DEVALUATION AND ITS IMPACT ON
ECONOMIC GROWTH OF ETHIOPIA
ODA BULTUM UNIVERSITY
COLLEGE OF BUSSINESS AND ECONOMICS
DEPARTEMENT OF ECONOMICS
A Research Paper Conducted and Prepared
By:
Abdella Mohammed Ahmed (M.Sc.)
And Submitted to
Department of Economics
TITLE: DEVALUATION AND ITS IMPACT ON ECONOMIC GROWTH
OF ETHIOPIA
JULY, 2024
CHIRO, ETHIOPIA
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
My outstanding thank goes to Allah since He did great things for me throughout all my
life progression. I am thankful for my advisor Assistance professor Debala Bonsa and Dr.
Leta Sera for their tireless reading and commenting me starting from the proposal writing
of this thesis which enabled and directed me to the completion of this paper. Without
their intellectual comments and guidance this paper would not have such good shape. I’m
also grateful for Mr Dawit Abdisa, And Dr. Yekin Ahmed. for assisting me when I
working this paper in providing information of E-view software running, for helping me
in providing some necessary material of reading, and intellectual comments. Moreover I
am grateful for all my friends those who helped me in writing this thesis and other
essential support.
Lastly I am thankful for my mother Khadija Mohammed as her support and moral
throughout my previous life time really enabled me reach on this achievement. My today
level attainment is one of the realizations of what she had been envisioned for me at my
early age and guided me through this triumphant life.
1
Acronyms
ADF:
Augmented Dickey Fuller
BOP:
Balance of Payment
DCs:
Developed countries
DF:
Dickey Fuller
DGP:
Data Generating Process
DW:
Durbin Watson
ECM:
Error Correction Model
EPRDF:
Ethiopia People Revolutionary and Democracy Front
LDCs:
Least Developed Countries
IMF:
International Monetary Fund
MEDAC:
Ministry of Economic Development and Cooperation
MOFED:
Ministry of Finance and Economic Development
Ms:
Money Supply
NBE:
National Bank of Ethiopia
OLS:
Ordinary Least Square
REER:
Real Effective Exchange Rate
RGDP :
Real Government Investment
RPI:
Real Private Investment
TOT:
Terms of Trade
TGE:
Transitional Government of Ethiopia
2
Abstract
This paper uses annual data for the period 1980-2009 to investigate the
impact of devaluation on economic growth of Ethiopia using time series
econometrics techniques. According to the traditional theory, it is expected
that devaluation of domestic currency generally decreases the relative
price of domestically produced goods and thereby stimulate demand for
domestic export. Hence, the devaluation of currency can be expected to
have expansionary effect on real output in Ethiopia. So this study uses
more rigorous empirical model and econometric methodology and examines
the impact of currency devaluation on economic growth of Ethiopia. The
empirical result finds it devaluation exerts negative impact on economic
growth of Ethiopia.
Key Words: Devaluation, Impact, Economic Growth
3
CHAPTER ONE
1. INTRODUCTION
1.1 Background of the Study
Ethiopia is mainly known with her natural environments and the size of
its population stands third in the continents. Nevertheless, the economic
and the social indicators show that it is at last bottom in the world. It is
significantly attributed to the man-made calamities (Such as civil war
and poor economic policy), natural calamities (recurrent appearance of
the drought) and external shocks (Sentayehu, 1996).
The GNP per capita of the country was birr 217.97 in 1994 which was
the lowest in the world.
Infant mortality is 111 per 1000 and life
expectancy is 16 years, health service covers only 45 percent of the
population. Malnutrition is rampant with daily per capital claries of 1000
only, about 12 percent of the rural and 80 percent of urban population
have access to the safe drinks water. The average growth rate of the real
gross domestic product (RGDP) was about 2.21 percent from 1964-1995.
The growth of population which was about 2.9 percent per annum was
higher than of the real GDP. It indicated that the growth rate of per
capita income is decelerating. It also depicted that the performance was
less than the average developing and African countries (Getachew, 1995).
The major underlying cause for decelerating of the growth rate of
aggregate output was the poor performance agricultural sector that
dominates the Ethiopian economy. It was the largest employer and
foreign exchange earner. In contrast to its size the state of development
of agricultural sector was abysmally low. It was characterized by large
subsistence sub sector and extremely low productivity. The system did
not implement high yield seed, fertilizer, and pesticides, etc and coupled
4
with backward agricultural land tenure system (Eshetu, and Mekonnen,
1992).
If the process had continued without appropriate macroeconomic policy,
its exports would have been declined and its reserved would have
debited. The contractionary macroeconomic policy could be considered
as remedy for overviewed currency, however, it entails casts i.e.
reduction of output and employment. The other remedy for those
outlined problem is to devalue the currency. The government adopted the
second remedy as a solution in October 1992.
In the post 1992 period was a period of a recovery and stabilization for
the economy one of the major economic aims of the EPRDF regime,
which come to power in May 1991, was the stabilization and adjustment
of the distorted economic structure. In an attempt to cushion the
escalating economic problems, the government declared a new economic
policies and structural adjustment program component embracing a
substantial correction of the overvalued nominal exchange rates,
decontrol of any prices, liberalization of the foreign trade, autonomy of
state
owned
enterprise
and
privatization
of
small
and
medium
enterprises, financial market reform, liberal investment code with an
investment authority that is organized as “one-stop shop” as opposed to
command economic system to the previous regime. The private sector is
presumed to play a leading role in the growth and development process
of the country while the state is to be the facilitator and regulator of
these activities (Befekadu, 1999).
With such changeable policy environments, the growth rate of GDP had
been positive for the periods 1991/92-2002/03 after the politically
unstable year of 1991/92, it was only in the year 1997/98 and 2002/03
that a negative growth of -1.4% is and -3.8% was recorded respectively
on average, the economy has been growing at about 4 percent for the
5
same period. However, the gains in growth of per capita terms during
this period were just recoveries in fact the level of per capita real GDP did
not repeat the highest level which had been achieved in 1982/83
(Berhunu and Seid, 2001). Therefore the concern of this study is to
assess the impact of the second remedy: devaluation on the Ethiopian
economy.
1.2 Statement of the Problem
Like many African countries Ethiopia faced serious economic crisis in the
mid 1970‟s and the entire decade of 1980‟s. This economic crisis has
manifested itself in various forms such as social growth rate of GDP was
(2.4 percent per annum in the period 1973 to 1985), negative growth rate
of per capita income and increasing balance of payment deficit.
Agricultural output growth rate was lower than population growth rate.
Hence the country had to either in part basic necessities or to depend on
external donations (Asmorem, 1992).
However, after the fall of “Derge” a new government came to power in
May 1991. The Transitional Government of Ethiopia (TGE), to mitigate
the general economic problem, began implementing the comprehensive
macroeconomic and structural reforms. Devaluation of the Ethiopian birr
against the standard currency (dollar) was one of the under taken
measure in order to stabilize the economy in October 1992, the birr was
devaluated by about 142% in dollar terms i.e. from birr 2.07 /USD to
birr 5.00/ USD. Since then, in the process, the exchange rate of birr has
been
depreciated
overtime
and
reached
to
birr/USD=13.63.
On
September 1, 2010, for the second time, the birr was devaluated by
about 20% in dollar term i.e. from birr 13.63/USD to birr 16.35/USD.
The objective of devaluation, according to the TGE, stated to improve the
current account balance. The rationale for the said objective was set as
6
most of the Ethiopian exportable items unlike other Africa countries can
be used in domestic consumption (coffee, oil seeds and oil nuts) by
making foreign markets more attractive than domestic market, the
volume of export increase, to encourage the production of exportable by
shifting resources from non-tradable to tradable by making exportable
items cheaper (Sentayehu, 1996).
There is hot controversy weather devaluation would result in improving
the current account balance and make competitive in the external trade
by increasing the volume of export, decreasing the import bills,
eliminating market distraction and to have economic growth (MEDAC,
1997/8).
Most studies revealed that devaluation will improve the balance of
payment. But it has little ability to further objective of reducing inflation
and stimulating growth (Killick khan and the world bank, 1993). Mostley,
Harrigan and Toye undertook a study on the impact of devaluation in
1991. Their finding indicated that devaluation had no measurable impact
on the real GDP, positive impact on export growth, and the balance of
payment and negative impact on investment levels. The study conducted
by Edward (1986), show that devaluation is contractionary in the first
year and the effect is completely reversed in the second year. According
to these estimates, devaluation is neutral in the medium to long run.
Therefore the studies described above show that there is divergence in
effectiveness of devaluation on the growth of the economy. Thus this
study will attempt to examine the contribution of devaluation in the
trade balance and the impact of devaluation on economic growth.
7
1.3 Objective of the Study
The general objective of the study is to evaluate the impact of devaluation
on the growth of the Ethiopia economy. The specific objectives of the
study are: To identify the contribution of devaluation on trend of trade
balance.
To examine the relationship between devaluation and GDP growth.
Based on the results it tries to provide important recommendation
and to predict about the impact of current devaluation on
Ethiopian economic growth.
1.4 Methodology and Data Source
Data Type and Sources
To achieve the above mentioned objectives of the study, the paper
employed only secondary data which are obtained from various
publications of National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE), Ministry of Finance and
Economic Development (MOFED), Central Statistical Authority (CSA) and
Ethiopia Investment Authority. The data on Gross National Product
(GDP) and terms of trade are obtained from National Bank of Ethiopia
(NBE) and Central Statistical Authority (CSA). National Bank of Ethiopia
(NBE) and ministry of Finance and Economic Development are the
source for data on Export, Import, money supply (Ms) and Real Effective
Exchange Rate (REER). The data on Real Private Investment and Real
Government
Investment
are
collected
Authority.
8
from
Ethiopia
Investment
Method of Data Analysis
The data collected from those sources can be analyzed by using both
descriptive statistics and time-serious econometrics. The descriptive
method of data analysis is based on the empirical data using percentage,
tabulations and graphs. In addition to the descriptive method, the time
serious data will be used to analyze the impact of devaluation on
economic growth and to choose a set of variables that determine
Ethiopian economic growth.
1.5 Significance of the Study
It is known that the performance of the external economic sector was less
competitive during the military regime. This can be attributed to the bad
policies followed by the then government. Fixing the exchange rate
without taking into account the value of birr (over valuation of currency),
and restriction of the private sector from taking part in the foreign trade
sector are some of the major bad policies. To avert bad condition created
by these policy instruments, the government of Ethiopia has taken much
reform. Among which, devaluation is one which aimed to promote the
external balance via promoting export and discouraging imports.
Now some years have passed after the introduction of devaluation and an
assessment is necessary to be made so as to evaluate the impact of
devaluation on economic growth of Ethiopia. Having this in mind a brief
discussion is going to be made on the chapter that follows.
1.6 Limitation of the Study
The major limitation from this study is, since the study is entirely
depend on those secondary data which are collected from different
9
organizations, the process has faced some challenges due to luck of
timely published essential documents and even availability of the existed
one. In addition to this, the financial and time constraints are another
limitation to the study.
1.7 Organization of the Paper
The remaining part of the paper is organized in six chapters. Chapter two
reviews the theoretical and empirical aspects about the relationship
between devaluation and economic growth, particularly in the Ethiopian
economy. The third chapter will be about result of the study, which
covers descriptive method. The forth chapter is about the result of a
study, which covers econometrics method. The fifth chapter, which
covers econometrics analysis. The last chapter will be the conclusion and
recommendation.
10
CHAPTER TWO
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1 Theoretical Literature Review
2.1.1 Theory of devaluation
There are three approaches to see the effect of devaluation on the current
account. These are the elasticity approach, the absorption approach and
the monetary approach.
2.1.1.1 The elasticity approach
The elasticity approach is the change in the trade balance resulting from
a depreciation or devaluation and depending on the price elasticity of
demand for the nation‟s exports and imports. In this approach, only
relative commodity prices were considered important to determine the
possible effectiveness of devaluation. All that was considered necessary
to know the price elasticity of the demand for and supply of goods and
services imported and exported by a country (Mannur, 1983).
The elasticity approach makes use of the Marshal Learner condition i.e.
Ex + EM > 1, where Ex is the elasticity of demand for the devaluating
country‟s export and Em is its elasticity of demand for imports. But
using the elasticity approach to see the impact on export and import of a
devaluating country is not without limitation. First, it assumes point
elasticity; however there may be a non-marginal devaluation care which
improves the balance of payment. Second, the marshal-Lerner condition
uses fixed demand and supply curves contrast to this, the income effect
of marginal devaluation are not negligible (Sodersten and Reyree, 1994).
The above mentioned limitations may not inhibit form using the elasticity
approach. That is some adjustment is possible by assuming arc rather
11
than point elasticity and through the action of government to neutralize
the income effects.
It is argued that elasticity of both demand and supplies arc responsive in
the long run than in the short run. This implies trade volumes will take
some time to adjust to their new equilibrium position. Thus it seems that
the Marshall Lerner condition is satisfied in the long run than in short
run. In other words, devaluation may worse the condition of the balance
of payment initially. This can be clearly showed using what is called the
J-curve effect (Ibid).
Surplus
Time
Deficit
J – Curve effect
Table 2.1
If Marshall-Lerner condition is not satisfied in the long run either, then
the graph shown above fatten out at a deficit greater than that before
devaluation.
12
2.1.1.2 The monetary approach
The monetary approach says that any improvement in the balance of
payment brought by devaluation is transitory and disequilibrium in the
money market is a prime cause for the disequilibrium settled in the
balance of payment (Sodersten and Geoffreyree, 1994). This can best
explain in the diagram that follows.
Money
PPP
Price
As1
M (D1)
M2
P2
P2
M1
P1
P1
M (D1)
R1
R2
Reserve
Y1
Real Income
E1
E2
Exchange
rate
Table 3.2 Devaluation under the monetary approach
Suppose the domestic currency is devalued, so that the exchange rate
becomes E2, as a result domestic goods become competitive and hence
the demand for domestic currency bids up both domestically and abroad.
That calls for the demand for money to shift to M2. This also created a
surplus of balance of payment that causes domestic currency to
appreciate but to reserve such trends concerned parties may like to
purchase foreign currency. But that increases the level of reserve and
hence the money supplies. The increment in the money supply will shift
prices upward and such trend continues till price equals to P2 where
money supply and demand are equal at M2.
2.1.1.3 The absorption approach
The absorption approach, developed by Sidney Alexander, takes a macro
approach to the question of devaluation. Alexander thought that the
13
conventional micro approach is in adequate in so far as it ignores the
income effect of devaluation. Devaluation affects domestic economic
variables such as consumption, investment and national income, and
this has to be taken into account predicting the results of devaluation on
the Bop situation of a country. This is denoted algebraically as follows.
Y= C+Id+G+X-M ………. National income equation ………. (1)
Equation (1) can be rewrite as X-M=Y - (C+Id+G) ……. (2)
Where G= government budget deficit
C= consumption expenditure
Id= Investment expenditure
X= Export
M= Import
(X-M)= Trade balance (net export)
Equation (2) can further be written B= Y-A
Where- B-denotes trade balance (net export)
-
A- absorption of the economy (C+Id+G)
Some components of absorption will be affected by output indirectly
through the act of devaluation while other components are directly
affected by devaluation. Such components are denoted in equation
directly affected by devaluation.
This is algebraically shown by
da= ady+dD
But the change in current account due to devaluation is given by dB= dydA. Then dB = dy – ady – dD = (1-a) dy – dD.
NB:
“a” = Marginal propensity to absorb lies between “o” and “1”
14
2.1.2 The link between devaluation and economic growth
There was no serious controversy over the possible effect of devaluation
or economic growth until the Late 1970s. The dominant view up to that
period was that devaluation would improve trade balance, alleviate
balance of payment difficulties and accordingly expand output and
employment. The mechanism behind these positive effects is that
devaluation switches demand from imports and makes export industries
more competitive in international market by stimulating domestic
production of tradable goods and inducing domestic industries to use
more domestic inputs (Christopoulos, 2004).
The most traditional argument in favor of negative effect of real
appreciation up on economic growth it based on the assumption that real
exchange
rate
appreciation
deteriorates
the
competitiveness
of
enterprises vis-avis their foreign competitors and therefore and therefore
decrease exports. This deterioration diminishes thus the profit of the
export sector in favor of service and agriculture, largely protected from
foreign competition. It decreases industrial self-financing and the will to
invest in the industrial sector and more generally in the tradable good
sector. If the tradable sector is the most efficient and innovating, real
appreciation may act negatively on growth, beyond its impact on mainly
exporting firms. Real appreciation is particularly bad for growth in
developing countries because it doesn‟t allow promoting the small and in
efficient tradable sector, which suffer disproportionately from the
institutional and market failure (Rodrik, 2008).
The issue of devaluation has long been a major item in the economic and
political agendas of LDCs. These countries needed to devalue their
currency for a verities of reasons, including correcting the price of
distortions and getting the price for the market forces to function
properly and changing the relative price of traded to non-traded goods,
15
hence increasing competitiveness in the foreign markets. As a result, it
would be possible to decrease foreign trade difficult and improve the
balance of payment and above all, to achieve available economic growth.
Needless to say, increasing the rate of growth of output is a crucial for
economic development output growth is essential for LDCs in order to
raise national income per capita, achieve high standard of living for their
population and close the development gap between themselves and the
industrialized countries (Nwanna, 1994).
2.1.3 The Link between Devaluation and Output
There are two views regarding the relationship between devaluation and
output. The first one is the traditional view that is optimistic in a sense
that it is expansionary rather than being contractionary. The reasons in
favor of this argument are devaluation promotes production of tradable,
it has expenditure switching effect, higher export and in an improvement
of the external position of the country in question. From analytical point
of view, devaluation can affect the real sector of the economy through a
number of channels. This theory also argues that devaluation will either
have an expansionary effect on aggregate output, or in the worst of cases
it will leave aggregate output unaffected. If there is utilized capacity,
nominal devaluation will be expansionary, and total aggregate output will
increase on the other hand, if the economy is operating under full
employment, the nominal devaluation will be translated into equiproportional increases in prices with the real exchange rate and
aggregate output will not be affected (Sentayehu, 1996).
The other view is that, devaluation has contractionary effect through a
number of channels one is redistribution of income from those with high
marginal propensity to consume to those with high marginal propensity
to save. The other way through which devaluation has contractionary
effect arises from temporary disequilibrium in the money market. As
16
devaluation entails high inflation, it in turn calls for high demand for
money and people prefer to hold financial asset to hold goods. But that
had adverse impact in the demand for goods. In contrast to this,
devaluation also motivates the production of goods domestically through
a number of channels. One instance is the condition of acute shortage of
foreign currency, which link domestic production that involves extensive
use of imported intermediate goods. However, devaluation can be taken
as remedy for the shortage of foreign currency through the promotion of
export (Ahamed, 1988).
The link between devaluation and output can also be seen from both the
supply and demand side of the economy on demand side, devaluation
will increase the price at which tradable goods are sold items of domestic
currency and decline their price in terms of foreign currency; in short it
increases the demand for tradable goods. The effect of devaluation on
non-tradable goods is less clear. Demand for such goods emanates from
domestic private consumption, private investment and public sector
spending (Maria, 1989).
Even if devaluation has a contraction effect on non-traded goods, these
effects can be offset by a number of contrary factors. The wealth effect
would weaken if the privates sector‟s assets were indexed to the price
level. In addition, its effect on trade reduces to some extent through a
decline in the real value of other taxes because of the rise in prices and a
lag into tax collection. With regard to private investment, the effect of
devaluation lowers as the price of outputs bid up in the same direction
that of the price of imported capital and intermediate goods. The effect
will also weaken further as the real wage is likely to fall and that induces
and increase in capital expansion (Ibid).
On the supply side, devaluation brings about an increase domestic price
of imported inputs and in nominal wages in both sectors. The price of
17
imported inputs rises by the same proportion as the devaluation. The net
effect of demand and supply are likely to favor products of tradable goods
despite the rise in the production cost. But this assumes the increase in
nominal wage should not be excessive with regard to its effect on the
supply side of non-tradable goods, its outcome is less obvious. It depends
on the initial distortions and specific restriction that follows it (Ibid).
2.1.4 Devaluation and investment
Devaluation
affects
investment
through
many
channels.
Firstly,
devaluation alters the real supply of capital goods. Secondly, it affects
the real price of imported inputs, which are used in conjunction with
capital goods to produce output. Thirdly, devaluation has an impact on
the real product wage and thereby affects profitability and investment.
Fourthly, a devaluation produce changes in real income, which affects
the demand for domestically, produced goods. Finally, devaluation affects
nominal and real interest rates which in turn have an impact on
investment (Chibber and Shafik, 1990).
The net effects of devaluation on investment will therefore, be a
composite of several factors and is theoretically indetermination. The
short versus long-term effects of devaluation on private investment can
go in opposite directions. Even if the short run effects of devaluation are
negative because of increase in the real cost of imported capital and
inputs and contractionary demand effects of devaluation. The long run
effects on private investment still are positive as the economy respond to
increased competitiveness.
It is necessary to review the effect of devaluation on private investment in
a macroeconomic context. If devaluation is to achieve in primary
objectives of improving the trade balance, then for a given level of output,
domestic demand must fall
18
Y = Cp + Ip + Cg + Ig + (x-m)
Where Y = Fixed output level
Cp= private consumption
Ip= private investment
Cg= government consumption
Ig= government investment
X= Export and
M= Import
For fixed output level (Y) an increase in private investment (Ip) is possible
only if public expenditure (Cg + Ig) falls by more than the improvement in
the trade imbalance (X-M). If aggregate output falls, the short run effect
on private investment is likely to be negative. On the other hand if the
effect on output of devaluation is positive due to a strong and rapid
response. Form the tradable goods sectors; these negative effects can be
avoided. Even if these positive effects are not large enough to the short
run because of a weak supply response, the long run effects need to be
(Gaylor, 1971).
Finally the possible outcome of devaluation which is not given much
emphasis on many literatures is its psychological risky ness. To the
extent that devaluation is viewed as a sign of economic weakness, the
credit worthiness of the nation may be jeopardized. Thus, devaluation
may dampen investor confidence in the country‟s economy and hurt
country‟s ability to secure foreign investment (Davis, 1998).
2.1.5 Inflation and devaluation
There is a wide accepted consensus that inflationary situation set in
following devaluation. The reason is that it increases the price of tradable
goods in terms of domestic currency and the price of local goods
manufactured which use imported intermediate inputs. As the price of
19
machines and imported intermediate input bids up in terms of domestic
currency, it is no surprise that the price of these manufactured goods
goes up. But that calls for the shifts of consumers to non-tradable goods
away from tradable and non-tradable goods which uses imported
intermediate inputs. To this effect most developing nations are
increasingly
aware
of
keeping
their
external
competitiveness
via
devaluating their currency so as to make their export cheap in the world
market. But such targets are possible if a nominal devaluation brings
about the desired rate real devaluation of currency. But such act is not
always possible mainly because of the inflationary situation set in
following devaluation. Such situation are particularly sever for small
open economies as it brings inflation as a permanent feature and even
under some particularly circumstances leads to hyperinflation (Maria,
1989).
Devaluation is inherently inflationary. The impact is transmitted to
domestic price both directly through the higher price of imports
(consumer goods, fuel row materials and spare parts) as well as indirectly
through the higher demand arising from tradable sector. The pass
through would be higher the lower the elasticity of demand for imports
and import substituting goods (Befekadu and Kibre, 1992). In favor of
this Singh (1983) indicated the following.
The Chicago and Cambridge schools of economics which normally
have very different views about the functioning of the economic
system do agree on one point that the general is not a suitable
method for structural change and that its major consequence is to
generate inflation. The reasoning in each case if off course different
(Singh, 1983).
20
2.1.6 Nominal devaluation and aggregated demand
Krugman and Taylor (1978), identified three different factors of the
contractionary effects of a devaluation on aggregate demand and,
therefore, output.
a. If imports initially exceed exports, a nominal devaluation causes
the foreign currency payment to exceed receipts thus reducing the
real income at home and increasing it abroad. The larger the
initial trade deficit the greater the contractionary outcome.
b. Secondly, they note that if foreign trade is initially in balance,
devaluation raises prices of traded goods relative to home goods,
giving rise to wind fall profit in exports and import-competing
industries. If money wage lag the price increases and if the
marginal propensity to save from profit is higher than form wage,
national saving goes up thus reducing aggregate demand and
therefore output.
c. Thirdly, they argue that if there are existing advalorem taxes on
export and imports; devaluation redistributes income from the
private sector to the government which has a marginal propensity
to save close to unity. This reduces the aggregate demand.
Bird (1983), in addition to the above factors cites a fourth channel
through which devaluation may cause a reduction in aggregate demand.
Devaluation raises the domestic currency costs of servicing any given
external obligation expressed in foreign currency. In countries with large
volume of debt and high interest payment, devaluation may enhance
domestic expenditure reducing effect and thus output.
21
2.1.7 Nominal devaluation and aggregate supply
Wijinbergen and Edward (1986), identified three channels through which
a devaluation can result to contractionary through aggregate supply.
Wijinbergen points out that a contraction through the aggregate supply
may be worse than the one through the aggregate demand because of
inflationary effect while a reduction of the aggregate demand abate
inflation. The various channels are:a. Devaluation in the presence of intermediate imports increases the
cost of production of local firms. The increased cost of production
may force some of the firms to cut their production thus reducing
the aggregate supply.
b. If devaluation leads to inflation, the real volume of credit from the
banking sector is reduced. Whatever the source of working capital,
devaluation that is inflationary reduces the real value of working
capital and may have adverse effect on output.
c. A third channel that may lead to a cut on aggregate supply is if
real wage is indexed on imported consumer goods. Since
devaluation may cause a rise in the price of such products, it may
result in agitation of higher real wages.
2.1.8 Devaluation, current account deficit, and growth
One of the most important objectives of devaluation is to improve a
country‟s international competitiveness and foreign reserve. Devaluation,
by increasing the price of traded goods, i.e. the price of export in
domestic market and increasing the price of imports, creates conductive
environment to increase the supply of exports and decrease the level of
imports. The ultimate result of this depends on the elasticity of import
and export demand (Plane, 1990).
22
The significance of variation in elasticity varies from country to country.
Developing countries which rely heavily on a single product and the price
of which is quoted by a foreign currency, devaluation fails to reduce this
price and the export elasticity of demand. Therefore, it is largely
irrelevant. Devaluation raises the domestic currency price and the
profitability of exporting, there by imposing the importance of the
elasticity of supply (Sentayehu, 1996).
The impact of devaluation on export depends on slack in the export
sector, capacity utilization, investment (including crop expansion,
diversification, and gestation period), etc. While the increase in domestic
currency price are necessary, they are definitely not sufficient to increase
the volume of exportable other factors such as investor uncertainty,
expectation formation, availability of modern inputs, etc, are as, if not
more important as “getting price right”. Most importantly, the speed of
responses is of crucial significance. Where adjustment is not quick, the
inflationary impact of devolution undermines the real exchange rate thus
invalidating the comparative advantage it is expected to enjoy (Befekadu
and Kibre; 1998).
Another factor that would affect export prices are international prices.
Where the latter are depressed, the domestic currency price increase is
likely to be a once-and for-all phenomenon unless the initial devaluation
is followed by another and/or policies such as subsidy or tax reduction
are instituted to make up for diminishing benefit. But subsidy and tax
reduction would have implication for reducing government deficit. In the
short to medium run, both imports and import substituting goods are
unlikely to respond to changes in prices, given the structure of the
economy. If the policy succeeds in decreasing imports this is likely to
reduce capacity utilization and therefore output growth. Thus the
23
decrease in current account deficit would be at the cost of the growth of
the economy (Ibid).
With regard to imports, it is highly improbable that any developing
country will be able to influence the foreign price of its imports. Since its
demand for particular import will represent only a small fraction of the
total world demand for the producer. The domestic price of imports may
not rise to the full extent of devaluation if devaluation is accompanied by
the removal of import controls that has previously maintained import
prices at artificially high levels. Even in a country which has dual
exchange rate and the parallel market largely dominates the foreign
exchange market; devaluation may not change the imported price in
domestic price (Sentayehu, 1996).
2.2 Empirical Literature Review
The evidence regarding the impact of devaluation on real economic
activity is mixed: while some studies suggest that devaluations have an
expansionary effect, other indicates that they generate a contractionary
in the economy.
2.2.1 The Effect of Devaluation in Developed Countries
R.S Cott Hacker and Abdulnasser Hatemi (2004) tasted the trade Jcurve for three transition central European countries the Czech
Republic, Hungary and Poland in their bilateral trade with respect to
Germany. They find that three are some characteristics associated with a
J-curve effect for each country after a real or nominal depreciation the
export ratio briefly drops to below its initial value within a few months
and then rises to a long run equilibrium value higher than the initial one.
Connally (1983) considers a group of 22 countries and regresses the
change in the rate of real growth on the change in the nominal exchange
24
rate. The coefficient obtained was positive and marginally significant
providing some support to the hypothesis of expansionary devaluations.
Gylfason and Risager (1984) have developed a model for a small country,
which stresses the impact of devaluation on interest payments on the
foreign debt. Using the imputed parameter data, Gylfason and Risager
suggest that while devaluation is generally expansionary in Dcs.
Study made by younger (1992) approved that nominal devaluation leads
to an equally proportional rise in price in countries which follow free
market economy continuing his assertion he said once equilibrium
exchange rate is established, nominal devaluation causes price to rise by
the same amount of the change in nominal devaluation. While for the
case countries where the economy permits only limited competition, he
explained that nominal devaluation would not bring an equally
proportional rise in price. The reasons for such occurrence are two. First,
if the supply side of the foreign currency is considered, official exchange
rate are highly overvalued and their market allocation has very little to
do with market prices. Second, if the demand side is taken into account,
quantity restriction clears the market for foreign exchanges. Hence
nominal devaluation of currency may not have direct relation with prices.
In addition to the above mentioned reasons, nominal devaluation may
not have much impact on domestic price level even if it increases the
price of tradable because much of such items for example minerals are
not given due attention in local consumption basket.
Tumorsky (1981) analyzed the effect of devaluation under the condition
of rational expectations. According to this study, real output is
responsible to the unanticipated component of change in exchange rate.
In the short run devaluation which is under predicted will lead to a less
than proportionate increase in the price of domestic output, together
with an expansion in the real domestic activity. A devaluation which is
25
over predicted will lead to a more than proportionate increase in the price
of domestic output, causing the level of domestic output to fall. A
correctly anticipated devaluation will lead to an exactly proportionate
increase in the domestic price level, leaving the level of domestic really
output unaffected. Thus it is possible for devaluation to have a perverse
contractionary effect on the economy and this will be the case if it does
not measure up to previously held expectations.
Gylfodan and Schmidf (1983) have constructed a small macro model with
intermediate goods, where devaluation has two conflicting effects. On the
one hand, they generate an expansion through aggregate demand; on the
other hand, devaluation results through its effect on the cost of imported
intermediate inputs in an upward shift in aggregate supply schedule. The
implications of the models are analyzed by importing plausible values to
the corresponding parameters for a group of five developed countries and
five developing countries with the exception of the United Kingdom and
Brazil, these results suggest that, as postulated by the traditional theory,
devaluation have a positive effect on aggregate output.
2.2.2 The Effect of Devaluation in Developing Countries
Rodrik (2008) provide evidence from 184 countries over eleven 5- year
period from 1990-54 through 2000-24 and analyzed the effect of under
valuation and over valuation of currencies on stimulating economic
growth.
He
concludes
that
overvaluation
hurts
growth
while
undervaluation is good for growth. For most countries, high growth
periods are associated with undervalued currencies. Also he noted, there
is a little of nonlinearity in the relationship between a country‟s real
exchange rate and its economic growth. He represented that an increase
in undervaluation boosts economic growth just as well as a decreasing in
overvaluation. But this relationship holds only for developing countries.
The relative price of tradable to non tradable (real exchange rate) seems
to play a more fundamental role in the growth process.
26
Sheely (1988) found that devaluation have a negative impact on output
for 16 Latin American countries while Nunnenkamp and Schweickert
(1990) rejected the hypothesis of contractionary devaluation and found a
positive
relationship
between
currency
devaluation
and
output
expansions. But Upadhyaya (1999), did not find any significant long run
effect of currency devaluation on aggregate output for 4 out of 6 Asian
countries while he found contractionary effect for two countries. In
addition Christopoluos (2004) investigated the effect of currency
devaluation on output expansion in a sample of 11 Asian countries over
the period 1966-1949. He found that, in the Long run in out of 11
countries and for the panel as a whole, depreciation exerts a negative
impact on output growth while for 3 countries depreciation improves
growth prospects.
Edwards (1988) examined the effect of depreciation on production in 12
developing countries during 1965-1980 using the following regression.
Log Y a + Y1 time + B1 Log GE/y + B2 (∆ Lag M – ∆ log Me) + B3 Log ToT
+ B4 Log REt + Ut
In which Y is the real aggregate production, trend rate of real growth
rate. GE/Y ratio of nominal government spending, ∆ real rate of nominal
money growth, ∆ log Me expected rate of nominal money growth. ToT
term of trade, RE real exchange rate and u error term. He concluded that
depreciation of money had contracting effect on production in short run,
expansionary effect after a year and nothing in long run. The author
cited theoretical and logical reasons as follows, undervaluation of
currency leads to increase in the price level, decreasing effect on
household consumption spending (Pigou effect), and redistribution of
income from low to high saving rate, deteriorating trade balance and
creating stagnation. All of these caused to reduce aggregate demand
production.
In
addition
to
these
27
demand
side
effects,
currency
undervaluation would influence supply side via increasing import inputs
prices, decreasing aggregate supply and finally reduction of production.
Kruger (1972) discovered that the effect of devaluation on economic
growth depends crucially on what happened to export earnings through
she found very little evidence to suggest that devaluation leads to severe
recession of prolonged duration.
In a study of 8 LDCs, over the period of a two year post devaluation
period, Connany and Taylor (1976) found that prices of traded goods rose
by an amount approaching the extent of devaluation whilst prices in
general rose by less than half as much. In this study, a nominal
devaluation was found to be inflationary. Similar results were obtained in
the case of Turkey by Bnis and Uzmueur (1990) who employed an
interactive three stage least squares procedure using monthly data for
the period January 1981 to December 1987. In the case of Turkey the
devaluation for 35% of the inflation during the period of study.
Bragwat and Onisuka (1974) after having an empirical study in 46 Africa
countries which devalued their currencies, conclude that imports
continued to grow after devaluation and in majority of cases, the growth
rate exceeds the devaluation growth rate i.e. conditions that requires the
elasticity of export and import demand to be more than unity is not
satisfied. This is because of the very strong demand for imported
necessities and inelastic foreign demand for Africa export. Thus, with
relatively in elastic demand for export and import, devaluation has little
or no effect is changing trade balance in the context of Africa countries.
In the world Bank study (1993) essentially using before and after
approach, out of twenty-nine sub-Sahara Africa „adjusting‟ countries
fourteen had an improvement in GDP growth, whereas fifteen had
showed a decline between the period 1987-1991. The World Bank study
28
further confirms that in almost all cases, rate of growth, investment and
saving were not at levels required to sustainable development.
Using data from the period 1956-89, Balassa (1989) analyzed subSahara Africa (SSA) countries economic performance in general and
agriculture exports in particular. He found that a one percent change in
the real exchange rate is associated with a 0.8 to 1 percent change in the
ratio of exports to output SSA countries. Balassa also found that the
response of the export-output ratio to the real exchange rate changes for
SSA countries is higher than for other parts of the world. His evidence of
an export shares argues against the prevailing pessimistic view export
position using a CGE. (Control group approach and econometrics
approach) model for two Africa counties, Madagascar and Niger.
For Kenya, Branson (1986) has developed a small simulation model
which suggests that contrary to the traditional view, devaluation will
have important contractionary effects. Bransons model is one picturing
an economy with two sectors. One producing agricultural products that
are exported and not consumed domestically and has a low output
elasticity (this is the case with nearly all of Kenya‟s major export cropscoffee, tea and sisal). The second sector produces non traded export
goods using domestic factors and imported intermediate inputs, all of
which have low elasticity of substitution among them. In the event of a
terms of trade shock such as the one of 1979-1980. Bronson argues that
the appropriate policy would have been a reduction in absorption rather
than devaluation with low levels of wage indexation, the absorption cut
will have a much smaller effect on investment incentives and avoid
inflationary consequences associated with a devaluation which will
enable the country to maintain non-indexed wages. He concludes that
devaluation may not be on appropriate component of a stabilization
program in countries such as Kenya with an elastic supply of exports
29
and with intermediate imports. He, however, argues that devaluation
would be the appropriate policy for liberalization.
According to the study conducted by Abent (2004) using export and
import data from 1980/81-2000/01 and found that the long run static
media of export function responsiveness of export for a unit change in
real effective exchange rate (i.e. export elasticity) highly statistically
significant (2.148) while the long run static model of import function the
responsiveness of imports for a unit change in real effective exchange
rate (i.e. import elasticity) highly statistically insignificant (-1.838) has no
strong relation. Thus the sum of the two demand elastics in absolute
terms is 0.31 that is devaluation would result in worsening trade balance
accordingly marshal Lerner condition (MX+MM>1) to Ethiopia export and
import for the period 1980/81-2000/01 does not full filled.
Befekadu and Kibre (1994) analyzed the impact of devaluation on the
supply of coffee. According to them the supply response of coffee to
devaluation is not exciting in the short to medium run because of its
gestation period which at the minimum, extended over three years.
Second and most importantly, expected increase can materialize only if
we assume farmers price expectation to run a head of four years or more.
Given the host of uncertainties over hanging in the production process of
such perennial crops and experience of farmers regarding price volatility,
such an assumption is an over stretched one.
30
CHAPTER THREE
3. EXCHANGE RATE POLICY AND PERFORMANCE OF
FOREIGN TRADE OF ETHIOPIA
3.1 An overview of exchange rate policy in Ethiopia
Exchange rate policy involves choosing as exchange rate system and
determining the particular rate at which foreign exchange transactions
will take place. A country‟s exchange rate policy affects its relative price
structure in domestic currency terms between goods which are traded
internationally (tradable) and goods which are produced, for the domestic
market (non-tradable). Moreover, exchange rate policy will affect the
overall level of domestic price. For these reasons, the particular exchange
rate system and exchange rate level selected will have a widespread
impact on the entire economy.
In this part, we will attempt to review exchange rate policies and
exchange rate premium of Ethiopia.
3.1.1 Exchange rate policy
Before 1973 Ethiopian‟s exchange rate policy was in consonance with
international monetary fund (IMF) par value system. The exchange rate
was 2.48 Eth. Dollar per US dollar from July 23.1945 to December 31,
1963 on January 1st it was devalued to 2.5 Eth dollar per us dollar
(Jamin, 1994).
During the late 1960‟s, the relevance of the par value monetary system
based on us dollar come under question. The US dollar was floated and
ceased its convertibility to gold in December 1971. This situation led to
the devaluation of the U.S dollar by 79 percent in December 1971 under
Smithsonian agreement, gold price rose from $35 to $38 per ounce. The
31
Ethiopian dollar however remained unchanged in terms of gold. This is
effect meant a defacto revaluation of birr in terms of dollar.
Consequently, the Ethiopian birr exchange rate changed to 1 U.S dollar
equal to 2.30 Eth. Dollar (Almost 7.4 percent revaluation in terms of Eth.
Dollar). This rate served for the year 1971 and 1972. Not long after,
however, the US dollar once again came under pressure and was
devalued by 10 percent. The Ethiopian birr was almost revalued by 10
percent against US dollar. The exchange had become 1 US dollar = 2.07
birr (Birritu, 2001).
On February 23, 1973 the Ethiopian dollar has been changed to
Ethiopian birr. During this time the US dollar once again came under
pressure and was devalued by 10 percent; this is done to realign.
However, the Ethiopian birr was revalued by 10 percent against US
dollar. Therefore, the nominal exchange rate, that is official exchange
rate for almost eighteen years was 2.07 Ethiopian birr per US dollar until
October 1992, the exchange rate of Ethiopian currency against its
reference currency, the US dollar was determined by government decree.
Thus, up to the massive devaluation of official exchange rate of 1992 the
2.07 birr per US dollar was issued for external transaction purposes
(Ibid).
On October 1, 1992 National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE) was devalued the
Ethiopian birr by 142 percent in nominal terms or by 58 percent in real
dollar terms (Derresse, 1996). As a result of devaluation, exchange rate
was increased to 5 birr per US dollar. This rate used for about a year
until auction exchange rate was introduced. And also this rate was used
for all transaction purpose until May 1, 1993. After the introduction of
auction exchange rate, Ethiopia started to follow multiple exchange rate
policy. Exchange rates in operation during this time were official
exchange rate, auction exchange and the weighted average rate in
32
addition to the illegal parallel exchange rate. The official and weighted
average rates were determined by administrative means while the parallel
and auction exchange rate have been determined by market and quasi
market system respectively.
On July 15, 1995 national bank of Ethiopia (NBE) has unified auction
and official exchange rate. After unification, one official exchange rate
has been applicable to all imports that are auction exchange rate.
Auction exchange rate that Ethiopia followed is referred to Dutch auction
exchange rate system as it is a descending price auction where the
auctioneer calls starting from higher rate and each bidder gets the
amount requested at the rate he is willing to pay, until the allocated fund
is exhausted several important modification have been put in place to the
operation of the auction, the retail auction (where by the National Bank
of Ethiopia sells foreign exchange to final users) was replaced by whole
sale auction in September 1998. The whole sale auction is in operation
up to recent period.
The whole exchange rate policy since 1945 up to 2008/09 can be
summarized as in the following table.
33
Table 1: Exchange rate policy in Ethiopia (1945-2008/09)
Period
1945-1949
Nominal exchange rate
2.48
Policy
Rate linked to pound sterling and it was
based on IMF per value system
1949-1963
2.48
Rate delinked from pound sterling but
still based on IMF par value system
1964-1971
2.5
Fixed IMF par value system
1971-1973
2.3
International monetary fund (IMF) par
value system
1973-1992
2.07
Fixed exchange rate system and based
on IMF par value system. But in 1976
the Ethiopian dollar has changed to
Ethiopian birr.
1992-1993
5.0
Devaluation, but cradling pegs
1993-1995
Different rate
Multiple exchange rate policy (Ductch
auction exchange rate, official exchange
rate and marginal average rate)
1995-1998
Varies from time to time
Dutch auction exchange rate system
with retail auction
1998-2009
Varies from time to time
Dutch auction exchange rate system
with whole sale auction.
Source: National Bank of Ethiopia
3.1.2 Exchange rate premium
Even though there is no consensus among researchers about the
inception of the Ethiopian parallel market exchange rate, some are of the
34
opinion that it was non-existent or at its minimal level before the Derg
assumed power. Befekadu Degefe (1994) stated that the significance of
the illegal parallel market for foreign exchange has grown to the extent of
impairing the operation of the official foreign exchange market during the
post 1974 and particularly since 1980/81 fiscal years.
Hence, the parallel foreign exchange market activities in Ethiopia become
important in attracting traders and dealers, especially in the late 1980s,
particularly when franco-voluta imports were allowed. The premium
between the official and parallel market exchange rates depicted a
substantial increase over the years. For example, the premium, which
was about 93 percent in 1975/76, moved up to 206.5 percent in
1990/91. Hence, the parallel exchange rate premium continuously
expanded over the last two decades before the 1992 reform (See table 3).
However, after the introduction of the reform in 1997 in Ethiopia and
various exchange liberalization measures (devaluation, adoption of
foreign exchange auction system and opening of forex bureoux to engage
in retail transactions) took place, the margin of the premium began to
narrow. Most importantly, the banning of franco-valuta in late 1996 had
contributed much to the small premium in the exchange market.
The Ethiopian parallel foreign exchange market is a very volatile market
that, at times has showed a drastic fluctuation even after the economic
reform program of 1992. This high degree of volatility was due to both
social and economic factors.
35
Table 2: The official and parallel exchange rate (1975-2009)
Year
1975/76
1976/77
1977/78
1978/79
1979/80
1980/81
1981/82
1982/83
1983/84
1984/85
1985/86
1986/87
1987/88
1988/89
1989/90
1990/91
1991/92
1992/93
1993/94
1994/95
1995/96
1996/97
1997/98
1998/99
1999/00
2000/01
2001/02
2002/03
2003/04
2004/05
2005/06
2006/07
2007/08
2008/09
Official exchange
rate
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
2.07
5.00
5.00
5.95
6.25
6.35
6.71
7.12
8.1426
8.3279
8.5425
8.5809
8.6197
8.6518
8.6870
8.7943
9.2441
10.4205
Parallel exchange
rate
3.58
4.00
4.71
4.11
3.17
2.82
3.09
3.32
3.52
4.02
4.85
3.80
6.02
6.62
6.62
6.03
6.13
7.40
7.60
7.70
7.75
7.56
7.18
7.21
8.31
8.7914
8.6850
8.7091
8.6751
8.110
9.0258
8.9059
9.5569
11.8102
Premium
1.8261
1.9324
2.0338
1.9855
1.5314
1.3623
1.4928
1.6039
1.7005
1.9420
2.340
1.8502
2.9082
3.1981
3.1981
2.9130
3.0650
1.4808
1.5200
1.2941
1.2400
1.1905
1.0700
1.0126
1.102
1.532
1.67
1.49
0.64
0.68
3.97
1.85
3.38
13.34
Source: National Bank of Ethiopia
After the devaluation of 1992 exchange rate premium starts to decrease
as it is possible from the above table. But in 2008/09 this situation was
36
changed and the exchange rate premium started to widen. The
underlying cause for the flourish of the parallel exchange rate could be
cited that major consumer items started to be marked on the parallel
market.
3.2 The performance of the export sector of Ethiopia pre
and post devaluation
The relationship between export performance and economic growth has
been a subject of considerable interest to development economists in
recent
years.
Empirical
observation
across
countries
tended
to
demonstrate that developing countries with a favorable growth record
tended to enjoying higher rate of growth of national income. Obviously,
since exports are a companying of aggregate out put one would expect a
positive allocation in terms of the correlation coefficient. Therefore, to see
the trends of the export sector of Ethiopia, taking a comparison between
the periods of the pre devolution and post devaluation is essential in
order to appreciate the likely progress made in this same sector due to
devaluation.
37
Table 3: The Growth Rate of Export
Year
1979/80
1980/81
1981/82
1982/83
1983/84
1984/85
1985/86
1986/87
1987/88
1988/89
1989/90
1990/91
1991/92
1992/93
1993/94
Growth rate of quantity
exported
4.22
-2.54
-1.11
1.32
5.1
-3.41
-9.95
2.6
14.8
-12.8
-5.6
-20.8
-35.5
61.8
64.8
Year
1994/95
1995/96
1996/97
1997/98
1998/99
1999/00
2000/01
2001/02
2002/03
2003/04
2004/05
2005/06
2006/07
2007/08
2008/09
Growth rate of quantity
exported
10.7
16.7
8.2
-19.13
-16.78
9.7
12.5
44.25
-2.02
6.92
34.5
12.3
10.7
7.0
-1.5
Source: Own Computation from National Bank of Ethiopia
On the basis of table 3, the performance of export sector of Ethiopia is
analyzed as follows. Before September 1992 of devaluation period (i.e.
from 1999/80 – 1991/92), the growth rate of quantity exported was low
before the devaluation period except in 1987/88 with growth rate of 14.8
percent. But after the devaluation period of 1992/93, the growth rate of
quantity exported was increased by 61.8 and 64.8 for subsequent two
years. But this growth was declined for the remaining period as
compared to the above two periods showing. But on average the growth
rate was high (14.8) as compared to the pre devaluation period (-4.9).
Therefore we conclude that devaluation improved the performance of the
export sector of the country especially in the first three years after the
devaluation period.
38
3.3 The performance of the import sector before and after
devaluation
It is known fact that during the period of derg regime the growth rate of
export was low because the policies followed by that government were
hindrance to the development of the export sector. But after the coming
of new government and the introduction of devaluation increased the
growth rate of export. In the next section we discuss briefly on the import
side to determine whether the country is in good situation with regard to
the external economic performance.
Table 4: Growth rate of import
Year
Growth rate of quantity Year
Growth rate of quantity
imported
imported
1979/80 6.2
1994/95 37.8
1980/81 -4.4
1995/96 -37.4
1981/82 8.3
1996/97 37.4
1982/83 -4.2
1997/98 -5.8
1983/84 6.1
1998/99 32.5
1984/85 12.3
1999/00 11.3
1985/86 10.1
2000/01 8.4
1986/87 20.4
2001/02 -13.5
1987/88 -12.1
2002/03 25.5
1988/89 -6.1
2003/04 12.7
1989/90 71.5
2004/05 -10.2
1990/91 -24.1
2005/06 6.5
1991/92 -77.0
2006/07 26.14
1992/93 215.68
2007/08 3.44
1993/94 22.56
2008/09 14.17
Source: Own Computation from National Bank of Ethiopia
39
Note. The periods before and after 1992/93 are considered to see how
the import sector performance is before and after devaluation.
As it is seen form the above table 4, the import sector showed a declining
trend between 1979/80 – 1991/92 with an exception of 12.3, 10.1, 20.4
and 71.5 percent growth rate of quantity imported in 1984/85, 1985/86,
1986/87 and 1989/90 respectively. But after the devaluation the growth
rate of quantity imported showed an amazing increment (i.e. the growth
rate is 215.68% in 1992/93) and this is in contrary to the aim of
devaluation. The above table 4 also shows that the average growth rate of
quantity imported is 21.9%, which far greater than the pre evaluation
period (0.54). Therefore, devaluation is ineffective in reducing the growth
rate of quantity imported. To determine the external economic condition
of the country we need the aggregate interaction of import and export.
Empirical results show that the trade balance (export–import) of the
country is deteriorating overtime. However, devaluation is taken to
improve the condition of trade balance through promoting exports and
discouraging imports.
3.4 Trends of RGDP and REER
The ultimate policy objective of any country in general is to have
sustainable economic growth. However, the growth rate of RGDP during
the military government was low and this low growth rate of RGDP was
attributed to the poor performance of agricultural sectors. Agricultural
performance during the period not only discouraging in terms of its
magnitude, but also it is characterized by large degree of oscillation. The
main problems associated to agricultural sector were in appropriate to
market policy state determined price policies, politically forced peasant
cooperative producer and recumbent drought (Solomon, 2000).
40
Growth rate
Graph 1: Trends of real GDP and REER
As indicated in the figure 4, after the fall of military government the
Ethiopia‟s economy continues to register high growth rate. Ethiopia‟s
broad based economic growth continued for the sixty times in a row in
2008/09 putting the country in higher growth trajectory. The real GDP
grow at 9.9 percent in 2008/09 making Ethiopia area of the fastest
growth economies in the world despite world economic meltdown and
global financial crisis. With 42.6 percent share in real GDP, agriculture
and allied activities rose by 6.4 percent continuing 27.2 percent to the
overall economic growth recorded in the fiscal year.
On the above figure 4 the REER observed that there is no big change in
the value of the domestic currency. But as the inflation differential with
trading partners continued to widen, the real effective exchange rate
appreciated by 35 percent in 2008/09. The rate of appreciation however,
was slower during the second half of the fiscal year as a result of faster
depreciation in nominal exchange rate and lower inflation.
41
CHAPTER FOUR
4. ECONOMETRICS METHODOLOGY OF THE STUDY
In this research we emphasize time series analysis and the econometric
method concentrate on the discussion of some basic concept of time
series data.
4.1 Stationary and non-stationary series
When we deal with the stationary of variables we normally deal with
weak stationary as the strong stationarity is more of a theoretical
concept weak stationary is defined in terms of sample moments (mean
and variance). Xt is stationary, if.
1. E(xt)= N, i.e. the mean is independent of time which means as time
goes on the mean doesn‟t change.
2. Variance (Xt)-
2
< ∞ i.e. the variance exists or it is finite.
The whole idea of dealing with stationary and non-stationary series is to
avoid spurious regression which results from regressing non-stationary
variable on another. We can describe the spurious regression problem as
follows. If we have two random walk I (1) variable, xt and yt. Whose first
differences are given as Δyt
2y)
Δxt
2x)
and are also
assumed to be independent by construction, then in their linear
regression of the form yt= Bxt +εt we expect the value of B approach to
zero as the sample size increase so that tB ~ NID (1, 0). Due to the nonstationary properties of the variable, however, the sample moments will
not converge to constant as in the case of stationary variables. Rather,
the sample moment coverage to random variables which are functions of
wierier process. Therefore, in such regression instead of approaching to
zero, the t- statistics will approach two (Gujarati, 1998).
42
Hence we will be misleading if we use the t- distribution by wrongly
rejecting the null of no correlation between variables. As a rule of thumb,
as suggested by Granfer (1974), we suspect a spurious regression if we
have R2 greater than Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics. To avoid the
problem of spurious regression, we can either change the data to make it
stationary before conducting a regression or use the technique of cointegration. Therefore, in any time series analysis the first thing we have
to do is to test the variables involved is a regression for unit roots.
4.2 Tests for unit roots
The test has been performed using Dickey fuller (DF) and Augmented
Dickey Fuller (ADF) technique.
A. The Test for unity root
If we assume the data generating process (DGP) to be given by yt= ρyt-1 +
…. (1).
Where εt~
2),
the DF test is to test on the size of the coefficient ρ.
That is, whether ρ=1 or not (Adam, 1992).
If we subtract yt-1 from both sides of equation (1), we get Δyt = πyt-1+εt …2
Where π = ρ-1. The null hypothesis is H0: π = 0 (or unit root).
If we add a constant in equation (2), we get
Δyt = ∂0
If a time trend is further included
Δyt = ∂0 + Bt πyt-1 + εt ….4
In (3) and (4) the null hypothesis is H0: π=0 the null, therefore, it means
that we have a stationary series.
If there are more than one unit root, then testing for a single unit root
will be misleading. Therefore, following pantula‟s principle, it is better to
43
start with higher order unit roots by applying the DF test to the first
difference of the series. If the result is rejection, then we move to test the
given variable at level. If the residuals are serially correlated, which is not
unusual for such a DGP, the residual variance not be used (Sjoo, 1997).
This is solved by using the ADF test.
B. The ADF test for unit root.
The ADF test solves the above problem by augmenting the DF test
with some log structure of follows
Δyt = πyt-1+∑бi Δyt-1 + εt ………5
Δyt = ∂0 + πyt-1+∑бi Δyt-1 + εt ………6
Δyt = ∂0 + Bt + πBt + πyt-1+∑бi Δyt-1 + εt ………7
The ADF test is better than DF test since the augmentation leads to
empirical hypothesis there is also H0: π=0 in equation 5, 6, and 7.
Choosing the length of augmentation is a typical problem in ADF test.
4.3 Co-integration
In order to obtain both the short run dynamics and the long-run
relationship, one can appeals to what is known as co-integration. The
concept of co-integration implies that even if many economic variables
are
non-stationary,
there
linear
combination
may
be
stationary.
Therefore, the important thing is to rest whether integrated variables cointegrated so that a meaningful long run relationship can be established
4.4 Test to co-integration
Though there are different tests for co-integration, we focus on the two
step procedure by Engle and Granger.
The Engle – Granger two step procedure
44
Given yt ~I (1) and xt ~ I(1), then
Step 1: Do OLS on Yt = ∂+Bxt + εt (Regression on levels) which is called
co-integrating regression: save the residual from this regression.
Step 2: Test whether Êt (the estimated residual) is I (o) or I(1)
This can be done by ADF test which is formed as ΔÊt = ∂0 + π Êt-1 + ∑ ΔÊt 1+
ut
The null hypothesis here is π=0 (unit root) and the alternative is that the
variables are co-integrated. The relevant test statistics used here is
different from the usual unit root test on a variable because here we have
a derived variable.
The major problems in the above procedure are: the assumption of only
one co-integrating vector, the choice of logs in the ADF test and the
assumption of a common factor in the dynamic of the system.
4.5 The Error correction model
While a model in difference of variables gets around the problem of
spurious regression, it does so at the cost of not being able to discover
the long run relationship between variables of our interest. The error
correction model solves this by combining the long run information with
a short run adjustment mechanism.
k
k
An ECM can be represented as Δyt = Bi Δxt-1 + ∑ εt ………7
i=0
i=0
Where ECMt-1 is the error correction term which represents the deviation
from the long run steady state relation between the two variables ∂ in the
above equation represents how change in ∆yt reacts to deviation from the
long run equilibrium. The error correction term is one period log of the
saved residual from the co-integration relation in the two step procedure.
45
As long as we have co-integration among variables, as noted by Engle
and Granger (1987), there is an ECM formulation. We can use the tdistribution to test the significance of the parameter estimate of the ECM
as the conventional properties of the distribution hold asymptotically.
The choice of appropriate lag structure is a problem in estimating the
ECM.
46
CHAPTER FIVE
5. ECONOMETRICS ANALYSIS OF THE STUDY
5.1 Model specification
In order to estimate the relationship between devaluation and economic
growth, this paper used the model which was presented by Edwards
(1992), using gross domestic product (GDP) as an economic growth
index. This study hypothesizes that the GDP growth is a function of a set
of explanatory variable. So that in this study GDP growth is specified as
a function of Real Government investment (RGI) as a variable influenced
by fiscal indicator, Real Private Investment (RPI) as a variable influenced
by fiscal and monetary policy, money supply (MS) as a monetary fiscal
index. In order to investigate the impact of devaluation on economic
growth, devaluation was replaced by real effective exchange rate (REER).
Also export price index divided by import price implicit index is used as
the term of trade (TOT).
LGDP = f (LRGI, LRPI, LMS, LTOT, LREER) + ut ……(1)
LGDP = a0 + B1 LRGI + B2 LRPI + B3 MS + B4 TOT + B5 REER + ut …(2)
L – Represents the logarithm of variables
GDP – Gross Domestic product, the real aggregate production
RPI – Real private investment
PGI – Real Government Investment
REERt – ∑aitPit/pht were, ait = the trade shore of the country at time t in
the total export and import out of given country.
Eit – the bilateral nominal exchange rate country i at time to against
home country in terms of country currency
47
Pit – price index of country i at time t
Pht – Price index of home country at time t
TOT = Export in price index
Import price index
x 100
Ms = Money supply
The expected sign of B1 is positive since government investment has a
productive effect for future economic growth of the country. The expected
sign of B2 is positive since private investment can have an implication for
the sustainability of the external position because of high level of
investment implying high future growth through the buildup of large
productive capacity.
The expect sign of B3 is to be positive since increase in money supply
decrease the rate of interest, encouraging investment and thus, expands
output. This coefficient captures how monetary policy holds effective in
affecting the real variable.
The expected sign of B4 is also positive since it is clear that worsening of
the terms of trade (i.e. reduction in TOT) will result in real GDP
reduction. This implies an extra amount of export is necessary to
maintain the previous amount of imports if the terms of trade become
worsen.
The main interest of this analysis lays in the coefficient of the exchange
rate which B5 measures. If devaluation are contractionary (i.e. decreasing
real output), it stressed that the value of B4 should be significantly
negative. If, however, devaluation is expansionary (i.e. increasing real
output), the sign should be positive and statistically significant.
48
5.2 Model Estimation and interpretation
5.2.1 Unit root test of stationarity
A stationary test expected to be the first step in time series regression
analysis. That is, we must distinguish between stationary and nonstationary variables. Since failure to do so can lead to a problem of
spurious regression stationary.
Since time series data are employed in this study, a unit root test of
stationarity is conducted to know the order of integration of the variable
used in the regression. Based on the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF)
test, which were already discussed in the beginning of chapter 4, the
entire variable entering the regression is non-stationary in the original
time series data. However, the first difference of all variable is found to be
stationary which means that they do not exist a unit root problem. It is
therefore possible to say that the original time series is integrated of
order one.
Table 5.1: Result of unit root test of level of I (0) using augmented
dickey-fuller (ADF) test
Variables
Teststatistics
Critical values
1%
5%
10%
Ln RGDP
-2.866
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
Ln RGI
-0.756
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
Ln RPI
-1.272
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
Ln REER
-1.348
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
Ln TOT
-1.763
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
Ln MS
-2.056
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
49
One variable LnRGDP is found to be stationary at level and the
remaining variables are non-stationary
Table 5.2: Result of unit root test for I (1) of the variable using
augment dickey – fuller (ADF) test
Variables
Test
statistics
Critical values
1%
5%
10%
DLnRGDP
-5.201
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
DLnRGI
-4.752
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
DLnRPI
-9672
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
DLnREER
-4.294
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
DLnTOT
-4.674
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
DLnMS
-9.054
-3.730
-2.992
-2.626
As shown from table 4.3.2 all the variables are stationary after
differencing.
5.2.2 Test of co-integration
The existence of co-integrating relationship implies the long run
relationship between the variables. There are a number of methods for
testing co-integration but this study use the Engle-Granger two step
procedures.
The Engle-Granger methodology determines whether the residual is
stationary or not. If this residual, which is the Linear combination of the
variable is stationary, then the variables are said to be co-integrated, that
is, they have long run relationship.
50
Table 5.3 Co-integration Test
Variable
Residual (2)
Test statistics
-5.873
Critical values
1%
5%
10%
-3.723
-2.989
-2.625
According to the above result the residual from the long run model is stationary
at level, implying that the variables under consideration have a long run or
equilibrium relationship. Thus, the long run structural equation derived from the
co-integrating vector is not spurious rather, it is meaningful and it can be
presented as.
LnRGDP=8.75+0.41 LnRGI+0.325 LnRPI-0.18 LnREER-0.21 LnTOT-0.15 LnMS+ et
T: (3.51)
(1.76)
(2.08)
(-2.60)
(-0.90)
(-1.26)
SE: (2.49)
(0.235)
(0.156)
(0.29)
(0.233)
(0.118)
Table 5.4 Estimation results of the long run model
Dependent variable: LnRGDP
Solved static for long run equation result
Variables
Coefficient
Standard
t-value
P > /t/
error
Constant
8.746191
2.492714
3.51
0.002
LnRGI
0.4139318
0.2351097
1.76
0.091
LnRPI
0.3250898
0.1563899
2.08
0.049
LnREER
-0.1769035
0.2928942
-2.60
0.052
LnTOT
-0.2091855
0.2334518
-0.90
0.379
LnMS
-0.1488969
0.1184947
-1.26
0.221
No. of observation = 30
F (5,24) = 8.43
Prob > F = 0.0001
51
R2 = 0.6372
Adj R2 = 0.5616
DW = 1.66
The estimated model shows that the coefficient of real government
investment has got a sign that agrees with the expectation which is
positive and the coefficient was found to be statistically significant by
looking at the P value which is less than or equal to 10%. The coefficient
of real private investment also got the expected sign and statistically
significant. The coefficient of real effective exchange rate showed an
unexpected sign but the coefficient was found to be statistically
significant. The coefficient of terms of trade and money supply are
negative which is unexpected sign and they are statistically insignificant.
5.2.2.1 Interpretation of the Econometrics Result of the long run
model
The coefficient of real government investment (PGI) was found to be
significant and showed the expected positive sign. This means that a 1%
increase in real government investment will leads to 41.4 percent
increase in real GDP.
Real private investment (RPI) was found to be significant and showed the
expected positive sign. It observed that 1% increase in real private
investment (RPI) leads to 52.5 percent increase in real GDP in the long
run. This shows that capital accumulations through private investment
have productive effort for future capacity of economic growth.
The third variable incorporated in the specific model is real effective
exchange rate. Unlike the above two variables this variable appeared to
have negative correlation with growth in the long run and found to be
statistically significant. From table 4.4 a 1% rise of real effective
exchange rate (REER) reduces the real GDP by 18% in the long run. This
52
result against what the theory said and it indicates that devaluation has
contractionary effect on the growth of Ethiopia‟s economy. This is
consistent with the study done by Bronson (1986) in the Kenyan
economy.
This
might
be
attributed
with
an
absence
of
export
diversification, low elasticity of demand and supply for export, the
availability
of
domestic
substitute
for
imported
goods,
and
the
responsiveness of export and import price to the exchange rate
depreciation and size and degree of currency depreciation with the link of
international market development.
Finally, the estimated model show that both terms of trade and money
supply showed unexpected sign (i.e. the increase of terms of trade and
money supply reduces RGDP growth) and it also found that they are
statistically insignificant.
5.2.3 The Error correction model
The test of co-integration indicated that the variable under consideration
have a long run relationship since every co-integrated non-stationary
variable to have error correction representation. An error correction
model (ECM) is constructed and estimated in this section as the first
difference of the dependent variable is regressed on the first difference of
the explanatory variables with their lags and the first lag of the residual
obtained in the first step. It indicates the short run dynamics of the OLS
estimation result and its adjustment towards the long run equilibrium.
53
Table 5.5 Estimation Result of ECM
Dependent variable: DLnRGDP
Independent
Coefficient
variables
Standard
T – value
P >/t/
error
Constant
3.796157
0.0929262
40.85
0.000
DLnRGI
0.6544685
0.392272
1.87
0.074
DLnRPI
0.1935162
0.1467967
1.32
0.201
DLnREER
-0.358564
0.5466729
-0.660
0.519
DLnTOT
0.5254829
0.3311987
1.59
0.127
DLnMS
0.0639892
0.1111267
0.58
0.571
E lagged
-0.4348708
0.2636134
-1.65
0.113
No. of observation = 29
F (6,22) = 1.45
Frob > F = 0.2426
R2 = 0.2827
Adj R2 = 0.0871
The short run model could be
DlnRGDP=3.8+0.65 DlnRGI+0.19 DlnRPI-0.36 DlnREER+0.53 DlnTOT+0.064 DlnMS+Et-1
T: (40.85)
(1.87)
(1.32)
(-0.660)
(1.59)
(0.58)
SE: (0.093)
(0.35)
(0.147)
(0.547)
(0.33)
(0.11)
54
Where D indicates first difference of the logarithm of the variable
included in the model and Et-1 is the residual. In addition the model
taking a one period lags of the variables.
5.2.3.1 Interpretation of the econometrics result of the short run
model (ECM)
The short run (ECM) regression result shows that 28% of the variation in
RGDP is due to the explanatory variable involved in the model. The
coefficient of real private investment, real government investment, terms
of trade and money supply shows the expected sign but they are
statistically insignificant.
The coefficient of real effective exchange rate showed unexpected sign as
of the long run and it is statistically not significant in the short run.
In the above model, the coefficient of the error-correction term is
significant with magnitude of -0.43. This magnitude indicates that
deviation from the long run equilibrium is adjusted fairly where 43% of
the disequilibrium is removed each period. It has a negative sign
implying that any shock in the system in the short term will return back
to its long run path.
55
CHAPTER SIX
6. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATION OF THE
STUDY
6.1 Conclusion
In this paper, an attempt was made to study the impact of devaluation
on economic growth of Ethiopia by using both theoretically and
empirically review of different countries and it also assessed the overall
macro-economic performance of Ethiopia economic growth for the last
three decade and with due emphasis given to foreign trade of the
country.
The Ethiopia birr was overvalued in the last two decades. The real
effective
exchange
rate
had
adverse
effects
on
macro-economic
performance of the country. The previous government did not take the
right corrective measures; rather they pursued a policy of exchange
control and foreign exchange allocation. This aggravated the problem of
real exchange rate appreciation and depletion of the country‟s foreign
reserve.
To mitigate the general economic, problem the transitional government of
Ethiopia devalue the Ethiopia birr against the standard currency (Dollar)
by 142% in dollar terms on October 1992. Even if, the transitional
government of Ethiopia (TGE) taken devaluation as an instrument of
improving external competitiveness, the country experienced trade deficit
after the introduction of devaluation. The reasons are due to absence of
export diversification, low elasticity of demand and supply for export and
the availability of domestic substitute for import goods.
56
The empirical estimation of the real GDP of the country using OLS
estimation in long run and error correction model showed the following
results.
Real private and government investment showed direct relationship with
real GDP and statistically significant in the long run. But in the short
run only real private investment is significant. The positive relationship
with real GDP is an indication that domestic investments have a great
effect to attain a fast economic growth of developing country in order to
overcome the misery of poverty.
On the other hand real effective exchange rate terms of trade and money
supply showed negative relationship with real GDP in long run. Terms of
trade and money supply were insignificant in both long run and short
run in affecting the real GDP. While the real effective exchange is
significant during the long run, turned out to be insignificant during
short run.
Finally we conclude that, the real effective exchange rate which is the
main interest of this analysis results in reduction of real GDP of the
country. This result is against what the theory said (devaluation has
expansionary effect on real GDP) and it indicates that devaluation has
contractionary effect on the growth of Ethiopian economy.
6.2 Policy Implication
Based on the findings of this study, the following strategies and
measures are suggested for policy implication.
-
The findings imply that policy makers in developing countries
should be cautious when taking a decision on devaluing the
currency or using the policy instruments under their control in
such a way as to create real depreciation. More particularly, it is
57
not advisable to call for devaluation if the major concern is
increasing output in the short run. Along the same lines, we can
say that it is not recommended for the LDCs government like
Ethiopia implementing a flexible exchange rate system to allow for
a major depreciation, since it may hurt economic growth.
-
Even if devaluation is taken for the reason of improving the trade
balance deficit, it failed in achieving this aim. The main argument
behind that is the increasing amount of import at a rate that out
strips the case for exports. Hence, there is a need for the country
to build industries that can produce those commodities, which are
imported and demanded at large domestically. That is, strategy of
import substitution industries of the kind producing crucial goods
and services like fertilizer, pharmaceutical products, chemicals etc.
are mandatory for minimizing the amount of imports and that can
in turn pave the way for improving the condition of trade balance.
58
REFERENCES
Abent Aleme (2004), “The impact of exchange rate reform policy on trade
balance in Ethiopia,” BA thesis.
Ahmed linquat. (1986), Stabilization policies in developing countries,
World Bank research observer, Vol. 1, No. 1.
Anthony Davies (1998), “The implication of currency devaluation,” journal
of development studies, Vol. 5.No 2.
Ballasa B. (1989), “Incentive policies in sub-Saharan Africa”. Essay on
new direction in the world economy, London, Macmillan press.
Befekadu Degefa and Kibremoges (1992), “Post devaluation Ethiopian
Economy in Mekonen Tadesse and Abdulhamed Bedri (ed),” The Ethiopian
Economy problem of adjustment proceeding of the second annual
conference.
Befekadu degefa and Berhanu Nega (1999/2000), “The Ethiopian
Economy association annual report on the Ethiopian Economy,” Vol. 1.
Bird, G. (1988), “Should developing countries use currency depreciation as
a tool of Balance of payment adjustment”? A review of the theory and
evidence and a guide for policy maker,” Journal of development studies,
vol. 19, No. 4.
Branson, William H. (1986), “Stabilization, stagflation and investment:
The case of Kenya (1975-80).” In S.E Edwards and L. Ahmed (eds.),
Economic Adjustment and exchange rate in developing countries,
Chicago university of Chicago press.
Chibber Ajay and Nemat Shafik (1990), “Does devaluation hurt private
investment? The Indonesian case,” World Bank working papers, No. 418.
Christopoluos, D.K. (2004), “Does currency devaluation is effective? A
panel unit root test”, Economic letters, Vol. 72.
59
Connolly, M. (1983), “Exchange rates, real economic activity and the
balance of payments: Evidence from the 1960s,” Amsterdam, north
Holland.
Dean Taylor and Michael Connely (1971), Testing the monetary approach
to devaluation in developing, countries, journal of political economy, Vol.
84 No. 4. Part I.
Deresse Degefa (1996), “The parallel exchange rate and the premium in
Ethiopia” unpublished MSC Thesis A.A.U.
Diaz-Alejandro M, GF. (1963), “A note on the impact of devaluation and
redistribution effect” journal of political economy.
Edwards, S. (1986), Are Devaluation Contractionary? The Review of
Economics and statistics.
Kidane Asmorem (1994), “Exchange rate policy and economic reform in
Ethiopia”, AERC Research Paper.
Gloryfason T and Risager, O. (1984), “Does devaluation improve the
current account?”, European economic review, Vol. 2.
Gujarati (1986), “Basic econometrics”, Third edition.
Gylfason, T and Schmid, M. (1983), “Does devaluation cause stagflation?”
Canadian journal of economics, Vol. 16.
Killick, T and Mulega, FM. (1993), Monetary policy in developing
countries, Kenya.
Kruger,A.O.(1978), Liberalization Attempts and consequences, (Cambride,
MA; Ballinger).
Krugman, P and Taylor, L. (1978), “Contractionary effect of devaluation”,
journal of international economics.
MEDAC (1996), “Survey in the Ethiopia Economy”, review of post reform
developments.
60
National Bank of Ethiopia (various years) “Annual Report” (various
issues).
Sentayehu W/micheal (1996). The impact of devaluation on major macro
economic variables, unpublished MSC. Thesis A.A.U.
Sidney Alexander (1996), Effects of devaluation on trade balance, IMF
staff papers, vol. 3 No. 2.
Sodersten, Bo and Geoffreyree (1994). International Economics, Great
Britain, Macrays of Chatham Plc, Chatham Kent, third edition.
Tumorsky, S.J. (1977). Macro economic analysis and stabilization policy,
London: Cambridge university press.
Unpadhyaya, K.P. (1999) “Currency devaluation, aggregate output, and
the long run: an empirical study”, Economics Letters.
Wijinbergen Sweder Van. (1986), Exchange rate management and
stabilization polices in developing countries, journal of development
economies, Vol. 23.
World Bank study (1993), “Trends in developing economies” world banks.
Younger, S.D (1992), “Testing the link between devaluation and inflation.
Time series evidence from Ghana”. Journal of Africa economies, Vol. 1,
No. 3.
61