Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2�18) 180–204
brill.com/jocc
Costs do not Explain Trust among Secular Groups
John H. Shaver
University of Otago
corresponding author:
[email protected]
Susan DiVietro
Connecticut Children’s Medical Center
Trinity College
[email protected]
Martin Lang
Harvard University
Masaryk University
[email protected]
Richard Sosis
University of Connecticut
[email protected]
Abstract
Many human groups achieve high levels of trust and cooperation, but these achievements are vulnerable to exploitation. Several theorists have suggested that when groups
impose costs on their members, these costs can function to limit freeriding, and hence
promote trust and cooperation. While a substantial body of experimental research
has demonstrated a positive relationship between costs and cooperation in religious
groups, to date, this relationship has not held for secular groups. Here we extend this
line of research by comparing trust and cooperation among 11 secular groups, including
four U.S. Greek fraternities that impose high costs on their members. We find that although fraternities impose greater costs on their members than social clubs, fraternities
and social clubs do not significantly differ in their levels of intra-group trust. Moreover,
variation in costs does not explain variation in trust among fraternities. We suggest that
the lack of an evident relationship between costs and trust in our results is because
secular groups, unlike religious groups, lack repeated rituals that are coupled with supernatural ideologies. We conclude by suggesting possible avenues for future research.
© koninklijke brill nv, leiden, 2018 | doi 10.1163/15685373-12340025
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
181
Keywords
costly signaling theory – fraternities – ideologies – secular groups – trust
Introduction
Group living among social species entails significant selection pressures
(Pulliam & Caraco, 1984). The benefits of group living include, among other
advantages, greater and more efficient resource production. Examples of these
resources include defense against predation, territorial defense, more productive food acquisition, as well as greater social status (Irons, 2001). Such resources, however, are subject to increased intra-group competition. Moreover,
resources produced collectively are at risk of exploitation by freeriders who
extract benefits without commensurate levels of investment (Cronk & Leech,
2012).
Yet, despite these tradeoffs, human sociality is distinguished by extraordinarily high levels of cooperation and collective action (Hill, Barton, & Hurtado,
2009; Nowak & Highfield, 2011; Ridley, 1996). This cooperation often takes place
in the context of coalitions that survive across multiple overlapping membership generations, which allow groups of individuals to pursue shared interests across several domains, and achieve benefits that tend to increase over
time (Cimino & Delton, 2010; Delton & Cimino, 2010; Irons, 2001; Tiger, 1969).
However, while everyone benefits when all members invest in cooperative activities, this is difficult to achieve without social mechanisms that curtail incentives for freeriding. Overcoming problems of commitment are, therefore,
central obstacles to realizing cooperative goals and successful coalitions in all
human groups (Frank, 1988, 2001; Schelling, 1960, 2001).
When individuals can reliably commit to participation in collective
goals — that is, they can be trusted — successful cooperation is more likely to
emerge. Consequently, practices that encourage high levels of trust mediate
and encourage cooperative activities (Sosis, 2005). But simple advertisements
of cooperative willingness are relatively easy to fake and are therefore unlikely
to be reliable. Under conditions in which individuals can potentially achieve
net benefits through their defection, reliable signals tend to be those that are
too costly for defectors to imitate (Zahavi & Zahavi, 1997).
Scholars across several disciplines have suggested that when human social
groups impose significant costs on their members, these costs act to curtail
incentives for individuals to freeride, thus facilitating high levels of trust and
intra-group cooperation (Bulbulia, 2004; Iannaconne, 1992, 1994; Irons, 1996;
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
182
Shaver ET AL.
2001; Kurzban & Christner, 2011; Sosis, 2003). These theorists, for the most part,
were interested in how the costliness of membership obligations demanded
by religious communities can help to explain the high levels of cooperation
observed within these groups. Nonetheless, they assumed that the benefits of
costly obligations on promoting cooperation would not be limited to religious
communities, but would also extend to any group that imposes such costs on
individuals seeking membership. Thus a positive correlation between costs of
membership and cooperativeness was anticipated for secular groups as well
(e.g., Iannaconne, 1992, 1994; Irons, 1996). However, while research to date has
found a positive relationship between costs and cooperation and/or trust for
religious groups (e.g., Purzycki & Arakchaa, 2013; Soler, 2012), this relationship
has not held for secular groups.
For example, Sosis (2000) and Sosis and Bressler (2003) examined the
survivorship of 19th Century secular and religious communes in the United
States. These studies showed that for every year of their existence, religious
communes were more likely to survive than communes founded upon secular
ideologies. Moreover, among religious communes, the number of costly obligations demanded of members strongly predicted commune longevity; religious communes with more obligations survived longer. No such relationship
was found among secular communes.
Building on these studies, Sosis and Ruffle (2003) examined whether the
relative economic success of Israeli religious kibbutzim compared to secular
kibbutzim could be partially explained by higher levels of intra-group cooperation among members of religious kibbutzim. They conducted common pool
resource experiments on over 30 religious and secular kibbutizim and found,
after controlling for several possible confounds, that the members of religious
kibbutzim were more cooperative than their secular counterparts. These differences in cooperation appear to be driven by higher levels of ritual obligations, most notably daily communal prayer, on religious kibbutzim (Ruffle &
Sosis, 2007).
These results suggest that religious groups may be more cooperative than
otherwise similarly organized secular groups, and that costly obligations may
be contributing to the high levels of cooperation observed among religious
groups. In these studies, costly requirements were less frequent among secular communes than religious ones, even excluding overtly religious obligations
such as prayer.
In modern societies many secular groups, such as militaries, sports teams,
and U.S. Greek fraternities demand that members engage in substantial
costly behaviors and presumably these groups are highly cooperative. Thus,
while previous studies reveal that secular groups tend to be less cooperative
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
183
than religious groups, and these differences are partially explained by differences in costly requirements, research has yet to examine whether variation
in membership costs predicts variation in trust and cooperation among secular social groups with high costs of membership. Here we aim to fill this gap
by examining trust and costly requirements for membership among secular
social clubs and Greek fraternities at a U.S. university. U.S. college campuses
consist of several multigenerational organizations that vary in their membership costs and therefore represent an ideal setting to examine the relationship
between membership costs and trust among secular groups. These groups include Greek fraternities and sororities, clubs with shared academic interests
(e.g., computer science club), clubs with shared extra-curricular interests (e.g.,
hiking club), and sports teams, among others.
Greek Organizations on U.S. College Campuses
Despite substantial variation, secular Greek organizations (i.e., fraternities
and sororities) on U.S. college campuses share many features. For example,
prior to full initiation, interested individuals must go through both a vetting
period (called rushing) and a probationary period (called pledging). During
the rush period potential initiates meet with current members and engage in
activities such as sporting events or relaxed social gatherings. One purpose
of these events is for both potential and current members to begin to get to
know one another. More importantly, however, the ultimate goal of the vetting period is for current group members to determine, collectively, those individuals who the group would like to invite to become members. Those who
survive the vetting period are formally offered an invitation to pledge (i.e., join
the group). If the potential initiate accepts the invitation, s/he then enters a
pledge period.
During the pledge period potential initiates are easily recognizable to other
members of the University — pledges often wear pins and forms of clothing
that mark them as liminal members of a specific Greek organization. Some fraternities and sororities require that pledges wear pins twenty-four hours a day.
Throughout this phase the pledges of Greek organizations go through additional forms of hazing, or the enforcement of behaviors that are not important
for the goals of the group (e.g., calisthenics are often required of Greek fraternity pledges, however cardiovascular health is a group-irrelevant goal) (Cimino,
2011). Hazing on U.S. college campuses appears to be relatively common; a
recent study found that 36% of undergraduates had participated in at least
one hazing activity during their college career (Campo, Poulos, & Sipple, 2005).
Although fraternities and sororities range widely in their extent and severity
of pledging, pledges are often required to endure menial labor (e.g., cleaning
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
184
Shaver ET AL.
members’ apartments or the group’s meeting house), substantial memorization (e.g., all members’ full names and birthdates), the forced drinking of alcohol, beating or paddling, calisthenics, branding or tattooing, confinement,
and other forms of psychological abuse (Cimino, 2013a; Finkel, 2002). Cimino
(2013a, 2013b) suggests that, in general, hazing involves current members requiring pledges to engage in “impossible” tasks or expectations. Such tasks
necessarily result in failure, and pledges are subsequently punished through
various forms of physical and/or psychological harassment.
Hazing events typically take place in partially ritualized settings that are
attended only by pledges and full members. Across the pledge period hazing
events tend to increase in frequency and intensity and often culminate in a
“hell week” and/or a “hell night.” A “hell week” consists of a week of organized
hazing while a “hell night” is typically a night of hazing (often the last day of
hell week) that ends with the full initiation of pledges.
After initiation, group members are often required to engage in activities
that benefit the group and come at some cost to the individual either directly,
or in the form of opportunity costs. For example, the members of most groups
are expected to pay membership fees each month and attend a certain number of community-service oriented events, among other obligations. If group
members fail to live up to these obligations, or other normative expectations,
they can be placed on probation or expelled from the group. Generally, expulsion or quitting a group is stigmatized, whether or not it occurs after full
initiation or during the pledge period. In other words, people are not free
to move between Greek organizations, and because of the large number of
post-initiation requirements, membership in a Greek organization inhibits
(although does not necessarily preclude) membership in non-Greek campus
organizations. By agreeing to pledge a fraternity or sorority, then, individuals
pre-commit themselves to one specific social group for the duration of their
college career.
Greek membership on U.S. college campuses can often entail these considerable costs, but there is evidence that they may yield substantial benefits.
Importantly, members of Greek organizations have larger social networks, a social resource that is particularly beneficial in securing internships and employment after college (Abelson & Faux, 2013). Moreover, membership in a Greek
organization often returns prestige and status among the larger University
population (Ramey, 1982, as cited in Cimino 2013a; 2013b; Ramey, 1982).
Social Clubs on U.S. College Campuses
In addition to Greek organizations, there are a tremendous number of social clubs on U.S. college campuses. Academic clubs range from those whose
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
185
members share an interest in an academic topic to those who maintain a
certain grade point average. Non-academic clubs are incredibly diverse and
span a range of topics and interests including: music genres, multiple forms
of dance and comedy, sports and recreational activities, ethnic and religious
groups, political parties, and those formed around social ideals, among many
others.
In contrast to Greek organizations, social clubs are less exclusive and appear to require fewer pre- and post-initiation costs of members. The majority
of social clubs lack a vetting or probationary period. Quitting, or a forced removal from, a social club likely does not carry the same social stigma as would
quitting a Greek organization. Moreover, for the most part, students are able
to join many social clubs and invest in them to the extent to which they feel
comfortable, rather than have minimal levels of investments dictated by group
expectations.
To summarize, secular university groups vary in terms of costs and benefits,
with many groups enforcing substantial costs on their members, both prior to
and after full initiation. Although previous research among secular groups has
failed to find an association between membership costs and trust, this work
has failed to examine secular groups with high costs of membership. Drawing
from applications of costly signaling theory to the study of intra-group trust
(Iannaconne, 1992, 1994; Irons, 1996; Sosis, 2000), we hypothesized that university groups with costlier obligations would exhibit higher levels of intra-group
trust than university groups with less costly obligations.
Materials and Methods
Study Design
In order to test the hypothesis that secular groups that impose high costs on
their members exhibit higher levels of intra-group trust, we compared initiation costs and costs of participation against a behavioral measure of trust and
self-rated trust among four fraternities, four social clubs, and three classes.
Classes do not share many of the features of the other social groups in the
study, yet their members are drawn from the same population of students that
join fraternities and social clubs. Notably, because there are no costs for joining
a class (other than university fees that all students pay), nor costs of participation (other than those associated with academic evaluation), levels of trust
within classes serve as a trust baseline for the population. Moreover, because
classes are not social groups, yet their members do engage in some degree of
social interaction, classes functioned as a control group.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
186
Shaver ET AL.
Participants
Participants were 236 undergraduate students enrolled at the University
of Connecticut. Of these participants (M age = 20.07 years; SD = 2.03; Range =
18–34), 141 (59.7%) were males. In total, participants were unequally distributed across three sections of three introductory anthropology classes (n = 66),
four all-male Greek fraternities (n = 78), and four coed student groups (n = 92).
The student groups consisted of two groups with shared majors, an academic
excellence club, and a coed service fraternity. Although similar in name, the
coed service fraternity critically differs from the all-male Greek fraternities
sampled in our study because it is a social group that focuses on service rather
than purely social goals. The external focus of the coed service fraternity, as
well as its coed composition, makes it more similar to shared major groups
and the academic excellence group than Greek fraternities. Below, for convenience, we refer to these coed student groups, including the service fraternity,
as “clubs.” For additional demographic information see Table 1.
Fraternities
Three of the four fraternities maintained semester-long pledge periods, and
two fraternities required pledges to pass through a hell week before they were
granted membership. All fraternities maintained secret knowledge, even the
fraternity that did not have a pledge period or hell week. Membership dues
for fraternities ranged from $50 to $400 per semester. Lastly, all fraternities
reserved the right to expel disruptive or financially delinquent members,
but only two of the four fraternities reported expelling members in living
memory.
All fraternities in our sample had active event calendars that included business meetings, service activities, house cleanings, and social events such as
parties and sports competitions. Attendance is taken at most events but nonattendance was not punished in any fraternity. One fraternity maintained a
point system to track attendance, but this was used for rewarding participation
rather than punishing absence. All fraternities reward particularly active members with special recognition.
Clubs
Of the student clubs we sampled only the coed service fraternity had a pledge
period. The pledge period usually lasts about 8–9 weeks and requires pledges to
maintain an 80% average on quizzes about the fraternity’s history and bylaws,
engage in 35 hours of service, plan a pledge class event, and make pledge paddles for a big brother/sister. Membership dues are $65 per semester. Once the
pledge period is completed, members are required to attend weekly meetings
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Descriptive statistics for group types and groups
Fraternities
Clubs
Classes
αα
ββ
γγ
δδ
CSF
AEC
SMC 1
SMC 2
Class 1
Class 2
Class 3
N
20
20
22
16
24
24
24
20
24
24
18
Group size
55
34
27
25
55
28
34
250
% Males
100
100
100
100
25
20.8
42.7
50
70.8
33.3
38.9
Pledging length [weeks]
6.5
7.5
7
0
9
0
0
0
Hell week
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
No
Self-rated trust [1–7]
5.9
5.7
5.6
6.4
5.4
5.5
6.1
5.4
4.8
4.0
4.2
Mean proportion sent by A
82.3%
93.3%
83.0% 88.3%
64.7%
61.7%
78.3% 71.7%
41.9%
58.6%
73.3%
Mean proportion sent by B
38.3%
56.9%
62.0% 71.0%
51.4%
49.4%
50.9% 38.3%
38.3%
40.2%
45.2%
Note that Fraternity names are pseudonyms. Clubs: Coed Service Fraternity (CSF), Academic Excellence Club (AEC), Shared
Major Club 1 (SMC1), and Shared Major Club 2 (SMC2).
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Table 1
187
188
Shaver ET AL.
and to complete 20 hours of community service per semester. If members fail
to attend a project for which they have signed up, the hours are deducted from
their semester total. Members who miss three or more weekly meetings, fail
to complete 20 hours of community service, or fail to pay dues, are dismissed
from the service fraternity.
Two shared-major clubs — that is, clubs whose membership requires enrollment in a particular major — were included in our sample. One of the
clubs required members to pay $10 annually and attend three events each semester. The other shared-major club had no membership fees and required
attendance at six events per semester. Events for both clubs include meetings,
social events, and community projects. There are no penalties in either club for
failing to attend club events.
The academic excellence club is open to all students who achieve a 3.5 GPA
during their first year at the university. Activities include weekly meetings,
service activities, and social events. Students in the academic excellence club
can earn “points” for attending club events, and those who attend seven events
are awarded with a “Distinguished Member” title. Loss of academic standing is
grounds for dismissal from the club. There are no membership fees or penalties for lack of attendance at meetings or programs.
Classes
We sampled groups of students enrolled in sections of three large introductory
anthropology classes (typically between 100–300 students each). Sections are
groups of about 15–25 students who meet with a graduate teaching assistant
for an hour each week to discuss the lecture material covered by the professor
of the course. Each section we sampled was part of a different introductory
class. Introductory anthropology courses at the University of Connecticut fulfill a general education requirement and are consequently taken by students
enrolled in the full gamut of majors at the university. Attendance at sections
counts toward students’ grades.
Procedure
Participants from all groups played a trust investment game designed to measure trust and trustworthiness between pairs of individuals (Berg, Dickhaut, &
McCabe, 1995). In the trust game participants are anonymously paired and
randomly assigned to the role of either trustor (henceforth Player A) or trustee
(henceforth Player B). Both participants start with equal endowments; however, Player B’s endowment never enters game play. In the initial decisionmaking task, Player A sends any amount of her endowment to Player B. If
Player A sends none of her endowment, the game ends. If Player A sends some
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
189
or all of her endowment, this amount is tripled and then sent to Player B. In
the second stage of the experiment, Player B decides how much, if any, of her
received amount to send back to Player A. The amount Player A sends to Player
B in the first round of the game assesses trust since Player A’s investment represents a risk that Player B will return less money than was sent, while the
amount returned by Player B measures her trustworthiness (Camerer, 2003).
To recruit participants from fraternities and clubs we contacted their presidents and arranged times for their members to participate in the experiment.
The teaching assistants responsible for leading sections recruited participants
from each of the three introductory classes. Participants arrived as groups to
the Department of Anthropology at the University of Connecticut. Individual
participants were taken one-by-one to a predetermined office by a research assistant. Research assistants were paired (one with Player A and the other with
Player B) and communicated participants’ game decisions by cell phone. All
office doors were closed and five to seven experimental pairs were run simultaneously to assure anonymity. Following game play and interviews, participants
were invited to eat pizza in the company of researchers, where they discussed
their impressions of the experiments. Participants, however, were not allowed
to discuss their game decisions and were encouraged to keep these decisions
private even after leaving the anthropology department.
Both Player A and Player B started with endowments of 15 USD. Research
assistants explained the procedure and participants had to pass a game comprehension check before they were allowed to make their decision. Following
the decision-making task, all participants were asked questions that assessed
the costs and benefits of group membership, self-rated trust in the group, several demographic questions, and questions designed to measure religiosity. We
examined religiosity because prior studies have found a positive relationship
between religiosity and trust (Ahmed, 2009; Ahmed & Salas, 2011; Tan & Vogel,
2008). To assess religiosity, we asked each participant to rate their belief in
God, their belief that God determines when a person dies, and their frequency
of attendance at a religious house of worship. These measures were then standardized and used to construct a religiosity scale (Cronbach’s α = .81).
Costs of Membership
All behaviors incur some costs to individuals and some behaviors entail
greater costs than others. The costs of any behavior can include energetic expenditures, temporal costs, and a multitude of opportunity costs. Accurately
quantifying the relative costs of behaviors is therefore inherently difficult. To
operationalize the costs of group membership and group participation, we
follow the approach of Sosis (2000) and Sosis and Bressler (2003) and assess
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
190
Shaver ET AL.
the additive effect of behaviors, rather than attempt to quantify relative costs
among them. This approach assumes that there is a monotonically increasing
relationship between the number of group directed behaviors performed by
members and the cost incurred by those members.
To investigate costs, we created two scales related to participation
(Cronbach’s alpha = .71) and pledge costs (Cronbach’s alpha = .65). All variables included in the scales were z-scored and combined to create scores for
particular scales. Since these scales are not meant to constitute general psychometric tests, the Cronbach’s alphas are at acceptable levels. The pledge cost
scale included responses to the following questions: How long was your pledge
period?; Did it include a hell week?; and How difficult was your pledge period?
The participation cost scale included answers to the following questions: How
many meals per week do you eat with other members?; How many nights in
a week do you spend at the fraternity house?; How many functions do you attend in your fraternity per week?; How active are you in your fraternity?; and,
How many favors do you do for other members per week?
Several days after these games and interviews, one of us interviewed the
leader of each of the clubs (SD) and fraternities (JHS) to gather more specific
ethnographic information about each group. Interviews with fraternity leaders concerned pledge programs, the length and difficulty of pledging, the existence of a hell week, and prior instances of group member expulsions. All
procedures were approved by the Institutional Review Board at the University
of Connecticut and all participants granted informed consent.
Analyses
The relationship between predictors and the amount sent by Player A and the
amount returned by Player B was analyzed in R (version 3.0.3, R Core Team,
2014). Since monetary allocation was bounded by minimal and maximal contributions for Player A (0 to 15 $USD), we divided Player A’s allocation by
the total endowment ($15) to obtain a proportion of the endowment sent to
Player B (Johnson & Mislin, 2011). For Player B, we calculated the proportion
of received money that was sent back to Player A. To account for a distribution
of proportions with lower and upper bounds of 0 and 1, we fit a beta regression (Eskelson & Madsen, 2011; Smithson & Verkuilen, 2006) using the function
gamlss (gamlss package; Stasinopoulos & Rigby, 2007). Beta regression uses a
logit link function to account for the typical features of proportional data such
as heteroscedasticity and skewness (Cribari-Neto & Zeileis, 2010; Stasinopoulos
& Rigby, 2007). To incorporate extreme values of 0 and 1, we transformed
our dependent variables using the formula (y’=(y·(n − 1) + 0.5)/n), where y
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
191
is the transformed variable and n is the sample size (Smithson & Verkuilen,
2006).
Due to the clustered nature of our data (participants were nested within
specific classes/clubs/fraternities), we added random intercepts for each
group into the models. Using a bottom-up approach (West, Welch, & Galecki,
2007), we first added random effects and then fixed effects on the basis of their
overall improvement of the model (Akaike Information Criterion with ChiSq
test (p < .05)). After determining the best fitting models, the logit estimates
of means were converted back to proportions using an inverse link function
for means (βi = eβ’i / 1+ eβ’i) and the Delta Rule for standard errors of the means
(σµi = βi·(1 − βi)·σµ’i). Finally, an inverse transformation formula (y = (y’·n)/
(n−1)+0.5) was used to obtain unbiased coefficients. The predictors considered for each of the main models included age, group-type, religiosity, and sex.
Due to their theoretical importance, sex and group-type were retained in all
models. To model the fraternity data, we considered age, group size, pledge
costs, participation costs, religiosity, and years since pledging. Since we were
interested in the effects of group size, participation cost, pledging cost, and
years since pledging, these variables were retained in all of the fraternity
models.
Results
Self-rated Trust
Fraternities and clubs did not differ in their self-rated trust in other group
members (p = 0.958), but both fraternities and clubs trusted their members
more than participants enrolled in class sections together (p < 0.001; Figure 1A).
Males reported greater trust in their group members than females (p = 0.008)
and a person’s religiosity was positively associated with self-rated trust in their
group (p = 0.027). These results are displayed in Table 2, model 1, and the full
model is listed in the Appendix.
Trust Game Results, Player A
Overall, the average amount sent by Player A to Player B for fraternities was
$12.93 (SE = 0.59), $10.35 (SE = 0.58) for clubs, and $8.36 (SE = 0.80) for class
sections. The average amount returned by Player B to Player A for fraternities
was $22.42 (SE = 1.92), $14.99 (SE = 1.42) for clubs, and $11.18 (SE = 1.52) for class
sections. First, we assessed which predictors explained significant variation in
the amount sent by Player A to Player B. Group type was dummy coded, with
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
192
Shaver ET AL.
Figure 1
Predicted means and ±SEM for Self-rated Trust and Game decisions for Players A
and B Divided by Group-type. Predicted means with ±SEM for (A) self-rated trust
and (B) the trust game controlling for sex and religiosity. The differences between
fraternities and clubs in predicted means for self-rated trust and Player A are not
significant, but both differ significantly from class sections. The mean predicted
investment for Player B is significantly higher in fraternities than clubs and class
sections.
Table 2
Estimated differences (with standard error of differences) for Model 1: self-rated trust
in other group members; Model 2: proportion of money sent by Player A to Player B;
and Model 3: proportion of money returned by Player B to Player A. Intercept is the
Fraternity group
Model
(1) Self-rated trust
Intercept
Group: fraternities vs.
clubs
Group: fraternities vs.
classes
Sex: females vs males
Religiosity
5.74 (0.120)***
−0.009 (0.176)
(2) Player A
81.795 (3.394)*** 62.764 (4.462)**
−5.787 (5.094)
−18.103 (6.749)**
−1.351 (0.173)*** −18.281 (6.002)**
0.413 (0.155)**
0.137 (0.061)**
Cox-Snell R2
0.358
p < 0.1; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001
(3) Player B
4.628 (3.545)
−3.575 (1.660)*
0.188
−21.445 (6.696)**
−5.44 (5.746)
0.105
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
193
fraternities set as the reference category. For sex, females were set as the reference category. Additionally, a person’s religiosity was centered to make the
intercept meaningful.
Using post-hoc pairwise comparisons with false discovery rate corrections
(Benjamini & Hochberg, 1995), the amount sent by Player A to Player B was
significantly greater for fraternities compared to the class sections (p = .001),
but not significantly different from the amount sent by Player A in clubs
(p = .258; Figure 1B). Further pair-wise comparisons revealed that the amounts
sent by Player A were significantly higher for clubs compared to class sections
(p = .038). Additionally, there was a significant negative influence of religiosity
on the amount sent by Player A (p = .033). The effect of sex was not significant
(p = .194), but it was retained in the model to account for the unequal distribution of males and females across our group type variable (Table 2, model 2 and
Figure 1, Player B; full model in the Appendix). When the sex effect is removed
from the model, the difference between fraternities and clubs becomes significant (p = .021); however, this effect does not hold in analyses of only males
in fraternities and clubs (p = .390). This suggests that our sampling method
did not allow for separating the effects of group type from sex in these models. Figure 2 displays histograms of Player A decisions for each group type for
each sex.
Trust Game Results, Player B
We assessed the amount returned by Player B to Player A as a proportion
(amount sent/amount received). Again, using a bottom-up approach, we
added predictors on the basis of significant improvements in models. For the
proportion returned by Player B, only group type and sex significantly improved model fit. The inclusion of the sex variable functions as a control for
the unequal distribution of males and females across groups.
The results of this model are shown in Table 2, model 3, and the full model
is specified in the Appendix. Using post-hoc pairwise comparisons with false
discovery rate corrections, the results show that fraternity members sent back
a significantly higher proportion of the amount they received from Player A
compared to members of clubs (p = .012) and class sections (p = .006).
Additional pair-wise comparisons showed that the difference between clubs
and class sections was not significant (p = .573) (Figure 1B).
Because we did not analyze our data using ANOVA, estimation of Cohen’s d
would be problematic and might bias power analysis. However, as an estimate,
we performed a post-hoc power analysis on detecting a difference in investments between fraternities and clubs. Given the number of participants per
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
194
Figure 2
Shaver ET AL.
Histograms of Player A’s decisions in the Trust game by sex among classes, clubs,
and fraternities. Histograms illustrate that the effect of fraternities disappears after
accounting for sex differences.
cell in these two conditions (84 in total), the analysis revealed that we would
be able to detect effect sizes of 0.15 with the conventional 80% power.
Fraternity Costs and Trust
We regressed pledge costs and participation costs for the fraternities controlling for the effect of group size and length of membership; however, neither
scale significantly predicted the proportion sent by Player A, or the proportion
returned by Player B (Table 3). This may be due, in part, to the fact that there
was low variance in the amount sent by Player A in fraternities (mode = 100%).
The only significant effect we observed was a negative association between
self-rated trust and pledge costs, suggesting that in some fraternities very harsh
pledge periods might negatively affect their participants.
We could not investigate the difference in pledge costs between clubs and
fraternities since only one club had a pledge period; however, the standardized
participation costs in clubs (M = −0.139, SE = 0.055) were significantly lower
than in fraternities (M = 0.150, SE = 0.058; p < .001). Overall, these results suggest that neither the costs of pledging, nor the costs of participation play a significant role in increasing trust between members of the secular groups in our
sample, although both types of costs are significantly greater for fraternities.
Shared Goals of Social Clubs
One of the social clubs in our study was a service-oriented group whose members presumably share the goal of community service, and this shared goal
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
195
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
Table 3
Estimated differences (with standard error of differences) for the fraternities. Model
F1: self-rated trust in other group members; Model F2: proportion of money sent by
Player A to Player B; and Model F3: proportion of money returned by Player B to
Player A. Intercept is the mean of all predictors
Fraternity models
Intercept
Pledge costs
Participation costs
Group size
Years since pledging
(F1) Self-rated trust
(F2) Player A
5.883 (0.096)***
−0.328 (0.153)*
0.186 (0.142)
0.011 (0.009)
−0.148 (0.085)
86.245 (3.088)*** 59.598 (4.347)***
0.074 (3.300)
−9.717 (7.412)
−1.880 (3.253)
7.355 (6.613)
−0.107 (0.212)
−0.730 (0.442)
0.804 (1.792)
3.260 (3.944)
Cox-Snell R2
0.151
p < 0.1; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001
0.019
(F3) Player B
0.252
perhaps positively impacts trust. To further investigate possible differences
between clubs, we created a separate model with club type as a categorical
predictor and compared least-squared means between clubs with Tukey corrections (Table 4). The only significant difference we observed was higher
self-rated trust in one of the shared major clubs (SMC1) compared to the coed
service fraternity.
Discussion
The aim of this study was to test the hypothesis that high cost secular groups
exhibit greater intra-group trust than secular groups that impose fewer costs.
Our results show that although fraternity membership required greater costs
than social club membership, fraternities and clubs did not differ in their
average level of self-rated trust nor in their trust as measured in a trust game.
Moreover, differences in costs did not explain differences in levels of trust between the fraternities themselves. While we did not find a significant difference in trust between fraternities and clubs, both groups trusted significantly
more than the members of class sections. The increased trust in fraternities
and clubs relative to class sections is probably best explained by the increased
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
196
Table 4
Shaver ET AL.
Estimated differences (with standard error of differences) between different clubs
with Tukey corrections. Model F1: self-rated trust in other group members; Model F2:
proportion of money sent by Player A to Player B; and Model F3: proportion of money
returned by Player B to Player A. Clubs: Coed Service Fraternity (CSF), Academic
Excellence Club (AEC), Shared Major Club 1 (SMC1), and Shared Major Club 2
(SMC2)
Fraternity models
(F1) Self-rated trust
(F2) Player A
CSF vs. AEC
−0.125 (0.266)
3.030 (10.599)
CSF vs. SMC1
−0.750 (0.261)*
−13.496 (10.599)
CSF vs. SMC2
−0.054 (0.304)
−6.886 (11.116)
AEC vs. SMC1
−0.625 (0.266)
−16.525 (10.599)
AEC vs. SMC2
0.071 (0.309)
−9.915 (11.116)
SMC1 vs. SMC2
0.696 (0.304)
6.610 (11.116)
p < 0.1; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001
(F3) Player B
1.998 (9.586)
0.525 (9.586)
13.056 (10.054)
−1.473 (9.586)
11.059 (10.054)
12.532 (10.054)
interaction and shared identities of fraternity and club members. In general,
these findings suggest that the high levels of costs imposed by these secular
groups are not associated with significantly higher levels of trust.
All groups we investigated did exhibit high levels of trust, and it is possible
that we failed to find a relationship between costs of membership and trust because of the methods we employed, and/or the populations we sampled. The
modal response for Player A in the fraternities was to give all of their endowment to Player B. The results show a trend, though insignificant, toward a positive relationship between costs and trust among fraternities. Perhaps if we had
increased the stakes, the fraternity members would have given significantly
more than the clubs. However, a recent meta-analysis of 162 trust game studies
showed that increasing Player A’s endowment did not significantly increase
the amount sent to Player B (Johnson & Mislin, 2011). Moreover, the positive
effect of costs on Player A’s decisions in the trust game is attenuated after accounting for the effect of sex. Sampling from all-female groups, such as sororities, would not allow us to further assess the effect of sex because the members
of all-female groups face different decisions-making contexts than mixed-sex
groups and all-male groups.
We may have also failed to find a relationship because of the difficulty associated with collecting data about fraternity rituals, especially pledge rituals.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
197
Revealing fraternity secrets about initiation rites can be grounds for expulsion,
and thus gathering information about these events is challenging. In an attempt to overcome this obstacle, we conducted in-depth and anonymous interviews with the leader of each fraternity at each fraternity house. The leaders
did divulge a substantial amount of secretive material, and we were able to
gather considerable information about pledge rites, but these data likely only
reveal some of the initiation costs that fraternities impose on their members.
Still, from these leader interviews we were able to assess the impact of pledging, pledge length, and the existence of a hell week, in addition to the costs
imposed on fully initiated members. However, even with these relatively rich
data we failed to find a relationship between severity of costs and trust.
We did find that fraternity Player Bs returned a significantly greater amount
than Player Bs in the clubs or classes. Johnson and Medlin (2011) found that
the proportional amount returned to Player As was significantly influenced
by the proportion of the endowment that Player As initially sent; Player Bs who
received more, returned more. The decisions by Player Bs therefore represent
a measure of reciprocity that is largely based on the amount they receive. It
is possible that the members of fraternities are more trustworthy than club
members, but this is difficult to deduce from our results. It is more likely that
because the amount that Player A sends to Player B was tripled in our experiments, the insignificant differences between the amount sent between fraternities and clubs reached significance after tripling.
These results add to a growing body of research indicating that although
costs are positively correlated with trust and cooperation among religious
groups, these relationships do not hold for secular groups (Ruffle & Sosis, 2007;
Sosis & Bressler, 2003; Sosis & Ruffle, 2003, 2004). A fundamental difference
between the rites of secular and religious groups is that the rituals of secular
groups are mostly confined to initiation rites (e.g., hell nights, pledge periods),
while among religious communities rituals often take place frequently and repeatedly over time (e.g., weekly worship services) after initiation. It is possible
that the ongoing repetition of rituals, characteristic of many religions, is what
encourages high levels of intra-group trust and cooperation.
Additionally, while both secular and religious organizations have ideologies
and myths associated with the group, only religious belief systems appeal to
supernatural ideologies, and the coupling of supernatural beliefs with religious ritual may create a stronger sense of group belonging than rituals based
on secular ideologies (Purzycki & Sosis, 2013; Rappaport, 1999; Sosis & Bressler,
2003; Sosis & Ruffle, 2004). Thus, the lack of repeated rituals outside of initiation rites and a lack of supernatural ideologies associated with the group each
may partially explain the findings reported here.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
198
Shaver ET AL.
Rather than, or in addition to, differences in ritual frequency it may be that
the unfalsifiable nature of supernatural beliefs directly contributes to the
higher levels of trust experienced by religious communities (Rappaport, 1999).
Unlike secular ideologies, the members of religious communities are bound by
commitment to ideologies that are deeply felt and experienced as true despite
their unverifiable nature (Bulbulia 2009; Bulbulia & Sosis, 2009). Deeply felt
commitment to ideologies associated with supernatural worlds, often made
sacred through ritual practice, may have greater binding effects than mundane
empirically verifiable ideologies (Alcorta & Sosis, 2005).
Regardless, the findings reported here are limited in several regards. First,
we only indirectly assessed trust through interviews and an economic game.
Ethnographic research designs that directly observe cooperation within institutionalized social groups would provide insights about the dynamics of intragroup trust and further elucidate the findings reported here. Second, although
experimental studies show that shared collective goals increase cooperation
(Mitkidis, Sørensen, Nielbo, Andersen, & Lienard, 2013), we did not attempt
to interview participants about the existence of shared goals associated with
the group. It is possible that the members of clubs share similar goals (e.g.,
community service, getting good grades), while most fraternities lack shared
and specific goals, at least amongst all members. It remains possible that both
costs imposed on members and commitment to shared goals contributes to
increased trust. That is, because many fraternities lack shared goals but foster
trust by imposing costs, while clubs might encourage trust with shared goals
but without imposing significant costs, we failed to find a difference between
these two types of groups.
It is also possible that the benefits to costly membership in the secular
groups investigated here are not directly related to intra-group trust, but rather
to relative advantages in the mating pool. If correct, we would expect that costs
would be associated with both number of sexual partners and perceived attractiveness. Some data appear to support this possibility, as the severity of hazing
during initiation was found to be positively associated with prestige across
29 fraternities at the University of Washington, and across 31 chapters (i.e.,
across 31 universities) of the same fraternity (See Cimino, 2013a; 2013b). Perhaps
the members of high cost groups translate prestige into increased mating opportunities, and such a possibility is an avenue for future research. In other
words, it is possible that the high costs paid by the members of some religious
and secular communities return fundamentally different benefits. The benefits
of increased trust and increased attractiveness to potential mates, however, are
not necessarily mutually exclusive.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
199
Conclusion
Throughout human history religions have influenced social organization.
Although a large number of secular social groupings exist today, these are largely confined to modern large-scale industrialized societies (Norris & Inglehart,
2004). Purely secular social groupings are relatively absent from the cross-cultural record and the non-Western societies traditionally studied by anthropologists. Despite their recent evolutionary emergence, however, secular groups
share many attributes with religious groups. Both religious and secular groups
have secret knowledge available only to full members, both frequently require
that new members go through initiation rites, and both require that members
follow norms lest they be punished or banished. Additionally, both religious
and secular groups seem to favor adolescence as the appropriate period for
initiation, and human adolescents appear more motivated to join groups than
do humans at other stages of the lifespan (Alcorta, 2006; Lienard, 2011; Shaver
& Sosis, 2014). Although many have pointed out the drawbacks of studies that
rely too heavily on data drawn from U.S. undergraduate samples (e.g., Sears,
1986), in the case of high cost secular groups, they are an inherently important
population to investigate.
Regardless, future research ought to examine the features of shared goals
and ideologies that may impact trust, the extent to which such sharing encourages cooperation, and how different goals interact with costly requirements for membership. Work should also investigate the possibility that
similar levels of costly requirements return fundamentally different types of
benefits among different types of social organizations (i.e., religious vs. secular). Such undertakings would further extend this line of research, clarify the
findings reported here, and contribute to our understanding of how different
social groups are able to maintain and motivate divergent levels of trust and
cooperation.
Acknowledgments
During the preparation of this manuscript, Shaver was supported by a Royal
Society of New Zealand Marsden Fund Grant (ID: VUW 1321); Lang was supported by a grant to the Laboratory for Experimental Research of Religion
(CZ1.07/2.3.00/20.048), co-financed by the European Social Fund and the state
budget of the Czech Republic, and the Faculty of Arts, Masaryk University.
Sosis gratefully acknowledges support from a CTI Fellowship (Evolution and
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
200
Shaver ET AL.
Human Nature), an ESRC Large Grant (REF RES-060-25-388 0085) entitled
“Ritual, Community, and Conflict,” the John Templeton Foundation, and the
James Barnett Endowment. We would also like to thank the many research assistants who helped with data collection.
References
Abelson, M. & Faux, Z. (2013). Secret Handshakes Greet Frat Brothers on Wall Street.
Bloomberg News. Retrieved from: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-1223/secret-handshakes-greet-frat-brothers-on-wall-street.
Ahmed, A. M. (2009). Are Religious People More Prosocial? A Quasi‐Experimental
Study with Madrasah Pupils in a Rural Community in India. Journal for the Scientific
Study of Religion, 48, 368–374.
Ahmed, A. M., & Salas, O. (2011). Implicit influences of Christian religious representations on dictator and prisoner’s dilemma game decisions. The Journal of SocioEconomics, 40, 242–246.
Alcorta, C. S. (2006). Religion and the life course: Is adolescence an “experience expectant” period for religious transmission? In P. McNamara (Ed.), Where God and science meet: How brain and evolutionary studies alter our understanding of religion,
Vol. 1: Evolution, genes, and the religious brain (pp. 55–79). Westport: Praeger.
Benjamini, Y., and Hochberg, Y. (1995). Controlling the false discovery rate: a practical
and powerful approach to multiple testing. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society
Series B 57, 289–300.
Berg, R.J., Dickhaut, J., McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games
and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142.
Bulbulia, J. (2004). Religious costs as adaptations that signal altruistic intention.
Evolution and Cognition, 10, 19–38.
Bulbulia, J. (2009). Religiosity as mental time-travel. In. J. Schloss & M. Murray (Eds.).
The Believing Primate: Scientific, Philosophical, and Theological Reflections on
the Origin of Religion: Scientific, Philosophical, and Theological Reflections on the
Origin of Religion (pp. 44–75). OUP Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bulbulia, J., & Sosis, R. (2009). Ideology as cooperative affordance. Behavior and the
Brain Sciences, 32(6), 515–516.
Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction.
Princeton NJ, University Press, Princeton.
Campo, S., Poulos, G., & Sipple, J. W. (2005). Prevalence and profiling: Hazing among
college students and points of intervention. American Journal of Health Behavior,
29(2), 137–149.
Cimino, A. (2011). The evolution of hazing: Motivational mechanisms and the abuse of
newcomers. Journal of Cognition and Culture, 11(3–4), 241–267.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
201
Cimino, A. (2013a). Hazing as a manifestation of evolved psychology. Doctoral dissertation. University of California, Santa Barbara.
Cimino, A. (2013b). Predictors of hazing motivation in a representative sample of the
United States. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34, 446–452.
Cimino, A., & Delton, A. W. (2010). On the perception of newcomers. Human Nature,
21, 186–202.
Cribari-Neto, F., & Zeileis, A. (2010). Beta regression in R. Journal of Statistical Software,
34, 1–24.
Cronk, L., & Leech, B. L. (2012). Meeting at Grand Central: understanding the social and
evolutionary roots of cooperation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Delton, A. W., & Cimino, A. (2010). Exploring the evolved concept of NEWCOMER:
Experimental tests of a cognitive model. Evolutionary psychology: an international
journal of evolutionary approaches to psychology and behavior, 8, 317.
Eskelson, B., & Madsen, L. (2011). Estimating Riparian understory vegetation cover with
Beta regression and copula models. Forest Science, 57, 212–221.
Finkel, M. A. (2002). Traumatic injuries caused by hazing practices. The American journal of emergency medicine, 20(3), 228–233.
Frank, R. (1988). Passions within reason. New York: Norton.
Frank, R. (2001). Cooperation through emotional commitment. In R. Nesse (ed.),
Evolution and the capacity for commitment (pp. 57–76). New York: Russell Sage
Foundation.
Hill, K., Barton, M., & Hurtado, A. M. (2009). The emergence of human uniqueness: characters underlying behavioral modernity. Evolutionary Anthropology, 18(5), 187–200.
Iannaccone, L. (1992). Sacrifice and stigma: Reducing free-riding in cults, communes,
and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 271–291.
Iannaccone, L. (1994). Why strict churches are strong. American Journal of Sociology,
99, 1180–1211.
Irons, W. (1996). Morality, religion, and human nature. In W. Richardson and
W. Wildman (Eds.), Religion and science: History, method, and dialogue (pp. 375–
399). New York: Routledge.
Irons, W. (2001). Religion as a hard-to-fake sign of commitment. In R. Nesse (ed.),
Evolution and the capacity for commitment (292–309). New York: Russell Sage
Foundation.
Johnson, N. D. & Mislin, A. A. (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic
Psychology, 32, 865–889.
Kurzban, R., & Christner, J. (2011). Are supernatural beliefs commitment devices for
integroup conflict? In J. Forgas, A. Kruglanski, & K. Williams (Eds.), The 13th Sydney
Symposium of Social Psychology: Social Conflict and aggression (pp. 285–300). New
York: Psychology Press.
Leinard, P. (2011). Life-stages and risk avoidance: status and context-sensitivity in precaution systems. Neuroscience and Biobehavioral Reviews, 35, 1067–1074.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
202
Shaver ET AL.
Mitkidis, P., Sørensen, J., Nielbo, K. L., Andersen, M., & Lienard, P. (2013). Collectivegoal ascription increases cooperation in humans. PLoS ONE 8(5): e64776.
Norris, P., & Inglehart, R. (2011). Sacred and secular: Religion and politics worldwide.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nowak, M., & Highfield, R. (2011). SuperCooperators: Altruism, evolution, and why we
need each other to succeed. Simon and Schuster.
Pulliam, H. R., & Caraco, T. (1984). Living in groups: is there an optimal group size.
Behavioural ecology: an evolutionary approach, 2, 122–147.
Purzycki, B. G., & Arakchaa, T. (2013). Ritual behavior and trust in the Tyva Republic.
Current Anthropology, 54(3), 381–388.
Purzycki, B. G., & Sosis, R. (2013). The extended religious phenotype and the adaptive
coupling of ritual and belief. Israel Journal of Ecology and Evolution, 59, 99–108.
R Core Team (2014). R: A language and environment for statistical computing.
R. Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria. URL: http://www
.R-project.org/.
Rappaport, R. A. (1999). Ritual and Religion in the Making of Humanity. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Ridley, M. (1996). The origins of virtue: human instincts and the origins of cooperation.
U.K.: Penguin Books.
Ruffle, B., & Sosis, R. (2007). Does it pay to pray? Costly ritual and cooperation.
The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 7, 1–35 (Article 18).
Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Schelling, T. (2001). Commitment: Deliberate versus involuntary. In R. Nesse (ed.),
Evolution and the capacity for commitment (48–56). New York: Russell Sage
Foundation.
Sears, D. O. (1986). College sophomores in the laboratory: Influences of a narrow data
base on social psychology’s view of human nature. Journal of personality and social
psychology, 51(3), 515.
Shaver, J. H., & Sosis, R. (2014). How does male ritual behavior vary across the lifespan?
Human Nature, 25(1), 136–160.
Smithson, M., & Verkuilen, J. (2006). A better lemon squeezer? Maximum-likelihood
regression with beta-distributed dependent variables. Psychological Methods, 11,
54–71.
Soler, Montserrat. (2012). Costly signaling, ritual and cooperation: evidence from
Candomblé, an Afro-Brazilian religion. Evolution and Human Behavior, 33(4),
346–356.
Sosis, R. (2000). Religion and intra-group cooperation: Preliminary results of a comparative analysis of utopian communities. Cross-Cultural Research, 34, 70– 87.
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
Costs do not Explain Trust among secular groups
203
Sosis, R. (2003). Why aren’t we all Hutterites? Costly signaling theory and religious behavior. Human Nature, 14, 91–127.
Sosis, R. (2005). Does religion promote trust? The role of signaling, reputation, and
punishment. Interdisciplinary Journal of Research on Religion, 1, 1–30.
Sosis, R., & Bressler, E. (2003). Cooperation and commune longevity: A test of the costly
signaling theory of religion. Cross-Cultural Research, 37, 211–239.
Sosis, R., & Ruffle, B. (2003). Religious ritual and cooperation: Testing for a relationship
on Israeli religious and secular kibbutzim. Current Anthropology, 44, 713–722.
Sosis, R., & Ruffle, B. (2004). Ideology, religion, and the evolution of cooperation: field
tests on Israeli kibbutzim. Research in Economic Anthropology, 23, 89–117.
Stasinopoulos, D., & Rigby, R. (2007). Generalized additive models for location scale
and shape (GAMLSS) in R. Journal of Statistical Software, 23, 1–46.
Tan, J. H., & Vogel, C. (2008). Religion and trust: An experimental study. Journal of
Economic Psychology, 29, 832–848.
Tiger, L. (1969). Men in groups. New York: Random House.
West, B., Welch, K., & Galecki, A. (2007). Linear mixed models: a practical guide using
statistical software. New York: Chapman & Hall/CRC.
Zahavi, A., & Zahavi, A. (1997). The handicap principle: A missing piece of Darwin’s puzzle. New York: Oxford University Press.
Appendix A: Model Specification
Self-rated Trust
In Equation 1, y represents self-rated trust to other group members; β0 is the intercept;
other β’s are fixed effects; u0 represents a random intercept for a group; ε is a beta distributed error term; μ is a location parameter; and Φ is a dispersion parameter.
Equation 1: y = β0 + β1(group type = club) + β2(group type = class) + β3(sex = female) +
β4(religiosity) + u0 + ε ̴ normal (μ,σ2)
Trust Game, Player A
In Equation 2, y represents the amount sent by player A; g is a logit link; β0 is the intercept; other β’s are fixed effects; u0 represents a random intercept for a group; ε is a
beta distributed error term; μ is a location parameter; and Φ is a dispersion parameter.
Equation 2: g(y) = β0 + β1(group type = club) + β2(group type = class) + β3(sex =
female) + β4(religiosity) + u0 + ε ̴ beta (μ,Φ)
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204
204
Shaver ET AL.
Trust Game, Player B
In Equation 3, y is the percent returned by Player B to Player A; g is a logit link; β0 is the
intercept; other βs are fixed effects; u0 represents a random intercept for a group; ε is a
beta distributed error term; μ is a location parameter; and Φ is a dispersion parameter.
Equation 3: g(y) = β0 + β1(group type = club) + β2(group type = class) + β3(sex =
female) + u0 + ε ̴ beta (μ,Φ)
Journal of Cognition and Culture 18 (2018) 180–204