 0.573 0.629 0.210 0.523 0.473 0.392 0.077 0.220 0.807 0.104 0.101 0.614 0.305 0.726 0.213 0.273 0.593 0.602 0.681 0.698 0.274 0.580 0.529 0.448 0.133 0.275 0.860 0.156 0.142 0.652 0.196 0.156 0.150 0.128 0.125 0.111 0.108 0.069 0.064 0.057 0.056 0.056 0.056 0.055 0.053 0.052 0.041 0.038 0.074 0.084 0.010 0.368 0.403 0.035 Sacramento--Arden-Arcade--Roseville, CA Oshkosh-Neenah, WI Longview, WA Bakersfield, CA Gadsden, AL Florence, SC Salem, OR Corvallis, OR Merced, CA Cleveland-Elyria-Mentor, OH Myrtle Beach-Conway-North Myrtle Beach, SC Chico, CA Rome, GA Florence-Muscle Shoals, AL San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, CA Auburn-Opelika, AL Parkersburg-Marietta, WV-OH Durham, NC Utica-Rome, NY Oxnard-Thousand Oaks-Ventura, CA Spartanburg, SC Rochester, MN Duluth, MN-WI Longview, TX Palm Bay-Melbourne-Titusville, FL Los Angeles-Long Beach-Santa Ana, CA Fort Collins-Loveland, CO Abilene, TX Valdosta, GA Columbus, GA-AL 0.082 0.067 0.012 0.052 0.180 0.017 0.272 0.211 0.064 0.099 0.100 0.147 0.015 0.052 0.198 0.021 0.286 0.223 0.085 0.126 0.018 0.080 0.003 0.001 0.018 0.004 0.014 0.012 0.021 0.027 0.195 0.291 0.048 0.316 0.380 0.095 0.364 0.373 0.177 0.146 0.229 0.325 0.082 0.348 0.411 0.125 0.393 0.401 0.203 0.171 0.035 0.034 0.033 0.033 0.031 0.030 0.029 0.028 0.026 0.025 0.088 0.001 0.050 0.021 0.107 0.121 0.021 0.123 0.091 0.028 0.026 0.051 0.008 0.070 0.107 0.061 0.030 0.113 0.097 0.120 0.091 0.001 0.057 0.021 0.120 0.132 0.047 0.169 0.107 0.036 0.044 0.052 0.010 0.093 0.127 0.067 0.037 0.122 0.120 0.125 0.003 0.000 0.007 0.000 0.013 0.011 0.026 0.046 0.016 0.008 0.018 0.001 0.002 0.023 0.020 0.006 0.006 0.009 0.023 0.005 0.320 0.165 0.253 0.323 0.371 0.294 0.167 0.396 0.213 0.314 0.095 0.498 0.275 0.294 0.304 0.231 0.339 0.583 0.343 0.642 0.344 0.188 0.276 0.345 0.392 0.314 0.187 0.414 0.231 0.332 0.111 0.513 0.290 0.308 0.318 0.244 0.352 0.594 0.353 0.652 0.024 0.023 0.023 0.022 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.019 0.018 0.018 0.016 0.015 0.015 0.014 0.014 0.013 0.012 0.011 0.010 0.010 42 Lakeland, FL Pittsburgh, PA Fayetteville, NC State College, PA Fairbanks, AK Las Cruces, NM Asheville, NC Monroe, LA Scranton--Wilkes-Barre, PA Charleston-North Charleston, SC Philadelphia-Camden-Wilmington, PA-NJDE-MD San Diego-Carlsbad-San Marcos, CA 0.030 0.046 0.075 0.041 0.142 0.038 0.070 0.069 0.009 0.034 0.051 0.057 0.084 0.049 0.155 0.039 0.073 0.082 0.012 0.035 0.021 0.011 0.010 0.009 0.014 0.001 0.002 0.013 0.004 0.001 0.197 0.107 0.624 0.098 0.224 0.368 0.289 0.155 0.090 0.165 0.206 0.115 0.632 0.104 0.230 0.374 0.295 0.159 0.094 0.168 0.009 0.008 0.008 0.007 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.004 0.004 0.002 0.070 0.079 0.070 0.089 0.000 0.010 0.142 0.500 0.143 0.501 0.001 0.000 Additional Competitive Inner City Regions (Using Porter Definition) Albany-Schenectady-Troy, NY 0.077 Alexandria, LA 0.043 Altoona, PA 0.045 Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Marietta, GA 0.037 Bloomington, IN 0.052 Bremerton-Silverdale, WA 0.039 Cumberland, MD-WV 0.021 Grand Forks, ND-MN 0.062 Grand Rapids-Wyoming, MI 0.059 Greenville, NC 0.062 Harrisonburg, VA 0.057 Honolulu, HI 0.167 Kalamazoo-Portage, MI 0.056 Killeen-Temple-Fort Hood, TX 0.056 Lancaster, PA 0.032 0.094 0.046 0.054 0.039 0.054 0.039 0.022 0.070 0.069 0.063 0.122 0.170 0.091 0.131 0.037 0.017 0.002 0.009 0.002 0.002 0.000 0.001 0.008 0.010 0.000 0.065 0.002 0.035 0.075 0.005 0.252 0.271 0.370 0.107 0.276 0.153 0.206 0.432 0.206 0.409 0.515 0.585 0.361 0.599 0.117 0.247 0.270 0.309 0.106 0.267 0.133 0.190 0.427 0.195 0.405 0.445 0.554 0.329 0.585 0.116 -0.005 -0.001 -0.061 -0.001 -0.009 -0.019 -0.016 -0.005 -0.011 -0.004 -0.070 -0.032 -0.032 -0.014 -0.001 43 Lubbock, TX Madison, WI Norwich-New London, CT Ocala, FL Ogden-Clearfield, UT Pueblo, CO Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Goleta, CA Visalia-Porterville, CA Waco, TX 0.245 0.174 0.025 0.013 0.038 0.157 0.035 0.004 0.122 Additional Competitive Inner City Regions (Using Broad Definition) Albuquerque, NM 0.223 Ann Arbor, MI 0.269 Appleton, WI NA Bellingham, WA 0.052 Bend, OR NA Bismarck, ND NA Bloomington-Normal, IL NA Brownsville-Harlingen, TX 0.076 Cape Coral-Fort Myers, FL NA Clarksville, TN-KY 0.085 College Station-Bryan, TX 0.015 Colorado Springs, CO 0.177 Columbia, SC 0.033 Corpus Christi, TX 0.212 Davenport-Moline-Rock Island, IA-IL 0.093 Dubuque, IA 0.025 Glens Falls, NY NA Goldsboro, NC 0.161 Jacksonville, FL 0.178 0.250 0.220 0.028 0.016 0.049 0.186 0.035 0.006 0.143 0.006 0.047 0.002 0.003 0.011 0.029 0.001 0.002 0.021 0.782 0.572 0.122 0.293 0.106 0.484 0.430 0.256 0.463 0.775 0.522 0.121 0.284 0.098 0.450 0.424 0.251 0.420 -0.008 -0.050 -0.001 -0.009 -0.008 -0.034 -0.007 -0.005 -0.043 0.158 0.152 -0.065 -0.118 0.732 0.483 0.250 0.321 0.287 0.300 0.512 0.413 0.086 0.359 0.183 0.697 0.182 0.580 0.304 0.445 0.046 0.407 0.628 0.734 0.542 0.340 0.338 0.316 0.373 0.527 0.439 0.090 0.419 0.226 0.698 0.190 0.605 0.323 0.466 0.105 0.441 0.637 0.002 0.059 0.090 0.017 0.029 0.074 0.015 0.026 0.004 0.061 0.043 0.001 0.008 0.025 0.019 0.021 0.058 0.034 0.009 NA NA 0.045 NA NA NA -0.007 NA NA NA 0.075 NA -0.002 NA 0.085 0.013 0.137 0.030 0.208 0.085 0.021 NA 0.000 -0.002 -0.040 -0.003 -0.005 -0.009 -0.004 NA 0.149 0.155 44 -0.012 -0.023 Johnson City, TN Joplin, MO Kokomo, IN Lafayette, IN Lake Charles, LA Laredo, TX Las Vegas-Paradise, NV Logan, UT-ID Louisville, KY-IN Modesto, CA Morristown, TN Niles-Benton Harbor, MI Ocean City, NJ Oklahoma City, OK Orlando, FL Palm Coast, FL Pocatello, ID Portland-South Portland-Biddeford, ME Portland-Vancouver-Beaverton, OR-WA Port St. Lucie, FL Providence-New Bedford-Fall River, RI-MA Punta Gorda, FL Redding, CA Reno-Sparks, NV Saginaw-Saginaw Township North, MI St. Cloud, MN Salt Lake City, UT San Antonio, TX San Francisco-Oakland-Fremont, CA Spokane, WA Springfield, MO NA NA NA NA 0.060 0.058 0.030 0.135 0.076 0.086 0.165 0.021 NA NA NA NA NA 0.079 0.048 0.021 0.118 0.066 0.086 0.151 0.021 NA NA NA 0.209 0.046 NA NA NA NA NA 0.200 0.043 NA NA 0.015 0.067 NA NA NA NA -0.002 -0.001 NA 0.058 NA NA 0.134 0.113 0.154 0.120 0.147 0.059 0.071 0.103 -0.009 -0.003 0.013 0.066 0.058 NA NA 0.019 -0.010 -0.009 -0.017 -0.010 0.000 -0.014 -0.001 0.000 NA NA 0.116 0.104 0.152 0.116 0.134 0.059 0.059 0.092 45 -0.018 -0.009 -0.002 -0.004 -0.013 -0.001 -0.012 -0.012 0.338 0.122 0.265 0.416 0.277 0.674 0.231 0.249 0.413 0.289 0.077 0.014 0.028 0.567 0.161 0.392 0.530 0.148 0.260 0.159 0.128 0.069 0.562 0.449 0.199 0.361 0.302 0.650 0.179 0.235 0.637 0.405 0.162 0.386 0.449 0.315 0.716 0.250 0.319 0.421 0.293 0.078 0.020 0.061 0.576 0.163 0.628 0.537 0.150 0.272 0.210 0.136 0.088 0.593 0.468 0.230 0.394 0.304 0.690 0.198 0.240 0.641 0.066 0.040 0.121 0.033 0.038 0.042 0.018 0.070 0.008 0.003 0.002 0.006 0.033 0.009 0.002 0.236 0.007 0.001 0.012 0.050 0.008 0.019 0.031 0.019 0.031 0.032 0.002 0.040 0.019 0.005 0.005 Tuscaloosa, AL Tyler, TX Vineland-Millville-Bridgeton, NJ Warner Robins, GA Wenatchee, WA Wilmington, NC Winston-Salem, NC Yakima, WA Yuba City, CA 0.202 0.064 NA 0.188 0.063 NA 0.065 NA NA 0.063 NA 0.106 0.105 0.051 0.044 -0.014 -0.002 -0.002 NA 0.087 0.102 0.048 0.036 46 -0.019 -0.003 -0.004 -0.008 0.446 0.449 0.340 0.240 0.159 0.443 0.600 0.237 0.229 0.459 0.452 0.371 0.269 0.165 0.448 0.612 0.243 0.239 0.013 0.003 0.031 0.030 0.005 0.004 0.012 0.006 0.010 Appendix B. Summary Statistics of Tract-level Data Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev. 0.697 0.760 1.430 0.546 0.221 Min Max Change in log Employment 2002-2011 11,837 0.062 -6.672 5.182 log Distance to CBD 11,837 1.526 -4.560 4.029 log Employment 2002 11,837 6.468 0 11.537 log Population 2000 11,837 8.092 1.609 9.865 Change in log Population of Neighboring Tracts 2000- 11,837 0.033 -1.497 5.093 2010 Poverty Rate 2000 11,837 0.183 0.136 0 0.932 Change in Share with College Degree 2000-2010 11,837 0.032 0.079 -1 0.872 Share of Occupied Housing Units with new Residents 11,837 0.706 0.124 0 1 2000-2010 Share of Housing Units Built 2000-2010 11,837 0.083 0.138 0 1 Residential Density (Units/Acre) 11,837 6.669 9.807 0.000 561.963 Industrial Diversity Index 11,837 0.466 0.242 0 1.000 Automobile Accessibility (links per square mile) 11,837 1.479 2.413 0 36.770 Pedestrian Accessibility (links per square mile) 11,837 16.114 5.946 0.245 46.595 Public Transit Stop in Tract? 8,806 0.914 0 1 Low Income Housing Tax Credit Development in 11,837 0.292 0 1 Tract? Empowerment Zone/Renewal Community? 11,837 0.075 0 1 Note: Summary statistics are presented for inner city census tract sample. These are non-CBD tracts in the largest principal cities for states with a full sample of data (2002-2011) Appendix C. Characteristics of Metropolitan Regions with Competitive Inner Cities (Porter Definition) Versus All other Metros Notes: Figure presents the difference in distribution of various indicators for metropolitan areas with competitive inner cities and to the distribution for all other metropolitan areas. Sources: LODES (panel 1-3); Building Resilient Regions (BRR) Database (panels 4-8); EPA Smart Location Database (Panels 9-11). All variables calculated at the metropolitan (CBSA) level. N=252 48 i Throughout this paper we use the terms region and metropolitan area interchangeably. Specifically Abowd et. al. explain the noise inducing algorithm that the LEHD infrastructure files use as follows: “First, every data item [establishment] is distorted by some minimum amount. Second, for a given workplace, the data are always distorted in the same direction (increased or decreased) by the same percentage amount in every period….Third, the statistical properties of this distortion are such that when the estimates are aggregated, the effects of the distortion cancel out for the vast majority of the estimates, preserving both cross-sectional and time series analytical validity.” (Abowd et. al. 2009, p.184) iii Principal Cities are defined for each MSA by the Census Bureau as the largest city in the MSA. Additional cities may qualify to be a principal city, if it is a census designated place or incorporated place with more than 250,000 residents and 100,000 workers or a place whose employment exceeds the population and both are at least 10,000. iv http://www.epa.gov/smartgrowth/smartlocationdatabase.htm v For the list of tracts that were included in EZ/RCs see http://portal.hud.gov/hudportal/HUD?src=/program_offices/comm_planning/economicdevelopment/programs/. ii 49