BANK OF GREECE
EUROSYSTEM
Working Paper
Diversification, integration and cryptocurrency market
Sofia Anyfantaki
Stelios Arvanitis
Nikolas Topaloglou
PA
244
APRIL 2018
KINGPAPERWORKINGPAPERWORKINGPAPERWORKINGPAPERWORKI
BANK OF GREECE
Economic Analysis and Research Department – Special Studies Division
21, Ε. Venizelos Avenue
GR-102 50 Athens
Τel: +30210-320 3610
Fax: +30210-320 2432
www.bankofgreece.gr
Printed in Athens, Greece
at the Bank of Greece Printing Works.
All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and
non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged.
ISSN 1109-6691
DIVERSIFICATION, INTEGRATION AND
CRYPTOCURRENCY MARKET
Sofia Anyfantaki
Athens University of Economics and Business & Bank of Greece
Stelios Arvanitis
Athens University of Economics and Business
Nikolas Topaloglou
Athens University of Economics and Business
Abstract
We investigate the degree to which cryptocurrencies provide diversification benefits
to an investor. We use a stochastic spanning methodology to construct optimal
portfolios with and without cryptocurrencies, evaluating their comparative
performance both in- and out-of-sample. Empirical analysis seems to indicate that the
expanded investment universe with cryptocurrencies dominates the traditional one
with stocks, bonds and cash, yielding potential diversification benefits and providing
better investment opportunities for some risk averse investors. We further explain our
results by documenting that cryptocurrency markets are segmented from the equity
and bond markets.
JEL classification codes: C12, C14, D81, G11.
Keywords: Cryptocurrencies, Portfolio choice, Second Order Stochastic dominance,
Stochastic Spanning, Diversification, Market Integration, Market Segmentation.
Acknowledgements: The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and
not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Greece or the Eurosystem.
Correspondence:
Sofia Anyfantaki
Economic Analysis & Research Department,
Bank of Greece,
21, El. Venizelos Ave, 10250,
Athens, Greece
e-mail:
[email protected]
1 Introduction
The emergence of cryptocurrencies has drawn significant investment capital in the recent years. The rates of increase in market capitalization, in volumes traded, as well as in
the price of certain cryptocurrencies are exponential, indicating that changes in the cryptocurrency market can occur very rapidly. Bitcoin was the first cryptocurrency to appear
in 2008 and currently has the highest market capitalization. Soon after its appearance
several similar cryptocurrencies (collectively called “altcoins”) started to emerge: Litecoin was launched in 2011 and supports faster transaction confirmation. Additionally,
other applications of the blockchain technology that incorporate a cryptocurrency have
also emerged, the most dominant being Ethereum which was launched in 2015 and currently has the second highest market capitalization. Ethereum is an extended blockchain
application that can record contracts and includes a built-in cryptocurrency called Ether,
which is used to pay for contract execution. Another very interesting cryptocurrency is
Ripple.
A cryptocurrency is produced by cryptographic algorithms. This is then transported
across cyberspace using protocols such as peer-to peer networking. Most of the issues
surrounding the successful adoption of cryptocurrencies are connected to the question
of whether they are digital or virtual currencies, and as such, how their value is determined. Another compelling question is the issue of whether digital currencies should be
considered to be currencies or digital assets. There is a new and emerging literature regarding cryptocurrencies, with most emphasis surrounding Bitcoin and much of the study
has attempted to address the question of whether it is more analogous to a fiat versus
commodity money. For example, Yermack (2015) claims that Bitcoin has no intrinsic
value while lacks additional characteristics that are usually associated with currencies.
Although the role of cryptocurrencies can still be disputed, they are certainly subject of
rising awareness.
One possible explanation for investors’ interest in cryptocurrencies is their alleged diversification benefits. To have significant diversification benefits, the cryptocurrency returns need to have low-positive or negative correlations with the traditional asset classes
like bonds and equities returns. In this paper we revisit this question while our main
contribution is that we construct optimal portfolios and assess their performance in a
non-parametric way. We manage to do so by employing a stochastic dominance (SD)
approach.
The Mean-Variance (M-V) dominance criterion is questionable for portfolio selection,
if investment returns are not normally distributed, or the utility functions are not quadratic.
It is consistent with expected utility for elliptical distributions such as the normal distribution (Chamberlain, 1983; Owen and Rabinovitch, 1983; Berk, 1997) but has limited
3
economic meaning when the probability distribution cannot be characterized completely
by its location and scale. SD presents a further generalization that accounts for all moments of the return distributions without assuming a particular family of distributions. SD
ranks investments based on general regularity conditions for decision making under risk
(Quirk and Saposnik, 1962; Hadar and Russell, 1969; Hanoch and Levy, 1969; Rothschild
and Stiglitz, 1970) and can be seen as a model-free alternative to M-V dominance. SD is
a central theme in a wide variety of applications in economics, finance and statistics (for
overviews and bibliographies see, Levy, 2015; Mosler and Scarsini, 2012) and the concept
is used in numerous empirical studies in finance. Due to its non-parametric attractiveness,
SD is particularly appealing for asset classes and investment strategies with asymmetric risk profiles, for example small-cap stocks, junk bonds, derivatives and momentum
strategies.
SD is traditionally applied for comparing a pair of given prospects, for example, two
income distributions or two medical treatments. Davidson and Duclos (2000), Barrett and
Donald (2003) and Linton et al. (2005), among others, develop statistical tests for such
pairwise comparisons. A more general, multivariate problem is that of testing whether a
given prospect is stochastically efficient relative to all mixtures of a discrete set of alternatives (Bawa et al.,1985; Shalit and Yitzhaki, 1994; Post, 2003; Kuosmanen, 2004; Roman
et al., 2006). This problem arises naturally in applications of portfolio theory and asset
pricing theory, where the mixtures are portfolios of financial securities. Post and Versijp
(2007), Scaillet and Topaloglou (2010), Linton et al. (2014) and Post and Poti (2017) address this problem using various statistical methods. Their stochastic efficiency tests can
be seen as model-free alternatives to tests for M-V efficiency, such as the Shanken (1985,
1986) test (without a riskless asset) and the Gibbons et al. (1989) test (with a riskless
asset).
In a similar manner, the concept of stochastic spanning, introduced by Arvanitis et
al. (2017), can be perceived as a model-free alternative to M-V spanning (Huberman
and Kandel, 1987). Spanning occurs if introducing new securities or relaxing investment
constraints does not improve the investment possibility set uniformly over a given class
of investor preferences. Stochastic spanning, unlike M-V spanning, accounts for higherorder moment risk in addition to variance. Higher-order moment risk is arguably more
relevant for analyzing spanning than for efficiency. Efficiency tests are generally applied
to a given broad market index with limited skewness and kurtosis (at the typical monthly
to annual return frequency), in which case the arguments of Levy and Markowitz (1979)
for the M-V approximation are compelling. By contrast, a spanning test evaluates all
feasible portfolios, including those concentrated in a small number of risky securities, for
which the same arguments are unlikely to hold. Given this motivation, and for the second
4
order stochastic dominance relation, Arvanitis et al. (2017) propose a theoretical measure
for stochastic spanning, derive the null limit distribution for the associated empirical test
statistic and propose a relevant testing procedure based on subsampling.
In an empirical application using actual market data we test whether a portfolio set
originating from a traditional asset universe spans the same set augmented with cryptocurrencies. This could be of significant importance to the empirical analysis of financial markets. If the hypothesis of stochastic spanning is not true, then this implies that
the introduction of the new securities (in our case cryptocurrencies) or the relaxation of
investment restrictions is beneficial for some investors in the given class. Our focus is on
the most common SD criterion of second-order stochastic dominance (SSD), which has
a well-established economic interpretation in terms of expected utility theory and Yaari’s
(1987) dual theory of risk. We employ the S&P 500 Total Return Index, the Barclays
U.S. Aggregate Bond Index and the one-month Libor rate to proxy the traditional asset
universe, i.e., equities, bonds and the risk-free rate. We also use daily and weekly prices
for four cryptocurrencies namely Bitcoin, Ethereum, Ripple and Litecoin. We address our
research question both in- and out-of-sample.
In the in-sample analysis, using the Arvanitis et al. (2017) stochastic spanning test,
we find that the portfolios based on the traditional investment opportunity set do not span
the corresponding portfolio strategies that include cryptocurrencies. In the out-of-sample
analysis, at any point in time we construct optimal portfolios based separately on an asset
universe comprising traditional asset classes and on an asset universe augmented with
cryptocurrencies, in a rolling window fashion. We compare the real performance of these
portfolios using the Davidson and Duclos (2013) non-parametric stochastic dominance
test, as well as parametric performance measures. We find that the expanded investment
universe with cryptocurrencies empirically dominates the traditional investment universe
with stocks, bonds and cash, making the investor better off, w.r.t. to all the aforementioned
performance criteria.
Hence, given the above, the main contribution of this paper is the statistical finding that,
both in-sample and out-of-sample, the augmented portfolio with cryptocurrencies could
be a good option for some riks averse investors to help diversify their portfolio risks.
The results are not surprising. For most of the second half of 2016, Bitcoin had been on
a steady march higher, driven by a number of factors such as the devaluation of the yuan,
geopolitical uncertainty and an increase interest of the professional investors. In January
3, 2017, Bitcoin broke the $1000 mark for the first time in three years. The majority of
Bitcoin trading is done in China and so the devaluation of the yuan and fears over capital
controls had a significant impact on the price of the digital currency. But several other
factors have also had a notable impact, for example the U.S. election results in November
5
2016. In the first three quarters of 2017 there were numerous broad market developments
with material impacts on the digital asset space. For example, the denial of the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) of an exchange-traded fund (ETF), the Bitcoin
fork, Initial Coin Offerings (ICOs) legality and China’s stance on digital assets all contributed to a whirlwind move for the markets. Bitcoin and Ether are used to purchase
tokens for ICOs so a big part of Bitcoin’s and Ether’s surge was the ICO craze.
It is true that Bitcoin’s rally attracts interest in alternative cryptocurrencies like Ethereum.
It is also bringing a broader investment base. But while Bitcoin’s rise increases investors’
interest for Ethereum and other altcoins, Ethereum’s popularity depends at the same time
on a number of other factors, especially in the business and financial communities. Corporates have focused on the Ethereum wishing to use the technology for smart contract
applications, i.e., contracts that automatically execute according to a computer algorithm
when contract terms are met. Several financial institutions and large companies have invested in Ethereum technology and as a result in March 2017, the Enterprise Ethereum
Alliance (EEA) was formed with the involvement of some of the most valuable companies in the world, including Microsoft, JP Morgan and IBM. On the other hand, Ripple is
at times overwhelmingly independent and at others somewhat dependent to Bitcoin and
Ethereum. Its relative independence from Chinese markets and the lack of involvements
in ICOs shielded Ripple and the events in the digital asset space over the last year largely
did not involve Ripple directly. Litecoin, however, reacted quite dramatic to all news
from China since it is really popular among Chinese investors. Generally, in the last year
Litecoin’s bullish run coincides with other altcoins’ soaring gains including Ripple and
Ethereum.
Finally, we explain the documented diversification benefits of cryptocurrencies by using the approach of Cambell and Hamao (1992) to establish that cryptocurrency markets
are segmented from equity and bond markets. More specifically, under diversification
benefits and hence market segmentation, assets of the different markets are not priced
by the same discount factor (see, for example, Ferson et al., 1993; Bekaert and Urias,
1996; De Roon et al., 2003). To our knowledge, there is no relevant literature providing
evidence about the integration/segmentation of cryptocurrency markets with equity and
bond markets. We find that cryptocurrency markets are segmented from equity and bond
markets and exhibit characteristics of a unique asset class. We obtain data on a set of
variables documented to forecast returns in equity and bond markets: the dividend yield,
the default spread (Bessembinder and Chan, 1992), the term spread (Fama and French,
1989), the money supply growth (Chen, 2007) and the growth in the Baltic Dry Index
(Bakshi et al., 2011).
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe the stochastic spanning
6
methodology. In Section 3 we provide the empirical application. We present the results
from the in-sample and out-of-sample analysis. Section 4 presents the evidence on markets’ segmentation. The final Section concludes the paper. We discuss the computational
strategy in the Appendix.
2 Stochastic spanning
2.1 Preliminaries and null hypothesis
T
Let the investment opportunity set Λ := λ ∈ RN
+ : 1N λ = 1 , i.e. the N-simplex,
which represents the set of convex combinations of N base assets. Those are not necessarily restricted to be individual securities but are generally defined as the vertices of Λ,
which could in turn emerge as feasible combinations of some individual securities. The
analysis considers the random investment returns of the base assets represented by the random vector X := (x1 , . . . , xN ), with support bounded by X N := [x, x]N , −∞ < x < x < +∞.
X can be chosen arbitrarily as a closed superset of the maximal support of the base assets.
As in Arvanitis et al. (2017), to be realistic we do not allow for unbounded investment
opportunities, because of the risk of financial ruin and the associated negative spill-overs
to counterparties. For any realistic investment problem, private contracts, law and regulation may limit the investment possibilities. These restrictions will, for example, prohibit
any risk neutral investor from borrowing an infinite amount of money and assuming an
infinite and concentrated position in a single high-risk security.
´
Let F denote the continuous joint c.d.f. of X and F(y, λ ) := 1(X T λ ≤ y)dF(X) the
marginal c.d.f. for portfolio λ ∈ Λ. In order to define stochastic spanning, we use the
following integrated c.d.f.:
F
(2)
(x, λ ) :=
ˆ
x
F(y, λ )dy =
−∞
ˆ
x
−∞
(x − y)dF(y, λ ).
(1)
This measure corresponds to Bawa’s (1975) first-order lower-partial moment, or expected shortfall, for return threshold x ∈ X .
This study focuses on the effects of changing the set of base assets or investment constraints. For this purpose, we introduce a non-empty polyhedral subset K ⊂ Λ. A polyhedral structure is analytically convenient and can for example emerge if we remove some
of the extreme points of Λ and/or further restrict Λ with appropriate linear constraints. We
denote generic elements of Λ by λ , κ etc. We assume that λ ∈ Λ and κ ∈ K. Given the
above we will give the definition of stochastic spanning of Arvanitis et. al. (2017) and we
will descibe their measure for stochastic spanning.
7
Definition 1. (Stochastic Spanning): Portfolio set Λ is second-order stochastically spanned
by subset K ⊂ Λ if all portfolios λ ∈ Λ are weakly second-order stochastically dominated
by some portfolios κ ∈ K:
∀λ ∈ Λ, ∃κ ∈ K :∀x ∈ X : G(x, κ , λ ; F) ≤ 0
G(x, λ , τ ; F) := F (2) (x, λ ) − F (2) (x, τ ).
(2)
From Arvanitis et al. (2017) the following scalar-valued functional of the population
c.d.f. serves as a measure for deviations from stochastic spanning:
η (F) := sup inf sup G(x, κ , λ ; F) ≥ 0.
(3)
λ ∈Λ κ ∈K x∈X
If η (F) = 0, then there is no feasible portfolio λ ∈ Λ that is not weakly dominated by
a portfolio κ ∈ Κ. If η (F) > 0, then stochastic spanning does not occur.
According to the above definition K stochastically spans Λ iff any arbitrary element of
the latter set is weakly dominated by some element of the former set. Using the utility
class interpretation, this is equivalent to that for an arbitrary element of Λ there exists an
element of K, weakly prefered to the former, by every risk averse utility. Hence, by Proposition 2 of Arvanitis et al. (2017) the stochasic spanning measure can be reformulated in
terms of expected utility as:
η (F) =
sup
inf EF u X T λ − u X T κ ;
λ ∈Λ;u∈U2 κ ∈K
0
U2 := u ∈ C : u(y) =
ˆ
x
x
w(x)r(y; x)dx w ∈ W
r(y; x) := (y − x)1(y ≤ x), (x, y) ∈ X 2 .
(4)
;
(5)
(6)
In this formulation, U2 is a set of normalized, increasing and concave utility functions
that are constructed as convex mixtures of elementary Russell and Seo (1989) ramp functions r(y; x), x ∈ X . Stochastic spanning (η (F) = 0) occurs if no risk averter (u ∈ U2 )
benefits from the enlargement (Λ − K). The representation of spanning in 4 is quite useful
for the numerical implementation of the associated testing procedure derived in Arvanitis
et al. (2017) (see Appendix for a detailed description of the implementation).
8
2.2 Statistical test and critical values
In empirical applications, the c.d.f. F is latent and the analyst has access to a discrete
T
T
time series of realized returns (Xt )t=1
, Xt ∈ X , t = 1, ..., T. Let FT (x) := T −1 ∑t=1
1 (Xt ≤ x)
denote the associated empirical c.d.f.. Given the above, Arvanitis et al. (2017) use the following scaled empirical analogue as a test statistic for stochastic spanning:
ηT :=
√
T sup inf sup G(x, κ , λ ; FT ).
λ ∈Λ κ ∈K x∈X
We will use the test statistic ηT to test the null hypothesis of stochastic spanning. Arvanitis et al. (2017) establish the asymptotic distribution of the test statistic under the
null hypothesis. The basic decision rule to reject H0 against H1 if and only if ηT >
q(η ∞ , 1 − α ) where q(η∞ , 1 − α ) denotes the (1 − α ) quantile of the distribution of η∞
for any significance level α ∈ ]0, 1[ and η∞ is the relevant weak limit. However this is
infeasible due to the dependence of q(η∞ , 1 − α ) on the latent c.d.f. F as well as on
the temporal dependence of the returns process. However, feasible decision rules can be
obtained by using a subsampling procedure to estimate q(η∞ , 1 − α ) from the data.
The subsampling procedure, begins by generating (T − bT + 1) maximally overlapping
T −1
subsamples of (Xs )t+b
, t = 1, · · · , T − bT + 1, and then evaluates the test statistic on
s=t
each subsample value thereby obtaining ηbT ;T,t for t = 1, · · · , T − bT + 1. The empirical
distribution of subsample test scores can be described by the following c.d.f. and quantile
function:
T −bT +1
1
∑ 1(ηbT ;T,t ≤ y);
T − bT + 1 t=1
qT,bT (1 − α ) := inf sT,bT (y) ≥ 1 − α .
sT,bT (y) :=
y
(7)
(8)
We reject H0 if and only if ηT > qT,bT (1 − α ). This subsampling routine is asymptotically exact and consistent under reasonable assumptions on the subsample length and
significance level (see Online Appendix B in Arvanitis et al., 2017).
Although the test has asymptotically correct size the quantile estimates qT,bT (1 − α )
may be biased and very sensitive to the choice of subsample size bT in finite samples of
realistic dimensions (N and T ). Arvatitis et al. (2017) propose a correction procedure via
a regression-based method. For a given significance level α , the quantiles qT,bT (1 − α )
are evaluated for a range of the subsample size bT . Next, the intercept and slope of the
following regression line using OLS regression analysis are estimated:
9
qT,bT (1 − α ) = γ0;T,1−α + γ1;T,1−α (bT )−1 + νT ;1−α ,bT .
(9)
Finally, the bias-corrected (1 − α )-quantile is evaluated as the OLS predicted value for
bT = T :
−1
qBC
T (1 − α ) := γ̂0;T,1−α + γ̂1;T,1−α (T ) .
(10)
Arvanitis et al. (2017) argue that the asymptotic properties are not affected, while computational experiments show that the bias-corrected method is more efficient and more
powerful in small samples.
3 Empirical application
In the empirical application we test whether the inclusion of cryptocurrencies in the
asset universe could make some risk averse investors better off compared to the case where
the asset universe consists of only traditional asset classes (stocks, bonds and cash). We
address our research question both in- and out-of-sample.
We use data on daily closing prices of a number of indices obtained from Bloomberg.
We employ the S&P 500 Total Return Index, the Barclays U.S. Aggregate Bond Index and
the one-month Libor rate to proxy the traditional asset universe, i.e., the equity market,
the bond market and the risk-free rate, respectively. To access the cryptocurrencies asset
class, we use daily data on Bitcoin, Ethereum, Ripple and Litecoin US dollar closing
prices extracted from the Bitfinex exchange market through the CoinMarketCap. Ether
was first publiclly traded in July 2015 and data availability for cryptocurrencies before
that date was an issue. So, the dataset spans the period from August 7, 2015 to December
29, 2017, a total of 604 daily return observations.
Table 1 reports summary statistics regarding the performance of the employed assets
over this period. We can see that the daily average return of cryptocurrencies is higher
than that of stocks and bonds. The Sharpe ratio of cryptocurrencies is also considerably
higher. Moreover, cryptocurrencies exhibit considerable standard deviation, compared to
the mean. Skewness and kurtosis are extremely high, indicating large deviations from
normality. Although the one-month Libor rate is not constant, its daily return is calculated and is considered constant, therefore the standard deviation is zero, and we do not
calculate skewness and kurtosis.
10
3.1 In-sample analysis
In this section we test in-sample the null hypothesis that the traditional asset class spans
the augmented with cryptocurrencies asset universe. We get the subsampling distribution
of
the
test
statistic
for
subsample
size
bT ∈ [120, 240, 360, 480]. Using OLS regression on the empirical quantiles qT,bT (1 − α )
and for significance level α = 0.05, we get the estimate qBC
T for the critical value.
We find that the regression estimate qBC
T = 0.3408 is lower than the value of the test
statistic 0.34834. Thus, we reject the hypothesis that the traditional asset class spans the
augmented asset class with cryptocurrencies.
In order to validate our results, we carry out an additional test. Particularly, we test
whether the results on the outperformance of cryptocurrencies are robust to the choice of
traditional asset universe. To this end, we include both the S&P 500 and dynamic trading
strategy (i.e. SMB or HML) into the traditional asset universe. Moreover, we include the
Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and the Vanguard small-cap index funds.
We find that the regression estimate qBC
T = 0.33870 is again lower than the value of the
test statistic 0.34834.
We can see that in any case the optimal portfolios based on the investment opportunity
set that includes cryptocurrencies are not spanned by the corresponding optimal portfolio
strategies based on the traditional investment opportunity set.
The results of this in-sample-analysis indicate that the performance of traditional portfolios, consisting of stocks, bonds and cash, can be improved by including cryptocurrencies. Thus, some risk averse investors could benefit from the augmentation.
3.2 Out-of-sample analysis
In this section, we examine whether cryptocurrencies could provide diversification
benefits out-of-sample. Although in the in-sample tests we reject the null hypothesis
of stochastic spanning, it is not known a priori whether the augmented with cryptocurrencies portfolios will outperform the traditional ones in an out-of-sample setting. This
is because by construction these portfolios are formed at time t based on the information
prevailing at time t, while the portfolio returns are reaped over [t,t + 1] (next day). The
out-of-sample test is a real-time exercise mimicking the way that a real-time investor acts.
We form optimal portfolios separately for two asset universes: one that includes traditional asset classes, i.e., equities, bonds and risk-free asset and an augmented one
with cryptocurrencies. We resort to backtesting experiments on a rolling horizon basis.
The rolling horizon simulations cover the 604 working day period from 08/07/2015 to
12/29/2017. At each day, we use the data from the previous year (269 daily observations)
11
to calibrate the procedure. We solve the resulting optimization problem for the stochastic
spanning test and record the optimal portfolio of the traditional assets as well as the optimal portfolio of the traditional assets and the cryptocurrencies. The clock is advanced
and the realized returns of the optimal portfolios are determined from the actual returns
of the various assets. The same procedure is then repeated for the next time period and
the ex post realized returns over the period from 09/01/2016 to 29/12/2017 (334 working
days) are computed for both portfolios.
Figure 1 illustrates the cumulative performance of the traditional optimal portfolio as
well as the augmented with cryptocurrencies optimal portfolio for the sample period from
09/01/2016 to 12/29/2017. We observe that the augmented optimal portfolio has more
than 307 times higher value at the end of the holding period compared to the beginning,
while the traditional portfolio has only 1.265 times higher value. Not surprisingly, the
relevant performance of portfolios with cryptocurrencies is 242 times higher compared
to the equity market, the bond index and the Libor 1-month. The optimal augmented
portfolio includes Ethereum and Ripple, and small amount in Litecoin, but none of the
traditional assets.
We repeat the backtesting experiment extending the traditional asset class with the
SMB and HML indices, as well as the Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and
the Vanguard small-cap index funds, in the same way as we did in the in-sample analysis.
Figure 2 exhibits the cumulative performance of both the traditional optimal portfolio and
the optimal augmented portfolio for the sample period from 09/01/2016 to 29/12/2017.
The same observations hold here, i.e., the value of the augmented optimal portfolio is
more than 307 times higher at the end of the holding period while the traditional portfolio
has only 1.348 times higher value. Again, the relevant performance of the portfolio with
cryptocurrencies is 228 times higher than the performance of the equity indices, the bond
index and the Libor 1-month. The optimal augmented portfolio is the same as before.
3.3 Out-of-sample performance assessment
In this section, we compare the out-of-sample performance of the two optimal portfolios formed by the respective two asset universes by using both non-parametric and
parametric tests.
3.3.1
Non-parametric tests
There is a number of pairwise stochastic dominance tests presented in the literature;
see, for example Barret and Donald (2003), Davidson and Duclos (2000), Linton et al.
(2005) and Davidson and Duclos (2013). Here we prefer to use the Davidson and Duclos
12
(2013) stochastic dominance test, mainly for two reasons. First, the test allows for correlated samples. Second, the Davidson and Duclos (2013) test has as null hypothesis that
one portfolio does not stochastically dominate another, i.e., the nondominance. The majority of stochastic dominance tests posit the null of dominance. But rejecting dominance
of one portfolio does not necessarily imply that the other one is stochastically dominant.
However, under the Davidson and Duclos (2013) test, rejecting the nondominance of one
portfolio, leaves us with the only remaining alternative, i.e., dominance. Adding up to this
idea, we test the null of nondominance of the optimal portfolio based on stocks, bonds,
cash and cryptocurrencies over the traditional asset universe. The alternative hypothesis
is that the augmented asset universe based optimal portfolio stochastically dominates the
traditional asset based optimal portfolio. We test the null hypothesis using second order
stochastic dominance criteria1 .
We define the empirical versions of the dominance functions D2Tr and D2Aug (see Davidson and Duclos (2000) for the definition of dominance functions) as,
D̂2Tr =
1 T
∑ (max(z − yt , 0)),
T t=1
(11)
where T is the number of observations in the distribution sample of traditional portfolio
returns, yt is the t -th observation, and z is the threshold of interest. Analogously, we
define the dominance function for the augmented portfolio (Aug).
Then the augmented portfolio dominates at second order the traditional portfolio iff
D̂2Tr > D̂2Aug for all y in the joint support. The null hypothesis of nondominance is not
rejected unless there is dominance in the sample.
For each threshold level z, let the standardized difference of the two dominance functions,
D̂2Tr − D̂2Aug
,
(12)
t(z) =
(Var(D̂2Tr ) +Var(D̂2Aug ) − 2Cov(D̂2Tr , D̂2Aug ))1/2
and the resulting test statistic,
t ∗ = min t(z).
z
(13)
In order to simulate the p-values we use the bootstrap methodology described in Davidson and Duclos (2013). Notice that the relevant limiting results of Davidson and Duclos
(2013) could be justified in the framework of rebalanced optimal portfolios via results
such as Theorem 4.4.2 of Politis et al. (1999). The results entail T − 1, i.e., 233 overlapping periods for the in-sample fitting of the two portfolios with corresponding out1 Hodder
et al. (2015) use the same stochastic dominance test to test the out-of-sample performance of
alternative portfolios compared to a benchmark portfolio.
13
of-sample comparisons. The 233 p-values are considered from September 1, 2016 to
December 29, 2017, using overlapping periods of 100 daily returns. Since it is impossible
to aggregate the T − 1 values of the Davidson and Duclos (2013) test statistic to get a
unique measure of comparison, we compute quartile p-values from the distribution of the
T − 1 test statistics.
Table 2 reports the quartile p-values from the distribution of daily portfolio returns, under the null hypothesis that the augmented portfolio does not dominate the traditional one.
Panel A considers the case when the traditional set includes the S&P 500 Equity Index,
the Barclays US Aggregate Bond Index and the 1-month Libor, while Panel B considers
the case when the traditional set includes additionally the SMB and HML indices, as well
as the Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and the Vanguard small-cap index
funds. We observe that for the 25% and 50% quartile p-values, we tend to reject the null
hypothesis that the augmented optimal portfolio does not dominate the traditional one in
all cases, with respect to the second order stochastic dominance criterion.
The results indicate that the null hypothesis of nondominance over the traditional portfolio can be rejected even for 50% of daily tests for both cases.
3.3.2
Parametric tests
We compute a number of commonly used parametric performance measures: the Sharpe
ratio, the downside Sharpe ratio of Ziemba (2005), the upside potential and downside risk
(UP) ratio of Sortino and van den Meer (1991), the opportunity cost, the portfolio turnover
and a measure of the portfolio risk-adjusted returns net of transaction costs. The downside
Sharpe and UP ratios are considerd to be more appropriate measures of performance than
the typical Sharpe ratio given the asymmetric return distribution of cryptocurrencies.
For the downside Sharpe ratio, first we need to calculate the downside variance (or
more precisely the downside risk),
σP2− =
T
(xt − x̄)2−
∑t=1
,
T −1
(14)
where the benchmark x̄ is zero, and the xt taken are those returns of portfolio P at day t
below x̄, i.e. those t of the T days with losses. To get the total variance, we use twice the
downside variance namely 2σP2− so that the dowside Sharpe ratio is,
R̄ p − R̄ f
,
SP = √
2σP−
(15)
where R̄ p is the average period return of portfolio P and R¯f is the average risk free rate.
The UP ratio compares the upside potential to the shortfall risk over a specific target
14
(benchmark) and is computed as follows. Let Rt be the realized daily return of portfolio
P for t = 1, ..., T of the backtesting period, where T = 252 is the number of experiments
performed and let ρt be respecitvely the return of the benchmark (T-bills riskless asset)
for the same period. Then, we have,
UP ratio =
1
K
q
1
K
K
max[0, Rt − ρt ]
∑t=1
K
(max[0, ρt − Rt ])2
∑t=1
.
(16)
It is obvious that the numerator of the above ratio is the average excess return over the
benchmark and so reflects upside potential. In the same way, the denominator measures
downside risk, i.e. shortfall risk over the benchmark.
Next, we use the concept of opportunity cost presented in Simaan (2013) to analyse the
economic significance of the performance difference of the two optimal portfolios. Let
RAug and RTr be the realized returns of the optimal portfolio for the augmented and the
traditional asset class respectively. Then, the opportunity cost θ is defined as the return
that needs to be added to (or subtracted from) the traditional portfolio return RTr , so that
the investor is indifferent (in utility terms) between the strategies imposed by the two
different investment opportunity sets, i.e.,
E[U(1 + RTr + θ )] = E[U(1 + RAug )].
(17)
A positive (negative) opportunity cost implies that the investor is better (worse) off
if the investment opportunity set allows for cryptocurrency investing. Notice that the
opportunity cost takes into account the entire probability density function of asset returns
and hence it is suitable to evaluate strategies even when the assets’ return distribution is
not normal. For the calculation of the opportunity cost, we use exponential and power
utility functions alternatively, consistent with second degree stochastic dominance. We
also employ alternative values for the risk aversion parameter.
Next, we compute the portfolio turnover (PT) to get a feeling of the degree of rebalancing required to implement each one of the two strategies. For any portfolio strategy P,
the portfolio turnover is defined as the average of the absolute change of weights over the
T rebalancing points in time and across the N available assets, i.e.,
PT =
1 T N
∑ ∑ (|wP,i,t+1 − wP,i,t |),
T t=1
i=1
(18)
where wP,i,t+1 and wP,i,t are the optimal weights of asset i under strategy P (traditional or
augmented) at time t and t + 1, respectively.
Finally, we evaluate the performance of the two portfolios under the risk-adjusted (net
15
of transaction costs) returns measure, proposed by DeMiguel et al. (2009) which indicates
the way that the proportional transaction cost, generated by the portfolio turnover, affects
the portfolio returns. Let trc be the proportional transaction cost, and RP,t+1 the realized
return of portfolio P at time t + 1. The change in the net of transaction cost wealth NWP
of portfolio P through time is,
N
NWP,t+1 = NWP,t (1 + RP,t+1 )[1 − trc × ∑ (|wP,i,t+1 − wP,i,t |).
(19)
i=1
The portfolio return, net of transaction costs is defined as
RTCP,t+1 =
NWP,t+1
− 1.
NWP,t
(20)
Let µTr and µAug be the out-of-sample mean of monthly RTC with the restricted and the
expanded opportunity set, respectively, and σTr and σAug be the corresponding standard
deviations. Then, the return-loss measure is,
RLoss =
µAug
× σTr − µTr ,
σAug
(21)
i.e., the additional return needed so that the traditional portfolio performs equally well
with the augmented portfolio. We follow the literature and use 35 bps for the transaction
cost of stocks and bonds.
In the cryptocurrency market, transaction costs usually occur in two ways, namely trading fees and the bid-ask spread. Bid-ask spread is a type of risk premium to compensate
market dealer for providing liquidity. To execute a transaction, investor should pay additional premium to the exchange. And usually, exchange will ask for a high premium to
reduce loss by providing liquidity to the informed traders. But overall, the bid-ask spread
is minor issue compared to the normal price deviation. In contrast, other fees create more
frictions for investors to make arbitrage. For example, BTC-E charges a 0.2 to 0.5 percent
fee per transaction along with fees to deposit or withdraw traditional currency. According to CryptoCoins News, there is currently a $20 fee for a wire deposit. Bitstamp and
Bitfinex also charge trading fees and deposit/withdrawal/fees. In order to confirm the outof-sample superiority of the augmented portfolio, we decided to use higher transaction
costs for cryptocurrencies than for stocks and bonds, i.e., 50 bps.
Table 3 reports the parametric performance measures for the traditional and the augmented portfolios (Panels A and B respectively). These performance measures, although
parametric, will supplement the evidence obtained from the previously discussed nonparametric stochastic dominace measure. The higher the value of each one of these measures, the greater the investment opportunities for cryptocurrencies. From the results, we
16
can see that the inclusion of cryprocurrencies into the opportunity set increases both the
Sharpe ratios and the downside Sharpe ratios. This reflects an increase in risk-adjusted
performance (i.e., an increase in expected return per unit of risk) and hence expands the
investment opportunities of some risk-averse investors. The same is true for the UP ratio.
Furthermore, we observe that portfolios with only traditional assets induce more portfolio
turnover than the ones with cryptocurrencies, regardless of the choice of the traditional
assets. Additionally, we can see that the return-loss measure, that takes into account transaction costs, is positive in both cases. We find a positive opportunity cost θ . One needs
to give a positive return equal to θ to an investor who does not include cryptocurrencies
in her portfolio so that she becomes as happy as an investor who includes cryptocurrencies. The computation of the opportunity cost requires the computation of the expected
utility and hence the use of the probability density function of portfolio returns. Thus, the
calculated opportunity cost has taken into account the higher order moments in contrast
to the Sharpe ratios. Therefore, the opportunity cost estimates provide further convincing
evidence for possible diversification benefits from the inclusion of cryptocurrencies given
the large deviation from normality.
To sum up, the non-parametric stochastic dominance test, as well as the employed parametric performance measures, indicate that when the investment universe is augmented
with cryptocurrencies it empirically dominates the traditional one, yielding potential diversification benefits and providing some investment opportunities.
4 Market segmentation
In this section we further investigate the reason of the empirical outperformance of the
cryptocurrency assets over the traditional ones presented in the previous Section. To this
end, we test whether the cryptocurrency market is integrated/ segmented with the equity
and bond market.
Typical definitions of capital market integration imply that financial assets that trade
in different markets will have identical expected returns as long as they have identical
risk characteristics (Campbell and Hamao, 1992). An equivalent way of defining market
integration is that the financial assets have at least one stochastic discount factor (SDF)
in common, i.e., the same SDF prices all assets (see also, Bessembinder and Chan, 1992;
Chen and Knez, 1995). Hence, in the case of market integration, there is a common
stochastic discount factor which prices the various asset classes.
The existence of diversification benefits is tightly connected with spanning. A set of
test assets are said to provide diversification benefits relative to a set of benchmark assets
if adding these assets to the benchmark leads to a significant leftward shift in the efficient
17
frontier (Bekaert and Urias, 1996). This is equivalent to test whether a set of benchmark
assets spans the set of both benchmark and test assets. Thus, in the case of spanning,
including the test assets in the benchmark asset universe does not increase the portfolio
expected return per unit of risk (i.e., the Sharpe ratio) and thus diversification benefits do
not exist.
In the case where markets are segmented, assets in different markets are not priced by
the same stochastic discount factor. This in turn implies that assets in one market are not
spanned by assets in the other markets and hence diversification benefits exist (for the
case of Mean-Variance spanning, see for example Ferson et al., 1993; Bekaert and Urias,
1996; DeSantis, 1995; and for the non Mean-Variance case see, De Roon et al., 2003).
We follow the Campbell and Hamao (1992) model to test for market integration. Let a
K− factor asset pricing model,
K
Ri,t+1 = Et (Ri,t+1 ) + ∑ βik fk,t+1 + ei,t+1 ,
(22)
k=1
where Ri,t+1 denotes the excess return on asset i held from time t to time t + 1, fk,t+1
the kth factor realization, βik the factor loading with respect to the kth factor and ei,t+1 the
error term. The above equation maps to an expected return-beta representation (Cochrane,
2005),
K
Et (Ri,t+1 ) = ∑ βik λkt ,
(23)
i=1
where λkt is the market price of risk for the kth factor at time t. The time variation in the
kth factor market price of risk is modeled as
N
λkt =
∑ θknXnt ,
(24)
n=1
where there is a set of N predictors Xnt , n = 1, 2, ..., N. Assuming that markets are integrated, i.e., they have the same prices of risk and the time variation in expected returns
stems from time variation in the prices of risk, equations (23) and (24) imply that predictor
variables that drive prices of risk should be the same across assets. Therefore, evidence
that the predictors of the price of risk differ across asset classes would imply that the
market price of risk is not the same across assets and hence markets are segmented.
We use predictors which have been documented to predict equity and bond markets
returns: the dividend yield, the default spread (Bessembinder and Chan, 1992), the term
spread (Fama and French, 1989), the money supply growth (Chen, 2007) and the growth
in the Baltic Dry Index (Bakshi et al., 2011). We obtain weekly data on the dividend yield
on MSCI World, the junk bond premium (or default spread, defined as the excess of the
18
yield on long-term BAA corporate bonds rated by Moody’s over the yield on AAA-rated
bonds), the term spread (defined as the difference between the Aaa yield and the onemonth bill rate) and the Baltic Dry Index from Bloomberg. We also obtain weekly data
on money supply from the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US).
Table 4 presents the evidence on the forecastability of the weekly asset returns during
the period from August 7, 2015 to December 29, 2017. The Newey-West standard errors
are used to correct for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity. We can see that the S&P 500
equity index can be predicted by the default spread and the dividend yield. The Barclays
Bond index can be predicted by the term spread. On the other hand, these predictors do
not forecast cryptocurrency weekly returns. This evidence is also supported by the Fstatistic and the respective p-values: the hypothesis that all coefficient estimates equal to
zero can be rejected only for the traditional asset classes, i.e., the S&P 500 equity index
and the Barclays Bond Index.
Our results show that cryptocurrency returns cannot be forecasted by variables that
predict stock and bond market returns. This suggests that the price of risk is driven by
different predictors across the various asset classes which in turn implies that the prices
of risk differ. As a result, cryptocurrency markets are segmented from equity and bond
markets and hence the inclusion of cryptocurrencies in investors’ portfolios is expected to
yield some diversification benefits. Note that the market integration test offers a statistical
setting on top of the economic significance setting applied in the previous sections to
assess whether cryptocurrencies may offer diversification benefits. In addition, the test is
applied to the full sample and hence the obtained results are meant to be discussed in light
of the in-sample evidence.
5 Conclusions
Cryptocurrencies are one of the most important financial innovations in recent times.
They have drawn an increasing number of critics and supporters in equal measures. To
expand the analysis of cryptocurrencies as assets, we have adopted a stochasic dominance
approach.
In a related empirical application using actual market data, we test whether a portfolio
set originated from a traditional asset universe does not span the same set augmented by
including cryptocurrencies. If spanning is rejected, then some risk averters could benefit
from the augmentation of investment opportunities. We employ the S&P 500 Total Return
Index, Barclays U.S. Aggregate Bond Index and the one month Libor rate to proxy the
traditional asset universe, i.e. the equity market, the bond market and the risk-free rate.
We also use daily and weekly prices for four cryptocurrencies namely Bitcoin, Ethereum,
19
Ripple and Litecoin for the period August 2015 to December 2017. We conduct our
analysis both in- and out-of-sample by constructing and comparing optimal portfolios
derived from two respective asset universes: one that includes only the traditional asset
classes (equities, bonds and cash) and one that is augmented with cryptocurrencies, too.
In the in-sample tests, we find that the optimal portfolios formed based on the investment opportunity set that also includes cryptocurrencies are not spanned by the corresponding portfolio strategies based on the traditional investment opportunity set. Thus,
there may be some risk averse investors that would benefit from the augmentation, while
some others would not.
In the out-of-sample analysis, using a non-parametric stochastic dominance test as well
as parametric performance measures, we find that the expanded investment universe with
cryptocurrencies empirically dominates traditional one with stocks, bonds and cash, yielding some diversification benefits and providing better investment opportunities.
We explain the reported diversification benefits by documenting that cryptocurrency
markets are segmented from equity and bond markets.
While our results are interesting, and the cryptocurrency markets seem to be growing in
popularity, investments in such markets should be considered with extreme caution due to
excessive volatility. Hence, we acknowledge that there are some issues to be considered
before cryptocurrencies will form an asset class of significant interest.
20
References
Ali, M.M., 1975, Stochastic dominance and portfolio analysis, Journal of Financial
Economics 2, 205-229.
Arvanitis, S., M. Hallam, Th. Post and N.Topaloglou, 2017, Stochastic Spanning,
forthcoming in Journal of Business and Economics Statistics.
Athayde, G.M. and R.G. Flores, 2004, Finding a maximum skewness portfolio: A
general solution to three-moments portfolio choice, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control 28, 1335-1352.
Bakshi, G., G. Panayotov and G. Skoulakis, 2011, The baltic dry index as a predictor
of global stock returns, commodity returns, and global economic activity.
Barrett, G. and S. Donald, 2003, Consistent tests for stochastic dominance, Econometrica 71, 71-104.
Bawa, V.S., 1975, Optimal rules for ordering uncertain prospects, Journal of Financial
Economics 2, 95-121.
Bawa, V.S., J.N. Bodurtha Jr., M.R. Rao and H. L. Suri, 1985, On determination of
stochastic dominance optimal sets, Journal of Finance 40, 417-431.
Bekaert, G. and M.S. Urias, 1996, Diversification, integration and emerging market
closed-end funds, Journal of Finance 51, 835-869.
Berk, J., 1997, Necessary conditions for the CAPM, Journal of Economic Theory 73,
245-257.
Bessembinder, H. and K. Chan, 1992, Time-varying risk premia and forecastable returns in futures markets, Journal of Financial Economics 32, 169-193.
Brandt, M.W. and P. Santa-Clara, 2006, Dynamic portfolio selection by augmenting
the asset space, Journal of Finance 61, 2187-2217.
Campbell, J.Y. and Y. Hamao, 1992, Predictable stock returns in the United States and
Japan: A study of long-term capital market integration, Journal of Finance 47, 43-69.
Carrasco, M. and X. Chen, 2002, Mixing and moment properties of various GARCH
and stochastic volatility models, Econometric Theory 18, 17-39.
Cass, D. and J. Stiglitz, 1970, The structure of investor preferences and asset returns,
and separability in portfolio allocation, Journal of Economic Theory 2, 122-160.
Chamberlain, G., 1983, A characterization of the distributions that imply mean—Variance
utility functions, Journal of Economic Theory 29, 185-201.
Chen, S.S., 2007, Does monetary policy have asymmetric effects on stock returns?,
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 667-688.
Chen, Z. and P.J. Knez, 1995, Measurement of market integration and arbitrage, Review
of Financial Studies 8, 287-325.
21
Cochrane, J.H., 2005, The risk and return of venture capital, Journal of Financial Economics 75, 3-52.
Davidson, R. and J.-Y. Duclos, 2000, Statistical inference for stochastic dominance and
for the measurement of poverty and inequality, Econometrica 68, 1435-1464.
Davidson, R. and J.-Y. Duclos, 2013, Testing for restricted stochastic dominance,
Econometric Reviews 32, 84-125.
DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi and R. Uppal, 2009, Optimal versus naive diversification:
How inefficient is the 1/n portfolio strategy?, Review of Financial Studies 22, 1915-1953.
De Roon, F.A., T.E. Nijman and B.J. Werker, 2003, Currency hedging for international
stock portfolios: The usefulness of mean–variance analysis, Journal of Banking and Finance 27, 327-349.
DeSantis, G., 1995, Volatility bounds for stochastic discount factors: Tests and implications from international stock returns, Unpublished paper, Marshall School of Business,
University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA.
Dittmar, R.F., 2002, Nonlinear pricing kernels, kurtosis preference, and evidence from
the cross section of equity returns, Journal of Finance 57, 369-403.
Fama, E.F. and K.R. French, 1989, Business conditions and expected returns on stocks
and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 23-49.
Ferson, W.E., S.R. Foerster and D.B. Keim, 1993, General tests of latent variable models and mean-variance spanning, Journal of Finance 48, 131-156.
Fishburn, P.C., 1974, Convex stochastic dominance with continuous distribution functions, Journal of Economic Theory 7, 143-58.
Gibbons, M., S. Ross and J. Shanken, 1989, A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio,
Econometrica 57, 1121-1152.
Hadar, J. and W.R. Russell, 1969, Rules for ordering uncertain prospects, American
Economic Review 59, 2–34.
Hanoch, G. and H. Levy, 1969, The efficiency analysis of choices involving risk, Review of Economic Studies 36, 335-346.
Hansen, L.P. and S.F. Richard, 1987, The role of conditioning information in deducing
testable restrictions implied by dynamic asset pricing models, Econometrica 55, 587–613.
Harvey, C. R. and A. Siddique, 2000, Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests, Journal of Finance 55, 1263–1295.
Hodder, J.E., J.C. Jackwerth and O. Kolokolova, 2014, Improved portfolio choice using
second-order stochastic dominance, Review of Finance 19,1623-1647.
Huberman, G. and S. Kandel, 1987, Mean-variance spanning, Journal of Finance 42,
873-888.
Kuosmanen, T., 2004, Efficient diversification according to stochastic dominance cri-
22
teria, Management Science 50, 1390-1406.
Levy, H., 2015, Stochastic dominance: Investment decision making under uncertainty,
Springer.
Levy, H. and H. Markowitz, 1979, Approximating expected utility by a function of
mean and variance, American Economic Review 69, 308-317.
Linton, O.B., E. Maasoumi and Y.-J. Whang, 2005, Consistent testing for stochastic
dominance under general sampling schemes, Review of Economic Studies 72, 735-765.
Linton, O.B., Th. Post and Y.-J. Whang, 2014, Testing for the stochastic dominance
efficiency of a given portfolio, Econometrics Journal 17, 59-74.
Mencia, J. and E. Sentana, 2009, Multivariate location-scale mixtures of normals and
mean-variance-skewness portfolio allocation, Journal of Econometrics 153, 105-121.
Mosler, K. and M. Scarsini, 2012, Stochastic orders and applications: a classified
bibliography (Vol. 401), Springer Science and Business Media.
Owen, J. and R. Rabinovitch, 1983, On the class of elliptical distributions and their
applications to the theory of portfolio choice, Journal of Finance 38, 745-752.
Politis, D. N., J. P. Romano and M. Wolf, 1999, Subsampling, Springer Series In Statistics.
Post, Th., 2003, Empirical tests for stochastic dominance efficiency, Journal of Finance
58, 1905-1932.
Post, Th. and Ph. Versijp, 2007, Multivariate tests for stochastic dominance efficiency
of a given portfolio, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 42, 489-516.
Post, Th. and V. Poti, 2017, Portfolio Analysis using Stochastic Dominance, Relative
Entropy and Empirical Likelihood, Management Science 63, 153-165.
Quirk, J.P. and R. Saposnik, 1962, Admissibility and measurable utility functions, Review of Economics Studies 29, 140-146.
Roman, D., K. Darby-Dowman and G. Mitra, 2006, Portfolio construction based on
stochastic dominance and target return distributions, Mathematical Programming 108,
541-569.
Ross, S.A., 1978, Mutual fund separation in financial theory—The separating distributions, Journal of Economic Theory 17, 254-83.
Rothschild, M. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1970, Increasing risk: I. A Definition, Journal of
Economic Theory 2, 225-243.
Russell, W.R. and T.K. Seo, 1989, Representative sets for stochastic dominance rules,
In Studies in Economics of Uncertainty: In honor of Josef Hadar (Edited by T.B. Fomby
and T.K. Seo), New York.
Scaillet, O. and N. Topaloglou, 2010, Testing for stochastic dominance efficiency, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 28, 169-180.
23
Shalit, H. and S. Yitzhaki, 1994, Marginal conditional stochastic dominance, Management Science 40, 670-684.
Shanken, J., 1985, Multivariate tests of the zero-beta CAPM, Journal of Financial
Economics 14, 327-348.
Shanken, J., 1986, Testing portfolio efficiency when the zero-beta rate is unknown: A
note, Journal of Finance 41, 269-276.
Simaan, Y., 1993, Portfolio selection and asset pricing-three-parameter framework,
Management Science 39, 568-577.
Sortino, F. and R. van der Meer, 1991, Downside risk - capturing whatas at stake in
investment situations, Journal of Portfolio Management 17, 27-31.
Yaari, M.E., 1987, The dual theory of choice under risk, Econometrica 55, 95-115.
Yermack, D., 2015, Is Bitcoin a real currency? An economic appraisal, in Handbook
of Digital Currency, 31-43.
Ziemba, W., 2005, The symmetric downside risk sharpe ratio, Journal of Portfolio
Management 32, 108-122.
24
Appendix: Computational strategy
For convenience we present here the computational strategy for the spanning testing
procedure developed in Online Appendix of Arvanitis et al. (2017).
The test statistic can be written:
√
ηT =
T sup
T
T
.
sup EFT u X λ − sup EFT u X κ
(25)
κ ∈K
λ ∈Λ
u∈U2
The term in parentheses is the difference between the solutions to two standard convex
optimization problems of maximizing a quasi-concave objective function over a polyhedral feasible set. The analytic complexity of computing ηT stems from the search over
all admissible utility functions (U2 ). However, the utility functions are univariate, normalized, and have a bounded domain (X ). As a result, we can approximate U2 with
arbitrary accuracy using a finite set of increasing and concave piecewise-linear functions
in the following way.
We partition X into N1 equally spaced values as x = z1 < · · · < zN1 = x, where zn :=
x + Nn−1
(x − x), n = 1, · · · , N1 ; N1 ≥ 2. Instead of an equal spacing, the partition could
1 −1
also be based on percentiles of the return distribution. Similarly, we partition the interval
N2 −2
[0, 1], as 0 < N21−1 < · · · < N
< 1, N2 ≥ 2. Using this partition, let
2 −1
ηT :=
√
T sup
u∈U2
U2 :=
W :=
(
T
T
;
sup EFT u X λ − sup EFT u X κ
u ∈ C 0 : u(y) =
N1
∑ wnr(y; zn) w∈W
n=1
)
;
)
N1 N1
N2 − 2
1
: ∑ wn = 1 .
,··· ,
,1
w ∈ 0,
N2 − 1
N2 − 1
n=1
(
(26)
κ ∈K
λ ∈Λ
(27)
(28)
Every element u ∈ U2 consists of at most N2 linear line segments with knots at N1
possible outcome levels. Clearly, U2 ⊂ U2 and ηT approximates ηT from below as we
refine the partition (N1 , N2 → ∞). The appealing feature of ηT is that we can enumerate
N1 −1
1
(N2 + i − 1) elements of U2 for a given partition, and, for every
all N3 := (N −1)!
∏i=1
1
u ∈ U2 , solve the two embedded maximization problems in (26) using LP:
Proposition 1. Let
25
References
N1
c0,n :=
∑ (c1,m+1 − c1,m) zm;
(29)
m=n
N1
c1,n :=
∑ wm ;
(30)
m=n
N := {n = 1, · · · , N1 : wn > 0}
[
{N1 } .
(31)
For any given u ∈ U2 , supλ ∈Λ EFT u X T λ is the optimal value of the objective function of the following LP problem in canonical form:
T
max T −1 ∑ yt
(32)
t=1
s.t. yt − c1,n XtT λ ≤ c0,n , t = 1, · · · , T ; n ∈ N ;
M
∑ λi = 1;
i=1
λi ≥ 0, i = 1, · · · , M;
yt free, t = 1, · · · , T.
The proof is in the Online Appendix of Arvanitis et al. (2017). The LP problem always
has a feasible and finite solution and has O(T + M) variables and constraints, making
it small for typical data dimensions. Our application is based on the entire available
history of monthly investment returns to a standard set of benchmark assets (M = 11,
T = 1, 062), and uses N1 = 10 and N2 = 5. This gives N3 = 9!1 ∏9i=1 (4 + i) = 715 distinct
utility functions and 2N3 = 1, 430 small LP problems, which is perfectly manageable with
modern-day computer hardware and solver software.
The total run time of all computations for our application amounts to several working
days on a standard desktop PC with a 2.93 GHz quad-core Intel i7 processor, 16GB of
RAM and using MATLAB with the external Gurobi Optimizer solver.
26
Tables and Figures
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics of daily returns
Asset
S&P 500
Bond Index
1m Libor
Bitcoin
Ethereum
Ripple
Litecoin
Mean
Standard Deviation
Skewness
Kurtosis
Sharpe ratio
0.00045
0.00010
0.000003
0.00760
0.01465
0.01338
0.00940
0.00782
0.00195
0.00001
0.04558
0.10171
0.10145
0.07770
-0.40137
-0.31009
0.42899
0.62145
0.86734
4.73490
3.31961
4.24918
1.37703
-1.11955
5.64741
11.3222
36.42765
24.30942
0.05371
0.037313
0.16604
0.14375
0.13163
0.12064
Entries report the descriptive statistics on daily returns for the alternative asset classes used in this study. The
average return, the standard deviation, the skewness, the kurtosis, as well as the Sharpe ratio are reported.
The dataset covers the period from August 7, 2015 to December 29, 2017.
Table 2: Out-of-sample performance: Non-parametric stochastic dominance test
Quartile
25% p-value
50% p-value
75% p-value
Panel A
Traditional vs Augmented
Panel B
Traditional vs Augmented
0.031
0.050
0.126
0.028
0.056
0.144
Entries report quartile p-values from the distribution of p-values across 233 out-of-sample periods with the
null hypothesis that the augmented with cryptocurrencies optimal portfolio does not second order stochastically dominate the optimal portfolio of only traditional assets. Panels A reports the results when the
traditional set includes the S&P 500 Equity Index, the Barclays US Aggregate Bond Index and the 1-month
Libor, while panel B reports the results when the traditional set includes additionally the SMB and HML
indices, as well as the Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and the Vanguard small-cap index
funds.
27
Cumula2ve
Returns
300
250
200
150
28
100
50
0
9/1/16
10/1/16
11/1/16
12/1/16
1/1/17
2/1/17
3/1/17
4/1/17
5/1/17
Augmented
6/1/17
7/1/17
8/1/17
9/1/17
10/1/17
11/1/17
12/1/17
Tradi2onal
Figure 1: Cumulative performance of the traditional optimal portfolio as well as the optimal augmented portfolio with cryptocurrencies for
the entire sample period from 09/01/2016 to 12/29/2017.
Cumula2ve
Returns
300
250
200
150
29
100
50
0
9/1/16
10/1/16
11/1/16
12/1/16
1/1/17
2/1/17
3/1/17
4/1/17
5/1/17
Augmented
6/1/17
7/1/17
8/1/17
9/1/17
10/1/17
11/1/17
12/1/17
Tradi2onal
Figure 2: Cumulative performance of the traditional optimal portfolio when the traditional asset class also includes the SMB and HML indices,
the Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and the Vanguard small-cap index funds, as well as the optimal augmented portfolio with
cryptocurrencies, for the entire sample period from 01/09/2016 to 12/29/2017.
Table 3: Out-of-sample performance: Parametric portfolio measures
Panel A
Traditional
Performance Measures
Sharpe ratio
Downside Sharpe Ratio
UP ratio
Portfolio Turnover
Return Loss
Opportunity Cost
Exponential Utility
ARA=2
ARA=4
ARA=6
Power Utility
RRA=2
RRA=4
RRA=6
0.11762
0.12986
0.67490
9.566%
0.1856%
Augmented
0.18728
0.39570
1.04188
4.530%
Panel B
Traditional
0.14468
0.16437
0.68556
13.247%
0.1778%
1.125%
1.127%
1.126%
1.211%
1.255%
1.279%
1.134%
1.140%
1.139%
1.278%
1.256%
1.249%
Augmented
0.18728
0.39570
1.04188
4.530%
Entries report the performance measures (Sharpe ratio, Downside Sharpe ratio, UP ratio, Portfolio Turnover,
Returns Loss and Opportunity Cost) for the traditional and the augmented with cryptocurrencies asset
classes. The results for the opportunity cost are reported for different degrees of absolute risk aversion
(ARA=2,4,6) and different degrees of relative risk aversion (RRA=2,4,6). The dataset spans the period
from August 7, 2015 to December 29, 2017. In Panel A the traditional set includes the S&P 500 Equity
Index, the Barclays US Aggregate Bond Index and the 1-month Libor. In Panel B the traditional set includes additionally the SMB and HML indices, the Russell 2000 equity index, the Vanguard value and the
Vanguard small-cap index funds.
30
Table 4: Test for Market Integration
Predictor
Asset
Bitcoin
Ethereum
Ripple
Litecoin
S&P 500
Barclays
Bond Index
Dividend
Yield
Junk Bond
Yield
Term
Spread
Money
Growth
Baltic Dry
adjusted
R2
F
-0.210
(-1.621)
-0.102
(-0.662)
-0.290
(-1.914)
-0.232
(-1.197)
0.448
(3.359**)
-0.130
(-0.249)
0.111
(0.721)
0.087
(0.622)
0.097
(0.538)
0.087
(0.643)
-0.362
(-2.230**)
0.088
(0.307)
-0.083
(-0.549)
-0.059
(-0.345)
-0.099
(-0.502)
-0.101
(-0.715)
-0.057
(-0.429)
0.181
(1.921*)
-0.009
(0.094)
-0.010
(-0.134)
0.011
(0.185)
-0.029
(-0.336)
-0.072
(-0.815)
-0.171
(-0.697)
0.081
(0.814)
0.033
(0.027)
-0.007
(-0.073)
0.051
(0.601)
0.064
(0.706)
-0.006
(-1.453)
0.01
1.004
(0.418)
0.185
(0.968)
1.758
(0.128)
1.542
(0.182)
3.047
(0.013)
14.551
(0.008)
0.03
0.05
0.02
0.11
0.22
Predictive regressions are run to implement Campbell and Hamao (1992) test for market integration. Dependent variables for the regressions are the weekly excess returns on cryptocurrencies, equity and bond indices. The independent
variables are the instrumental variables lagged one week: the dividend yield, the junk bond premium (or default
spread) defined as the excess of the yield on long-term BAA corporate bonds rated by Moody’s over the yield on
AAA-rated bonds, the term spread defined as the difference between the AAA yield and the one-month Bill rate, the
money supply growth, and the growth in the Baltic Dry Index. A constant term is included in all regressions. The Table
reports standardized coefficient estimates with autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics in parentheses.
The adjusted R2 is reported and the F-statistic with the respective p-values in parentheses. The dataset spans August
2015- December 2017. * and ** asterisks indicate that the coefficient estimates are statistically significant at 10% and
5% significance level .
31
BANK OF GREECE WORKING PAPERS
226.
227.
228.
229.
230.
231.
232.
233.
234.
235.
236.
237.
238.
239.
240.
241.
242.
243.
Mamatzakis E.C. and A.N. Vu, “The interplay between quantitative easing and
risk: the case of the Japanese banking”, May 2017.
Kosma, T., E. Papapetrou, G. Pavlou, C. Tsochatzi and P. Zioutou, “Labour Market
Adjustments and Reforms in Greece During the Crisis: Microeconomic Evidence
from the Third Wave of the Wage Dynamics Survey”, June 2017.
Gibson D.H, and G. Pavlou, “Exporting and Performance: Evidence from Greek
Firms”, June 2017.
Papaspyrou S. T. “A New Approach to Governance and Integration in EMU for an
Optimal Use of Economic Policy Framework - Priority to Financial Union”, June
2017.
Kasimati, E. and N. Veraros, “Is there accuracy of forward freight agreements in
forecasting future freight rates? An empirical investigation, June 2017.
Rompolis, L., “The effectiveness of unconventional monetary policy on risk
aversion and uncertainty”, June 2017.
Mamatzakis, C. E., and A. Kalyvas, “Do creditor rights and information sharing
affect the performance of foreign banks?”, July 2017.
Izquierdo M., J. F. Jimeno, T. Kosma, A. Lamo, S. Millard, T. Rõõm, E. Viviano,
“Labour market adjustment in Europe during the crisis: microeconomic evidence
from the wage dynamics network survey”, September 2017.
Economides, G., D. Papageorgiou, and A. Philippopoulos, “The Greek Great
Depression: a General Equilibrium Study of its Drivers”, September 2017.
Dellas, H., D. Malliaropulos, D. Papageorgiou, E. Vourvachaki, “Fiscal Policy with
an Informal Sector”, October 2017.
Dellas, H., G.S., Tavlas, “Milton Friedman and the case for flexible exchange rates
and monetary rules”, October 2017.
Avramidis, P., I. Asimakopoulos, D., Malliaropulos, and N.G. Travlos. “Group
affiliation in periods of credit contraction and bank’s reaction: evidence from the
Greek crisis”, December 2017.
Karadimitropoulou, A., “Advanced Economies and Emerging Markets: Dissecting
the Drivers of Business Cycle Synchronization”, December 2017.
Bussiere, M., A. Karadimitropoulou, and M. A. León-Ledesma, “Current Account
Dynamics and the Real Exchange Rate: Disentangling the Evidence”, December
2017.
Moratis, G., and P. Sakellaris, “Measuring the Systemic Importance of Banks”,
December 2017.
Anyfantaki, S., S. Kalyvitis, M. Katsimi, and E. Thomaidou, “Export Pricing at the
Firm Level with Panel Data”, February 2018.
Alexakis. D. P., I.G. Samantas, “Foreign Ownership and Market Power: the Special
Case of European Banks”, February 2018.
Petropoulos, A., V. Siakoulis, D. Mylonas and A. Klamargias, “A Combined
Statistical Framework for Forecasting Default Rates of Greek Financial
Institutions’ Credit Portfolios., March 2018.
32