Health and Economic Development:
Evidence from non-OECD Countries
Alberto Bucci∗
Lorenzo Carbonari†
Monia Ranalli‡
Giovanni Trovato§
Abstract
This paper studies the empirical relationship between a country’s health and its
GDP dynamics in low- and middle-income countries. We employ a semi-parametric
technique, which combines mixed panel data models and cluster analysis to account for
unobserved heterogeneity, which is an important source of estimation bias in growth
regressions. We estimate a version of Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992) augmented
with human capital, in the form of both education and health. Our estimates show that
population’s health, here proxied by the life expectancy at birth, has a positive, sizable,
and statistically significant effect on both the level and the growth rate of the real per
capita GDP.
Keywords: Health; Education and Human Capital; Economic Development and Growth;
Finite Mixture Models; Classification.
JEL codes: I15; I25; J24; O41; C14.
∗
Università di Milano (DEMM and FinGro Lab), CEIS Tor Vergata, and RCEA (Rimini Center for
Economic Analysis).
†
Corresponding author.
University of Rome “Tor Vergata”, DEF and CEIS. E-mail address:
[email protected].
‡
Sapienza Università di Roma.
§
Università di Roma “Tor Vergata”, DEF and CEIS.
1
1
Introduction
Following to COVID-19 pandemic outbreak, health policies are a topic of renewed
interest and lively debate among policy makers and scholars. Less developed economies
are comparatively more exposed to the pandemic emergency, due to their weakness in
terms of health structures. The consequent risk is an additional slow down along
their development path, since health is one of the most important driver of economic
growth. Using a simple theoretical framework, this paper provides a model and a
robust empirical evidence on the close link between a country’s health and its economic
prosperity.
We build on Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), which convincingly provides evidence that: i) a standard Solow (1956) model, augmented with the inclusion of the
accumulation of human capital, can provide a better understanding of the international
differences in income per capita, and ii) the existing disparities in saving rates, education, and population change can account for most of the cross-country variations in
living standards. We extend their empirical model in order to answer two questions
which are not explicitly addressed in their paper, thus remaining open for discussion.
First, what is the role of health in determining a country’s living standards (measured
by the level of real per capita GDP) and its economic development (measured by the
growth rate of real per capita GDP)? Second, what is the role of health in explaining
cross-country differences in economic development?
Since human capital can appear both in the form of education/schooling and in the
form of health, we start our analysis by presenting a simple augmented version of the
Solow model which accounts for this. Then we take our model to the data, using a
large panel of low- and middle-income countries. To empirically assess the interplay
between GDP, physical capital, education and health, four well-known econometric
issues must be tackled: (i) measurement error (what is the correct measure for the
health status?), (ii) omitted variable (both the level and the growth rate of GDP
could be affected by other variables not included in our model), (iii) simultaneity
between regressors and response variable, (iv) heterogeneity in country-specific effects
of human capital on GDP. All these issues are at the root of endogeneity bias and
2
unobserved heterogeneity bias. Each of them, indeed, may produce correlation between
the estimated residuals and regressors (see e.g. Griliches and Hausman, 1986; Davidson
and McKinnon,1993, Wooldrige, 2010): the higher the correlation, the starker the
bias in the significance of the estimated coefficients. Several estimators have been
proposed to solve this problem, such as the Two Stage Least Squares, the dynamic
Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) or the Two Stage GMM with Instrumental
Variables. In this paper, we follow an alternative route and propose a flexible Bivariate
Finite Mixture model, which, as we show below, in our case, performs better than
both OLS and GMM. The key feature of this econometric model is the inclusion of a
latent term in the estimated equation. The latent term is distribution free and clusterspecific (e.g., Rabe-Hecksc 2004, Aitkin Rocci, 2002). A further advantage is that this
approach allows for a posterior classification, such that within each cluster the classical
homogeneity assumption still holds. In this way, we are able to study the role that
health-differences have in explaining international income-differences. Notably, our
cluster analysis complements the existing classifications, which are mainly obtained
through efficiency analysis (health output maximization or cost minimization).1
Our study reveals that, at least for non-OECD countries, aggregate health – here
proxied by life expectancy at birth, as it is standard in the macroeconomic literature
– positively affects both the level and the growth rate of real per capita GDP. In the
baseline Bivariate Finite Mixture model, a one-year increase in life expectancy raises
the long-run level of per capita GDP by 5%. Hence, the link between overall health
status and economic development appears to be rather substantial across countries.
Importantly, this effect is robust to changes in our econometric strategy and/or the
inclusion of other explanatory variables in our regressions.
Literature review This paper is a contribution to the empirical literature which
quantifies the direct and indirect effects of health on living standards and GDP growth
1
Notice that, despite our empirical model can not identify per se any causal relationship between popu-
lation’s health and GDP level/growth rate, which are, however somehow provided by the augmented Solow
model, it is able to capture the mutual dependency between covariates and response variables, assuming
that such a dependency may vary across countries.
3
in low- and middle-income countries. By looking only at the direct effects of health
on income, Weil (2007) finds that they are not particularly sizable: a 5 years increase
in life expectancy would increase labor productivity by 3.6% and output per capita by
the same amount at the steady state. To have a raw idea of what these figures might
imply, note that along the 2010’s Preston curve an increase in life expectancy of 5 years
would be associated with a doubling of output per capita. In line with Weil (2007),
Ashraf et al. (2009) estimate that an increase in life expectancy from 40 to 60 years
would raise GDP per capita in the long-run by only 15%, and, for the first 30 years
after such an increase, output per capita would be lower than if life expectancy had
not improved at all.
The size of the indirect effects from a better health seems instead remarkable. Hurd,
McFadden and Gan (1998) find that increased expectation of longevity leads to greater
household’s wealth in the United States. Lee et al. (2000) argue that rising life expectancy accounts for the boom in savings in Taiwan since the 1960s. Bloom, Canning,
and Graham (2003) find a positive effect of life expectancy on national savings, using
cross-country data. Zhang and Zhang (2005) construct a three-period overlappinggenerations model showing that rising longevity reduces fertility and enhances savings
and schooling investment, even though these effects are empirically small. Bleakley
and Lange (2009), and Jayachandran and Lleras-Muney (2009) provide robust evidence that higher life expectancy increases educational attainments at the individual
level.
2
The recent regression results of Madsen (2016) clearly show that, since 1870,
health has been highly influential for economic growth in 21 OECD countries because
it affects not only human capital investment, but also ideas-production.
Our paper is also related to the strand of literature which focuses on health’s effects
across different sample-compositions. Weil (2007 and 2005) suggests that health’s
positive effect on GDP is stronger across poor countries. For rich countries, instead,
the existing empirical evidence is mixed. For a sample of 31 high income countries over
the period 1995-2010, Bucci, Carbonari and Trovato (2019) obtain estimates for the
coefficient of life expectancy ranging from 0.399 to 0.458. For a panel of countries over
2
See also de la Croix and Licandro (1999), Kalemli-Ozcan, Ryder and Weil (2000), Boucekkine, de la
Croix and Licandro (2002 and 2003), Chakraborty (2004), Cervellati and Sunde (2005), and Soares (2005).
4
the period 1960-1990, Bloom, Canning, and Sevilla (2004) find that a one-year increase
in population’s life expectancy contributes to an increase of 4% in aggregate GDP (an
effect that the same authors reckon as extraordinary large). Cervellati and Sunde
(2011) and Hansen and Lönstrup (2015) document a strong and robust positive causal
effect of life expectancy on per capita GDP in countries which had already experienced
the onset of the demographic transition by 1940. Acemoglu and Johnson (2007) find
that life expectancy has a positive impact on aggregate GDP but a negative one (despite
often not statistically significant) on per capita and per worker GDP, for a panel of 47
countries over the period 1940-1980. They also find that health improvements have a
negative causal effect on economic growth.
Outline The paper is organized as follows. After deriving the augmented Solow
model (Section 2), we develop the econometric analysis, present the main results and
show how unobserved heterogeneity can help in explaining differences across countries
(Section 3). Then, we discuss our main findings along with a comparison with other
contributions closest to ours (Section 4). Section 5 concludes.
2
The augmented Solow model
As in Barro (2013), we assume that production at time t takes the following CobbDouglas form:
Yt = Ktα Etβ Htγ (At Lt )1−α−β−γ
with α, β, γ > 0
and 0 < α + β + γ < 1
(1)
where K, E, H, L and A denote physical capital, human capital in the form of education, human capital in the form of health, raw labor and the exogenous laboraugmenting technological progress, respectively. In equation (1), the contribution to
total real GDP of raw labor, human capital in the form of education and human capital
in the form of health (as reflected, respectively, by the elasticities 1 − α − β − γ, β,
and γ) is potentially dissimilar across each other and different from that of physical
capital, as well. For the sake of simplicity, the total of labor input (L) is also assumed
to correspond to total population. The dynamics of the size of population and the level
of technology are exogenous and obey, respectively to Lt = L0 ent and At = A0 egt .
5
At each date t, the amount of effective labor is At Lt , and grows at rate (n + g).
Physical capital, human capital in the form of education and human capital in the form
of health are three reproducible factor inputs. The economy-wide budget constraint is:
Yt = Ktα Etβ Htγ (At Lt )1−α−β−γ = Ct + IKt + IEt + IHt
(2)
Thus, the same production function applies to physical capital, education, health,
and consumption: once produced, one unit of output can interchangeably be transformed, instantaneously and without costs, into units of consumption, physical capital,
human capital in the form of schooling, and human capital in the form of health.
Let now kt ≡
Kt
A t Lt ,
et ≡
Et
A t Lt
and ht ≡
Ht
A t Lt
define the variables Kt , Et and Ht per
unit of effective labor. The production function in intensive form is given by:
yt ≡
Yt
= ktα eβt hγt
At L t
(3)
Let now sk , se and sh denote, respectively, the exogenous fractions of total income
invested in physical capital, education and health, with s ≡ sk + se + sh being the total
saving rate of the economy. We assume that these saving rates are time invariant. The
evolution of the three capital stocks is given by:
k̇t = sk yt − (n + g + δ)kt
(4)
ėt = se yt − (n + g + d)et
(5)
ḣt = sh yt − (n + g + d)ht
(6)
We continue to follow Barro (2013, p. 353) in assuming that the exogenous depreciation rate of physical capital (δ > 0) differs from the exogenous depreciation rate of
education and health (d > 0).
Eqs. 4-6 imply that the economy converges to a steady state equilibrium (defined
6
by k̇t = ėt = ḣt = 0 ) in which:
1
1−α−β−γ
h∗ =
"
sαk sβe s1−α−β
h
(n + g + d)1−α (n + g + δ)α
#
e∗ =
"
sαk sγh se1−α−γ
(n + g + d)1−α (n + g + δ)α
#
"
sβe sγh sk1−β−γ
(n + g + d)β+γ (n + g + δ)1−β−γ
k
∗
=
(7)
1
1−α−β−γ
(8)
#
1
1−α−β−γ
(9)
After some algebraic steps, it is possible to show that at the steady state the relation
linking the level of per capita income, to (some of) the exogenous variables of the model
and, more importantly, to the level of health, h∗ , is represented by:3
∗
Yt
β
α
ln
= ln A0 + gt +
ln(se ) +
ln(sk )
Lt
1−α−β
1−α−β
α
β
ln(n + g + d) −
ln(n + g + δ) +
−
1−α−β
1−α−β
γ
+
ln(h∗ )
(10)
1−α−β
Following Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), it is also easy to show that the growth
of per capita income, along the transition, is a function of the determinants of the
ultimate steady state and the initial level of income, i.e
∗
Yt
Y0
Yt /Lt
= ζ ln
− ζ ln
ln
Y0 /L0
Lt
L0
(λ > 0)
(11)
where Y0 /L0 is the per capita income at some initial date, ζ ≡ 1 − e−λt and λ
indicates the speed of conditional convergence toward the steady state. Plugging (10)
into (11) yields:
ln
3
Yt /Lt
Y0 /L0
β
α
=ζ
ln(se ) + ζ
ln(sk )−
1−α−β
1−α−β
β
α
−ζ
ln(n + g + d) +
ln(n + g + δ) +
1−α−β
1−α−β
Y0
γ
+ ζ ln A0 + gt
(12)
ln(h∗ ) − ζ ln
+ζ
1−α−β
L0
See Bucci, Carbonari and Trovato (2019) for the derivation of equation (10).
7
3
Empirical analysis
Table 1: Descriptive statistics: mean, standard deviation, min, median and max.
Variable
Mean
St. Dev.
Min
Median
Max
5-years avg. per capita GDP growth rate
2.165
4.422
life expectancy at birth
64.97
9.5
-37.493
2.296
29.617
31.96
68.04
81.95
log of per capita real GDP
8.005
0.969
4.959
7.977
10.496
log of the ratio real domestic investment to GDP
-1.883
0.621
-4.386
-1.777
-0.472
log of HC index
0.478
0.313
0.000
0.468
1.000
log of (g + n + δ)
-2.679
0.212
-7.634
-2.630
-1.742
Data Our sample consists of 72 non-OECD, non-oil countries along the period 19952014 (3,203 observations). The data are from the Penn World Table 8.1 (PWT hereafter) and the World Bank. The variables taken into account are real GDP, physical
capital, population, education and life expectancy at birth. We measure the population growth rate as the average rate of growth of the working-age population, where
the working age is defined as 15 to 65. As a measure of the theoretical variable sk
we use the average share of real investment (including government investment) on real
GDP. The human capital index (HC, provided by PWT) and the life expectancy at
birth (provided by the World Bank) proxy se and sh , respectively.4 For simplicity,
we assume d = δ, i.e. human and physical capital have the same depreciation rate.
Summary statistics are provided in Table 1.
Econometric strategy The econometric part of the paper is aimed at i) assessing
quantitatively the relative contribution of health on living standards and real GDP
growth, and ii) quantify the cross-country differences in long-run income and growth,
taking into account the dependence between GDP and health. We start by employing
OLS Fixed Effects (FE) and then GMM estimators to deal with the reverse causation
4
The HC index is based on the average years of schooling from Barro and Lee (2013) and an assumed rate
of return to education, based on Mincer equation estimates. Alternative measures for population health are
the health adjusted life expectancy, the adult mortality rate or child mortality. Data series for these variables,
however, are available only for shorter duration and/or with respect to a limited number of countries.
8
between the level of real per capita GDP and country’s health status (see Weil, 2014;
Tamakoshi and Hamori, 2015; and Linden and Ray, 2017). Since our aim is to show
that these regression models are not able to solve the bias due to the correlation
between residuals and regressors, in the following paragraph, for the sake of brevity we
restrict our attention only on the regression for the level of GDP.5 Then, we present the
flexible Bivariate Finite Mixture model (BFMM, hereafter), which allows for parameter
heterogeneity among countries with similar fundamentals (see Alfò and Trovato, 2004;
Alfò, Trovato and Waldmann 2008; Owen, Videras and Davis, 2009; Ng and Mclachlan,
2014; Yu, Malley and Ghosh, 2014; Lu, Huang and Zhu, 2016; Alfò, Carbonari and
Trovato, 2020).6 Moreover, through this estimation procedure, we are able to provide
a cluster analysis, i.e. we sort countries into groups based on the homogeneity of the
conditional joint distribution of their income levels and life expectancies with respect
to the estimated unobservable factors.7
OLS and GMM The empirical counterpart of the theoretical equation (10) is given
by:
ln(y)it = a1 + β1 ln(se )it + β2 ln(sk )it + β3 ln(n + g + δ)it + β4 ln(sh )it + νit
(13)
As stressed above, due to the endogeneity of life expectancy (sh ), we can get incon5
6
Results for the growth equation (12) are available upon request.
Notice that measurement error, omitted variable and varying parameters may be additional source of
unobserved heterogeneity (and thus, model mis-specification).
7
Consider the case of varying parameters among sample and suppose that the influence of xi on the
response, yi , is country specific. In this case, βi = β + ui where ui is the country specific effect for subject
i = 1, . . . , N , with E(ui ) = 0, and β is the OLS estimator, capturing the average effect of xi on yi . Formally:
yi = α + (β + ui )xi + ǫi
If we ignore the country specific heterogeneity and estimate the model with a homogeneous estimator (e.g.
OLS), we get:
yi = α + βxi + (ǫi + ui xi )
= α + βxi + ǫ̃i
As the classical endogeneity bias, the variable xi is correlated with the error term ǫ̃i .
9
sistent estimates for β4 . A possible solution is to to use IV regressions (both two
stage or GMM) for panel data, in which the instruments are the intercept and a vector of instruments correlated with the suspected endogenous variable and uncorrelated
with the gaussian error. According to Lewbel (1997 and 2012), we estimate equation
(13) using as instruments some transformations of the covariates and response. Such
transformations are useful when there is no available additional data or when it is not
possible to set a model to correlate instrument with unobserved variables. Here, the
choice of the regressors is driven by our augmented Solow model. Table 3 reports the
estimates of equation (13) for the OLS FE model and for three different specifications
for the GMM with Continuous Updating Estimator (CUE): GMM1 includes only the
Lewbel (2012) instruments, GMM2 includes only the lagged (from t − 1 to t − 3 values
of covariates) while GMM3 presents both Lewbel’s instruments and the lagged variables. All models are estimated controlling for time and subject’s correlation and are
estimated with robust standard errors.
Results for the OLS FE model and GMM models, which are more robust for heteroscedasticity (e.g. see Kleibergen, 2005, Caner, 2010, Baum et al., 2012), are not
univocal. Once we correct for the endogeneity of life expectancy, we can observe that
the effect of investment rate (sk ) and human capital (se ) are not statistically different from zero. GMM1 and GMM2 deliver the same estimated parameter for β4 while
GMM3 estimates a parameter for life expectancy quite similar to that obtained from
OLS FE. For the OLS FE model all the estimated parameters seem to be in line with
the standard literature on growth, for the models GMM1 and GMM2 only the parameter for population growth and the rate of depreciation (n + g + δ) is significant while
for GMM3 is significant also that for human capital (se ). Several issues emerge with
respect to the GMM models. Estimates are sensitive to the change of the selected
instruments, this indicating the presence of a possible model uncertainty problem, i.e.
uncertainty about the actual model we have selected to estimate equation (13). The
Sagan, Hansen and Jensen’s test for the orthogonality and endogeneity of instruments
does not reject the assumption that the instruments are valid, i.e. uncorrelated with
the error term. The Hansen J-statistic shows that, once we include instruments in our
regression, we can consider the life expectancy (sh ) as orthogonal. The under identifi-
10
Table 2: Panel Instrumental Variable Results
log of (g + n + δ)
log of investment rate (sk )
log of HC index (se )
log of life expectancy (sh )−1
controlled for Time and Subjects
R-squared
Number of individuals
OLS FE
Panel GMM CUE 1
Panel GMM CUE 2
Panel GMM CUE 3
-0.300***
-0.950***
-0.678***
-0.390***
(0.041)
(0.254)
(0.193)
(0.080)
0.036**
0.041
0.028
0.008
(0.014)
(0.057)
(0.0559)
(0.0540)
0.4427***
-0.201
-0.120
0.567***
(0.035)
(0.316)
(0.336)
(0.182)
0.474***
1.268***
1.267***
0.380*
(0.039)
(0.384)
(0.440)
(0.220)
YES
YES
YES
YES
0.3721
0.3548
0.2814
0.3678
3203
2986
2986
3203
Underidentification tests
Kleibergen-Paap LM χ2 (3)
13.456
14.70
15.45
(P-value)
0.0025
0.0021
0.016
8.32
14.03
12.65
10% maximal LIML size
5.44
6.46
4.45
15% maximal LIML size
3.87
4.36
3.34
3.30
3.69
2.87
Weak-instrument-robust inference
Kleibergen-Paap Wald F
Stock − Y ogo critical values
20% maximal LIML size
Overidentification test
Sargan-Hansen-Jensen
4.23
2.454
7.97
(P-value)
0.402
0.293
0.158
0.90
2.093
7.01
0.34
0.143
0.402
Orthogonality Statistics for life expectancy
Hansen J statistics
(P-value)
Test for Normal Residuals
Shapiro Francia (P-value)
0.006
0.004
0.007
0.004
Shapiro Wilk (P-value)
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
Instrumets
q vector as in Lebwel
Lagged covariates and
q vector as in Lebwel
(1997 and 2012)
trend variable
(1997 and 2012) and
lagged covariates.
11
cation test suggests that we may reject the assumption of not identified model. Finally,
looking at the weak of instrument test, we can reject the assumption of a small correlation between instruments and covariates (see the LIML maximum critical values). To
sum up, these tests, though significant, do not help us to discriminate the best model
to describe the relationship between per capita GDP, human capital and health status.
Figure A1 shows that the residual are still informative, meaning that the assumptions
about their orthogonality and homogeneity do not hold. Observations are clusterized,
some unobserved heterogeneity is still present. This is confirmed by the Shapiro Wilk
and the Shapiro Francia tests (that are robust for heteroscedasticity), which reject the
assumption of Gaussian residuals. Consequently, all the models presented in Table 3,
regardless of both the estimator (FE or GMM) or the instruments employed, are not
able to correct the parameters and standard errors bias due to the correlation between
residuals and covariates.
BFMM To avoid uncertainty about instruments and to allow for a country-specific
effects, we modify the empirical model as follows. We assume that the dependence
between the endogenous variables and regressors is not the same for all countries.
Therefore, we introduce a mixture model to explain the existing heterogeneity among
countries and to deliver a cluster analysis. The mixture model is obtained as the
non-parametric estimation of a model involving two correlated random effects and it
leads to a weighted sum of bivariate distributions. This allows to capture the countryspecific effect. The advantage of this model is twofold. First, it allows to correct the
bias between residuals and covariates. Second, it permits to group countries within
homogeneous clusters where cluster specific homogeneity implies unbiased standard
errors and more reliable estimates. The model requires a local independence assumption, i.e. there exists independence among variables given the random effects. This
does not mean that the model requires independence marginally. However, the cluster
memberships do not vary over time. The belonging to a specific cluster is based on
the maximum a posteriori criterion (MAP), i.e. the country is assigned to the cluster
showing the highest posterior probability. This can be done using the output of the (E
step of the) EM algorithm, which we describe in Appendix A.
12
Following Linden and Ray (2017), we assume that real GDP levels and life expectancy are jointly correlated in some points in time.8 Three main parameters are
involved in the distributions of our flexible BFMM: location, scale and shape. Let
yitj be continuous variables corresponding to two (j = 1, 2) outcomes observed over
n (i = 1, 2, . . . , n) countries and time t (t = 1, 2, . . . , T ), with parameters θ itj =
(θitj1 , θitj2 , θitj3 ). Since we are interested in understanding how much health affects
GDP level and its dynamics, and viceversa, we run two alternative models: one, labelled BFMMY , in which the outcomes will be the level of the real per capita GDP
and the aggregate level of health and one, labelled BFMMg , in which the outcomes
will be the real per capita GDP 5-years growth rate and the aggregate level of health.
Aggregate health will be proxied by life expectancy at birth.
Let x′itj = (1, xitj1 , . . . , xitjPj ) and z′itj = (1, zitj1 , . . . , zitjQj ) two sets of covariates,
which can vary over outcomes. To account for potential heterogeneity among countries
a matrix of correlated random effects is introduced, where each row is given by ui =
(ui1 ui2 ). It follows that the likelihood function can be written as
n Z Y
2 Y
T
Y
L(θ) =
f (yitj | uij , xitj , zitj )b(ui )dui
U
i=1
(14)
j=1 t=1
where f (·) is a generic probability density function and U is the support for b(ui ), the
bivariate distribution density of ui , with E(ui ) = 0. The presence of random effects
makes the parameter estimation not always feasible due to the presence of multidimensional integrals. However, if the multivariate random variable follows a multivariate
normal distribution, different approaches exist in literature to approximate it. Nevertheless, the normality assumption may result to be too strong. A more flexible approach
is to adopt a non parametric maximum likelihood approach, without defining a specific
parametric distribution for ui . This leads to a bivariate finite mixture model (see Lindsay, 1983). Formally, random effects can be approximated by a discrete distribution of
Cj ≤ n support points associated to pc1 c2 mass joint probabilities attached to locations
8
Notice that the flexible BFMM allows to deal with non-trivial correlation structure. For instance,
omitted covariates may affect both real GDP and aggregate health. It is well known that when responses
are correlated (in our case, real GDP level and life expectancy), the univariate approach is less efficient than
the multivariate one.
13
(ui1 = uc1 , ui2 = uc2 ) for cj = 1, . . . , Cj as follows
C1 X
C2
2 Y
T
n X
Y
Y
L(θ) =
p c1 c 2
f (yitj | ui1 = uc1 , ui2 = uc2 , xitj , zitj )
i=1
c1 =1 c2 =1
(15)
j=1 t=1
where pc1 c2 = Pr(ui1 = uc1 , ui2 = uc2 ) is the joint probability associated to each
pair of locations (uc1 , uc2 ). In other words, the bivariate integral is approximated
by a bivariate weighted sum. By the definition of weighted sum, it follows that the
weights have to be positive and have to satisfy the following constraints: both univariate
P 1
P C2
P
and bivariate weights should sum to 1, i.e. C
c1 c2 pc1 c2 = 1,
c1 pc1 =
c 2 p c2 =
P C2
P C1
pc1 = Pr(ui1 = uc1 ) = c2 pc1 c2 and pc2 = Pr(ui2 = uc2 ) = c1 pc1 c2 , respectively.
The number of support points (and thus the number of mixture components) may,
in principle, be different among outcomes. It leads to a finite mixture model with
C1 × C2 components, where each of the C1 locations are matched with each of the C2
locations of the second component.
Finite Mixture models overcome the issues, in observational studies, of OLS and
GMM with reference to confounding and measurement error. Recalling equations (10)
and (12) and their corresponding empirical log-likelihoods (14), the BFMMY and the
BFMMg can be written respectively as
E [ln(y)it,j=1 |ui1 , Xit ] = ai1 + β1 ln(se )it + β2 ln(sk )it + β3 ln(n + g + δ)it (16)
+ β4 ln(sh )it−1
E [ln(sh )it,j=2 |ui2 , Xit ] = ai2 + a1 ln(y)it−1
(17)
and
E [γit,j=1 |ui1 , Xit ] = ai1 + ξ0 ln(y)it−1 + ξ1 ln(se )it + ξ2 ln(sk )it + ξ3 ln(n + g + δ)it
+ ξ4 ln(sh )it−1
(18)
E [ln(sh )it,j=2 |ui2 , Xit ] = ai2 + a2 ln(y)it−1
(19)
where Xit is the vector of covariates for country i at time t, while ln(y)it is log of the
per capita GDP, γit is its 5 years average growth rate, ai1 and ai2 are the two random
intercepts estimating the country specific unobserved (or unmeasured) characteristics,
14
affecting the relationship between response variables and ln(sh )it via the locations ui
and uj in equation (14).
15
Table 3: Estimates
BFMMY
s.e.
BFMMg
s.e.
a01
6.194
0.105
23.780
1.653
a02
7.001
0.140
20.343
1.542
a03
7.624
0.106
26.620
1.774
a04
5.546
0.100
GDP level & GDP growth
Intercept
16
a05
6.658
0.102
log of investment rate (sk )
0.116
0.012
1.542
0.137
log of HC index (se )
0.433
0.034
0.878
0.372
log of (g + n + δ)
-0.460
0.037
0.419
0.434
log of life expectancy (sh )−1
0.445
0.040
3.413
0.403
-2.431
0.163
-0.992
0.014
1.351
0.013
a01
19.592
1.721
14.588
1.218
a02
8.942
0.065
19.585
1.198
GDP−1
ln(σ)
Life expectancy (sh )
a03
3.074
1.571
3.066
1.245
a04
14.595
1.360
8.934
1.248
GDP−1
6.010
0.155
6.011
0.144
ln(σ)
1.681
0.014
1.681
0.013
Note: in BFMMY and BFMMg the number of intercepts, in both regressions, depends on the number of univariate locations. Instrumented variable: life expectancy−1 .
Table 3 reports results for the two Bivariate Finite Mixture Models, BFMMY , for
the levels of per capita GDP, and BFMMg , for the rates of growth of GDP.9 The results strongly support our augmented version of the Solow model with education and
health.10 Both BFMMY and BFMMg rely on the assumption that one specific source
of unobserved heterogeneity bias is due to the bivariate relationship between observed
income (levels and growth rates) and life expectancy. This source of unobserved heterogeneity may affect the significance of the estimated parameters. Following equation
(14), we set the intercept for country i as ai = a + ui , where latent term ui has an
unspecified random discrete distribution with E(ui ) = 0. Since ui is country specific
we can group countries, with same latent term, in cluster for which the standard OLS
homogeneity assumption holds.
In BFMMY , the coefficients of sk , se and (n+g+δ) are in line with the literature and
our OLS estimates. The estimated elasticity of output with respect to physical capital
is relatively low (0.116), while that of human capital is relatively high (0.433), although
still in line with the microeconomic literature on private returns from schooling (see
e.g Arnold et al., 2011). Human capital is also found to be an important factor for
growth (0.878).11 The contribution of aggregate health is positive both on the level
(0.445) and on the growth (3.413) of per capita income, i.e. a one-year increase in life
expectancy raises the long-run level of per capita GDP by 5%. Notice that despite the
regression for life expectancy in the two models is the same, the estimates are different.
This is due to the fact that, within each component, we have a weighted regression in
9
In clusterwise regressions, the standards errors are obtained by the bootstrap method based on 500
samples.
10
In the two systems of equations presented here, human capital in the form of education/schooling appears
as a control only in equations (16) and (18). We run regressions, available upon request, in which it appears
even in the two equations for life expectancy with no significant change in our results. Given the importance
of education, as a productive input in the augmented Solow model, we also estimate a three-equation model
with human capital added as a third response variable. In this case, however, we obtain less accurate
estimates.
11
As a robustness check, we run our regression using the average years of education in working age
population, as an alternative proxy for human capital. Qualitatively, our results do not change. Estimates
are available upon request.
17
which the univariate weights are obtained as a marginalization of the bivariate posterior
probabilities. The posterior probabilities involve both responses, i.e. life expectancy
and per capita GDP in BFMMY , and life expectancy and per capita GDP growth in
BFMMg .
Since the number of groups are determined by how many different latent terms
exist for the sample, we choose the optimal number of support points (ui ) following
the Bayesian information criterion (BIC). Table A4 shows BIC values for the two
multivariate models (BFMMY and BFMMg ). Such values reject for both models the
hypothesis of no clustering in favor of:
i) a BFMMY containing 5 clusters with respect to the level of per capita income
and 4 clusters with respect to life expectancy, and
ii) a BFMMg containing 3 clusters with respect to the growth rate of per capita
income and 4 clusters with respect to life expectancy.
Tables A5 and A7 present our classifications while Tables A6 and A8 report descriptive statistics for each cluster in BFMMY and BFMMg , respectively. Figures A4-A11
show the patterns of GDP, levels and growth, and life expectancy over time across countries. In the BFMMY , we identify five clusters with respect to GDP levels and four
with respect to life expectancy. The cluster K1 =3 (Argentina, Barbados, Botswana,
Brazil, Bulgaria, Costa Rica, Croatia, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Malaysia, Malta,
Mauritius, Panama, Serbia and South Africa) is the one in which the unobserved factors that affect aggregate income are the strongest (i.e., a03 =7.624). Not surprisingly,
this cluster is the one with the highest per capita GDP, with a cluster mean of 9.23
(see the last column in Table A6). Analogously, the cluster K2 =1 (Albania, Argentina,
Armenia, Belize, Bulgaria, China, Costa Rica, Croatia, Cyprus, El Salvador, Jamaica,
Jordan, Malta, Myanmar, Panama, Paraguay, Romania, Serbia, Sri Lanka, Tajikistan
and Thailand) is the one in which the unobserved factors that affect life expectancy are
the strongest (i.e., a01 =19.592). Tandon et al. (2000), who produce a rankings-based
comparison of the efficiency of the health care system of 191 countries, list many of
the countries included in the cluster K2 =1 among the most efficient ones: Malta (7th),
Cyprus (24th), Costa Rica (36th), Croatia (43rd), Jamaica (53rd) and Albania (55th).
18
Using a different statistical technique, Kumbhakar (2010) provides a classification in
which Jamaica, China, Sri Lanka and Armenia appear among the top 10 countries,
ranked by efficiency in health. This cluster is also the one, between those identified by
our proxy for aggregate health, with the highest per capita GDP, with a cluster mean
of 8.62 (see the bottom of Table A6).
In the BFMMg , we identify three clusters with respect to GDP growth and four
with respect to life expectancy. For all the countries in the sample, we find that
aggregate health has positive impact on growth, with an elasticity of per capita GDP
growth rate on life expectancy equal to 3.413. Looking at the clusters’ composition,
some interesting analogies with the classification provided by BFMMY emerge. For
instance, the cluster K1 =3 (Argentina, Barbados, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Croatia,
Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Malaysia, Maldives, Malta, Mauritius, Panama, Romania
Serbia and Thailand) is the one in which the unobserved factors that affect the GDP
growth are the strongest (i.e., a03 =26.620) but also the one with the highest average per
capita GDP growth rate, 3.99% (see the last column in Table A8). A final point that is
worth mentioning is that in BFMMg , the unobserved factors that affect life expectancy
are particularly strong (a02 =19.585) in K2 =2 (Albania, Argentina, Armenia, Belize,
Bulgaria, China, Costa Rica, Croatia, Cyprus, El Salvador, Jamaica, Jordan, Malta,
Myanmar, Panama, Paraguay, Romania, Serbia, Sri Lanka, Tajikistan, Thailand),
which is also the cluster with the highest average life expectancy, 71.05 (see the bottom
of Table A8).
Finallly figures A2 and A3 show that the within groups residuals for the models
BFMMY and BFMMg are not informative anymore (compared to the OLS and GMM
results), meaning that the assumptions about their normality, orthogonality and homogeneity hold. Observations are not clusterized. This is confirmed by the Shapiro Wilk
and the Shapiro Francia tests, which reject the assumption of Gaussian residuals.12
12
We do not produce the residual plots for life expectancy in the two models, since the variable is needed
only for solving the endogeneity issue, thus reducing the bias in the estimation.
19
4
Discussion
The models presented in the previous section explain cross-country income and growth
differences with the cross-country differences in the capital output ratios and life expectancy, conditional on the estimated country-specific level of technology. We deal
with endogeneity using a two-step GMM model. To account for unobserved heterogeneity we run two BFMMs. Despite we do not formally test any causality, the augmented
Solow model can be used as a guidance to discuss our empirical results.
Our econometric analysis reveals that, for a large sample of low- and middle-income
economies, population’s health positively and significantly affects both the level and
the growth rate of per capita income. The positive impact on income level is consistent
with the augmented Solow model, in which the typical capital “dilution effect”, due
to the increase in population induced by a better aggregate health, is offset by the
increase in productivity arising from healthier workers. The size of the impact that
we document is quite large and is mainly due to the fact that we focus on a sample of
non-OECD/non-oil countries. Qualitatively, the result is in line with Bucci, Carbonari
and Trovato (2019), Bloom, Canning, and Sevilla (2004), Cervellati and Sunde (2011)
and Hansen and Lönstrup (2015) while it contrasts Acemoglu and Johnson (2007).
There are (at least) two possible, not mutually exclusive, explanations for the discrepancy between our and Acemoglu and Johnson’s results: the different period considered
and the econometric design employed in the two studies. Acemoglu and Johnson exploit the drop in mortality from specific infectious diseases, due to the international
epidemiological transition, as an instrument for the change in life expectancy. This
identification strategy makes use of the fact that the mortality rate from these diseases
was exogenous in 1940, because no treatment, medication, or vaccines were available
before that time. Starting from 1980, instead, all these diseases can be treated or
prevented in all countries, due to medical advances. After regressing per capita income growth on the increase in life expectancy between 1940 and 1980, Acemoglu
and Johnson report a positive but non-significant effect of increased life expectancy
on aggregate GDP and a positive and significant effect on population growth. The
overall impact on per capita GDP is found to be negative (which means that countries
20
that experienced larger exogenous health improvements saw lower gains in per capita
income). The authors ascribe their findings to the fact that increases in health result
mainly in large increases in population. In turn, the capital-dilution effect associated
to a faster population growth reduces income per capita at the steady state. Therefore, improved health finally lowers per capita income. Notably, the Acemoglu and
Johnson (2007)’s methodology has been questioned, as it regresses economic growth
against health improvements without including initial health in the model. As such,
the negative correlation between health improvements and economic growth shown in
their data may simply be the consequence of the fact that countries starting with better
health economically grow faster (while experiencing smaller improvements in health)
than those starting with lower initial health conditions (but experimenting larger health
enhancements during the transition).13 In our multivariate set-up, we tackle this issue
by using a one-period lag for life expectancy on the RHS of the equation (18).
The evidence of a positive effect of health on economic conditions for low- and
middle-income countries provides a rationale for international health aid. Especially
in low income countries, health aid is found to have a positive and significant effect on
health outcomes, i.e. an increase in life expectancy (Arndt et al., 2015) and a decrease
in infant mortality (Mishra and Newhouse, 2009). In particular, health aid is found
to be more effective at improving health outcomes for countries with higher domestic
health expenditure or a more efficient public sector (e.g. Gyimah-Brempong, 1992).14
13
To study this possibility, Aghion, Howitt and Murtin (2011) and Bloom, Canning, and Fink (2014)
include initial health in the Acemoglu and Johnson (2007)’s regressions and find that, indeed, the negative
causal effect vanishes. More specifically, Aghion, Howitt and Murtin (2011) combine the Mankiw et al.
(1992)’s approach (whereby output growth is correlated with the rate of improvement in human capital)
with the Nelson and Phelps (1966)’s approach (whereby a higher level of health should spur growth by
facilitating technological innovation), and look at the joint effect of health (level and accumulation) on
economic growth. After running cross-country growth regressions over the period 1960-2000, they show
that the level and the accumulation of health have significant positive effects on per capita income growth.
Moreover, they find a weaker relationship between health and growth over the contemporary period in OECD
countries. According to them, this result is explained by the fact that only gains in life expectancy below 40
years are significantly correlated with per capita income growth.
14
Chunling et al. (2010) warn that a potential substitution may occur between international health aid
21
Improving the effectiveness and/or increasing sic et simpliciter the public resources
allocated to health programs can increase life expectancy. From a theoretical standpoint, it is immediate to see that if the increase of this specific type of public expenditure occurs – keeping the size of public sector unchanged – the accumulation of physical
capital turns to be unaffected while possible gains for the accumulation of human capital, in the form of health, can emerge. Through this channel, therefore, such a public
policy can generate higher GDP and faster growth in low-income countries. Despite
the available evidence on this potentially virtuous link is mixed15 , when we include
public expenditure on health as an explicative variable on the RHS of equations (17)
and (19), we find that it positively affects both the level and the growth rate of GDP.
The elasticity of life expectancy with respect to such expenditure is 0.695 in BFMMY
and 0.733 in BFMMg .16
5
Concluding remarks
There are two alternative approaches to estimate the effect of health on economic
growth. The first is to calibrate the size of the effects of health at the aggregate level,
using estimates from microeconomic studies. The second is to estimate the aggregate
relationship directly, using macroeconomic data. We follow the second route. Building
on Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), we argue that international differences in income
and domestic expenditure on health. Studying a sample of developing countries they find that the presence
of programs aimed at providing Development Assistance for Health (DAH) to countries has a negative
effect on domestic government spending on health, while having a positive and significant effect on domestic
non-governmental health spending.
15
Studying a sample of Sub-Saharan African countries, Novignon et al. (2012) find that health expenditure
significantly improves life expectancy, and reduces death and infant mortality rates. Barenberg, Basu and
Soylu (2017) find similar results using Indian data in the periods 1983-1984 and 2011-2012. For a large
sample of developing countries, Baldacci et al. (2008) explore the channels through which social spending
can affect human capital and GDP growth. They find that health spending has a positive and significant
impact on human capital, and thus supports higher growth. Ssozi and Amlani (2015) find that, although
health expenditure in Sub-Saharan Africa has substantially increased since 2000, it has had a low impact on
both life expectancy and infant mortality.
16
For the sake of brevity we do not report these regressions, which, however, are available upon request.
22
per capita are best understood using an augmented Solow growth model in which
output is produced from physical capital, raw labor, human capital in the form of
education, and human capital in the form of health. The model predicts that the longrun level of per capita GDP and its growth rate (along the transition path) are both
positively affected by the level of aggregate health. We test these predictions by using
data from a sample of low- and middle-income countries, along the period 1995-2014.
As it is standard in this literature, life expectancy at birth has been used as a proxy for
population’s health. To take into account the unobserved heterogeneity, we estimate a
flexible Bivariate Finite Mixture Model, which incorporates the restrictions provided
by the augmented Solow model.
Our estimates document a sizable effect of health on living standards (per capita
GDP level) and economic development (per capita GDP growth rate). In the baseline
model (i.e. the BFMMy ), a one-year increase in life expectancy raises the long-run level
of per capita GDP by 5%. A reverse positive channel from GDP on life expectancy
is also confirmed. Our analysis also reveals the relevance of heterogeneity and the
clustering of countries according to outcomes (life expectancy and GDP level/growth)
clearly matters. Finally, despite we are not able to distinguish between the effects
of different types of health investments, our study provides an argument in favor of
an increase in the size of public national or international health plans, which may
improve aggregate welfare in low- and middle-income countries not only directly, by
producing better health conditions, but also indirectly, by positively affecting aggregate
productivity.
23
References
[1] Acemoglu, D. and S. Johnson (2007). Disease and development: The effect of life
expectancy on economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6). pp. 925-985.
[2] Adams, P., Hurd, M.D., McFadden, D.L., Merrill, A. and T. Ribeiro (2003).
Healthy, Wealthy, and Wise? Tests for Direct Causal Paths between Health and
Socioeconomic Status. Journal of Econometrics, 112(1). pp. 3-56.
[3] Aghion, P., Howitt, P. and F. Murtin (2011). The relationship between health and
growth: When Lucas meets Nelson-Phelps. Review of Economics and Institutions,
2(1). pp. 1-24.
[4] Aitkin, M. and R. Rocci (2002). A general maximum likelihood analysis of measurement error in generalized linear models. Statistics and Computing, 12(2). pp.
163-174.
[5] Alfò, M., Carbonari, L. and G. Trovato (2020). On the Effects of Taxation on
Growth: An Empirical Assessment. Ceis Research Paper, n. 480.
[6] Alfò, M., and G. Trovato (2004). Semiparametric mixture models for multivariate
count data, with application. Econometrics Journal, 7, pp. 1-29.
[7] Alfò, M., G. Trovato and R.J. Waldmann (2008). Testing for Country Heterogeneity
in Growth Models using a Finite Mixture Approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23, 487-514.
[8] Arndt, C., Jones, S., and F. Tarp (2015). Assessing Foreign Aid?s Long-Run Contribution to Growth and Development. World Development, 69(C), pp. 6-18
[9] Arnold, J., Bassanini, A. and S. Scarpetta (2011). Solow or Lucas? Testing speed of
convergence on a panel of OECD countries. Research in Economics 65, pp. 110-123.
[10] Ashraf, Q.H., Lester, A. and D.N. Weil (2009). When Does Improving Health
Raise GDP?. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Acemoglu, D., Rogoff, K. and
M. Woodford, Eds.). volume 23, pp. 157-204. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
[11] Baldacci, E., B. Clements, S. Gupta and Q. Cui (2008). Social spending, human
capital, and growth in developing countries World Development, 36 (8). pp. 1317134.
24
[12] Barenberg, A.J., D. Basu and C. Soylu (2017). The Effect of Public Health Expenditure on Infant Mortality: Evidence from a Panel of Indian States, 1983-1984
to 2011-2012. The Journal of Development Studies, 53(10). pp. 1765-1784.
[13] Barro, R.J. (2013). Health and Economic Growth. Annals of Economics and Finance, 14(2). pp. 305-342.
[14] Barro, RJ. and J-W. Lee (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the
world, 1950-2010, Journal of Development Economics, 104, pp. 184-198.
[15] Baum C.F., Lewbel A, Schaffer M.E., Talavera O., (2012). Instrumental variables estimation using heteroskedasticity-based instruments. http://repec.org/
usug2012/UK12_baum.pdf.
[16] Ben-Porath, Y. (1967). The production of human capital and the life cycle of
earnings. Journal of Political Economy, 75 (4). pp. 352-365.
[17] Blanchard, O.J. (1985). Debt, deficits and finite horizons. Journal of Political
Economy, 93 (2). pp. 223-247.
[18] Bleakley, H., and F. Lange (2009). Chronic disease burden and the interaction
of education, fertility, and growth. Review of Economics and Statistics, 9(1). pp.
52-65.
[19] Bloom, D.E. and D. Canning (2009). Population health and economic growth. In:
Spence, M. and M. Lewis (Eds.). Health and Growth, pp. 53-75. Washington, DC:
The World Bank.
[20] Bloom, D.E., Canning, D. and G. Fink (2014). Disease and development revisited.
Journal of Political Economy, 122(6). pp. 1355-1366.
[21] Bloom, D.E., Canning, D. and B. Graham (2003). Longevity and life-cycle savings.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(3). pp. 319-338.
[22] Bloom, D.E., Canning, D. and J. Sevilla (2003). The Demographic Dividend: A
New Perspective on the Economic Consequences of Population Change. Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, CA.
[23] Bloom, D.E., Canning, D. and J. Sevilla (2004). The effect of health on economic
growth: A production function approach. World Development, 32(1). pp. 1-13.
25
[24] Bloom, D.E. and G. Fink (2014). The economic case for devoting public resources
to health. In: Farrar, J., Hotez, P., Junghanss, T., Kang, G., Lalloo, D. and N.
White (Eds.). Manson’s Tropical Diseases, 23rd Edition, Philadelphia: Elsevier,
pp. 23-30.
[25] Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and O. Licandro (2002). Vintage human capital,
demographic trends, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 104(2).
pp. 340-375.
[26] Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and O. Licandro (2003). Early mortality declines
at the dawn of modern growth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(3). pp.
401-418.
[27] Bucci, A., L. Carbonari and G. Trovato (2019). Health and Income: Theory and
Evidence for OECD Countries. In: A. Bucci, K. Prettner and A. Prskawetz (Eds.),
The Role of Human Capital and Demographics on Economic Growth: Health, Education and Prosperity, Palgrave-MacMillan, 2019.
[28] Caner, M., (2010). Testing, Estimation in GMM and CUE with Nearly-Weak
Identification, Econometric Reviews, 29 (3): 330-363
[29] Cervellati, M. and U. Sunde (2005). Human capital, life expectancy, and the
process of development. American Economic Review, 95(5). pp. 1653-1672.
[30] Cervellati, M. and U. Sunde (2011). Life expectancy and economic growth: The
role of the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth, 16(2). pp. 99-133.
[31] Chakraborty, S. (2004). Endogenous Lifetime and Economic Growth. Journal of
Economic Theory, 116(1). pp. 119-137.
[32] Chunling L., M.T. Schneider, P. Gubbins, K. Leach-Kemon, D. Jamison, C.J.L.
Murray (2010). Public financing of health in developing countries: a cross-national
systematic analysis. The Lancet, 375(9723). pp. 1375-1387.
[33] Davidson, R. and J. McKinnon (1993). Estimation and Inference in Econometrics.
Oxford University Press.
[34] de la Croix, D. and O. Licandro (1999). Life expectancy and endogenous growth.
Economic Letters, 65(2). pp. 255-263.
26
[35] Dempster, A.P., N.M. Laird and D.B. Rubin, Maximum Likelihood from Incomplete Data via the EM Algorithm. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series
B (Methodological), Vol. 39, No. 1 (1977). pp. 1-38
[36] Fincher, C.L., Thornhill, R., Murray, D.R. and M. Schaller (2008). Pathogen
prevalence predicts human cross-cultural variability in individualism/collectivism.
Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 275(1640). pp. 1279-1285.
[37] Fraley, C., and A. E. Raftery (1998). How Many Clusters? Which Clustering
Method? Answers Via Model-Based Cluster Analysis. The Computer Journal, 41,
pp. 578-588.
[38] Griliches, Z. and J. A. Hausman (1986). Errors in variables in panel data. Journal
of Econometrics, 31, 93–118.
[39] Gyimah-Brempong, K. (1992). Do African Governments Favor Defense in Budgeting? Journal of Peace Research, 29(2). pp. 191-206.
[40] Hansen, C.W. and L. Lönstrup (2015). The rise in life expectancy and economic
growth in the 20th century. Economic Journal, 125(584). pp. 838-852.
[41] Howitt, P. (2005). Health, human capital, and economic growth: A Schumpeterian
perspective. In: López-i-Casasnovas, G., Rivera, B., and L. Currais (Eds.). Health
and Economic Growth: Findings and Policy Implications, pp. 19-40. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
[42] Hurd, M., McFadden, D. and L. Gan (1998). Subjective Survival Curves and LifeCycle Behavior. In: D. Wise (Ed.), Inquiries in the Economics of Aging. Chicago:
Chicago University Press.
[43] Jayachandran, S. and A. Lleras-Muney (2009). Life expectancy and human capital investments: Evidence from maternal mortality declines. Quarterly Journal
Economics, 124(1). pp. 349-397.
[44] Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Ryder H.E. and D.N. Weil (2000). Mortality decline, human capital investment, and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics,
62(1). pp. 1-23.
27
[45] Kleibergen, F.(2005). Testing parameters in GMM without assuming that they
are identified. Econometrica, 73, 1103.
[46] Kumbhakar, S.C (2010). Efficiency and productivity of world health systems:
where does your country stand. Applied Economics, 42 (2010). pp. 1641-1659.
[47] Lewbel, A. (1997). Constructing instruments for regressions with measurement
error when no additional data are available, with an application to patents and
R&D. Econometrica, 65, 1201-1213.
[48] Lewbel, A, (2012). Using Heteroscedasticity to Identify and Estimate Mismeasured
and Endogenous Regressor Models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,
30:1, 67-80. http://fmwww.bc.edu/EC-P/wp587.pdf.
[49] Lee, R. (2003). The Demographic Transition: Three Centuries of Fundamental
Change. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4). pp. 167-190.
[50] Lee, R., Mason, A. and T. Miller (2000). Life Cycle Saving and the Demographic
Transition: The Case of Taiwan. Population and Development Review, 26(0). Supplement, pp. 194-219.
[51] Linden, M., and D. Ray (2017). Aggregation bias-correcting approach to the
health-income relationship: Life expectancy and GDP per capita in 148 countries,
1970-2010. Economic Modelling, 61, pp. 126-136.
[52] Lindsay, B. (1983). The geometry of mixture likelihoods: a general theory. Annals
of Statistics, 11, pp. 86-94 .
[53] Lu, X., Y. Huang and Y. Zhu (2016). Finite mixture of nonlinear mixed-effects
joint models in the presence of missing and mismeasured covariate, with application
to AIDS studies. Journal of Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 93, pp. 119130.
[54] Madsen, J.B. (2016). Health, human capital formation and knowledge production:
Two centuries of international evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 20 (4). pp. 909953.
[55] Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. and D.N. Weil (1992). A Contribution to the Empirics
of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2). pp. 407-437.
28
[56] Mishra, P. and D. Newhouse (2009). Does health aid matter? Journal of Health
Economics, 28(4). pp. 855-872
[57] Nelson, R.R. and E.S. Phelps (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 56(0). pp. 69-75.
[58] Ng, S.K. and G.J. Mclachlan (2014). Mixture models for clustering multilevel
growth trajectories. Journal of Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 71, pp.
43-51.
[59] Novignon, J, S. Olakojo and J. Nonvignon (2012). The effects of public and private
healthcare expenditure on health status in sub-Saharan Africa: New evidence from
panel data analysis. Health Economics Review, 2 (22). pp. 1-8.
[60] Owen, A., J. Videras and L. Davis (2009). Do All Countries Follow the Same
Growth Process? Journal of Economics Growth, 14(4). pp. 265-286.
[61] Preston, S.H. (1975). The changing relation between mortality and level of economic development. Population Studies, 29(2). pp. 231-248.
[62] Pritchett, L. and L.H. Summers (1996). Wealthier is healthier. Journal of Human
Resources, 31 (4). pp. 841-868.
[63] Rabe-Hesketh, S., A. Skrondal, and A. Pickles (2004). Generalized multilevel
structural equation modeling. Psychometrika 69 (2), 167–190.
[64] Schaller, M. and D.R. Murray (2008). Pathogens, personality, and culture: disease prevalence predicts worldwide variability in sociosexuality, extraversion, and
openness to experience. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 95(1). pp.
212-221.
[65] Sharma
dynamic
R
(2018).
panel
data
Health
of
143
and
economic
years.
PLoS
growth:
ONE
Evidence
13(10):
from
e0204940.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0204940.
[66] Ssozi, J., and S. Amlani (2015). The Effectiveness of Health Expenditure on the
Proximate and Ultimate Goals of Healthcare in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 76, pp. 165-179.
29
[67] Solow, R.M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 70 (0). pp. 65-94.
[68] Soares, R.R. (2005). Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility
choice. American Economic Review, 95(3). pp. 580-601.
[69] Tamakoshi, T., and S. Hamori (2015). Health-care expenditure, GDP and share
of the elderly in Japan: a panel cointegration analysis. Applied Economics Letters,
22 (9). pp. 725-729.
[70] Tandon, E., Murray, C., Lauer, J. (200). Measuring Overall Health System Performance for 191 Countries. World Health Organization. GPE Discussion Paper,
No. 30, EIP/GPE/EQC.
[71] Yu, B., A.J. O’Malley and P. Ghosh (2014). Linear mixed models for multiple
outcomes using extended multivariate skew-t distributions. Stat Interface, 7 (1).
pp. 101-111.
[72] Weil, D.N. (2005). Economic Growth. Boston: Pearson.
[73] Weil, D.N. (2007). Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3). pp. 1265-1306.
[74] Weil, D.N. (2014). Health and economic growth. In: Aghion, P. and S.N. Durlauf
(Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 2B, Chap. 3, pp. 623-682. Amsterdam:
Elsevier-North Holland.
[75] Wooldridge, J.M. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data,
MIT Press Books, The MIT Press
[76] Zhang, J. and J. Zhang (2005). The effect of life expectancy on fertility, saving,
schooling and economic growth: Theory and evidence. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics, 107(1). pp. 45-66.
30
Appendix
A
EM algorithm
The parameter estimates are carried out through the EM (Expectation-Maximization)
algorithm (Dempster et al., 1977) based on the following complete-data log-likelihood:
ℓc (θ) =
K2
K1 X
n X
X
wk1 k2 {ln(pk1 k2 ) + ln(fik1 k2 )} ,
(20)
i=1 k1 =1 k2 =1
where wk1 k2 ia a dummy variable assuming value 1 if unit (country) i is in component
k1 and k2 at the same time, 0 otherwise, and
fik1 k2 ≡ fik1 fik2 =
T
Y
f (yit1 | uk1 , xit1 , zit1 )f (yit2 | uk2 , xit2 , zit2 )
t=1
In the E-step (Expectation step) we compute the posterior probabilities for each unit
i to belong jointly to the k1 -th and k2 -th components of the mixture, that is
ŵik1 k2 = P
pk1 k2 fik1 k2
k1 k2 pk1 k2 fik1 k2
with k1 = 1, . . . , K1 and k2 = 1, . . . , K2 . The marginal posterior probabilities can be
easily derived as
ŵik1 =
P
k2
ŵik1 k2
ŵik2 =
P
k1
ŵik1 k2 .
In the M-step (Maximization step), we maximize 20 with respect to model parameters,
exploiting its separability. A close-form solution is available for p̂k1 k2 , that is p̂k1 k2 =
Pn
−1
i=1 ŵk1 k2 n .
The maximization over the remaining parameters can be carried out using a stan-
dard maximization routine. Nevertheless, the algorithm may be trapped at a local
maximum and, consequently, may fail to reach a global maximum. A simple way to
overcome the issue is to run the EM algorithm from multiple random starting points
for a number of steps, then pick the one with the highest likelihood, and continue the
EM from the selected point until convergence. To determine the value of K1 and K2
we use the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC).17
17
The BIC is largely used in cluster analysis because it allows to compare models with different parametriza-
31
Table A4: Model choice based on the minimization of BIC
BFMMY
BFMMg
(K1 , K2 )
BIC
(K1 , K2 )
BIC
(2,2)
5046.226
(2,2)
18234.78
(2,3)
4906.209
(2,3)
18094.51
(2,4)
4865.328
(2,4)
18063.07
(2,5)
4894.884
(2,5)
18093.29
(3,2)
4074.441
(3,2)
18211.47
(3,3)
3925.361
(3,3)
18067.44
(3,4)
3892.534
(3,4)
18043.98
(3,5)
3933.105
(3,5)
18080.03
(4,2)
3477.886
(4,2)
18212.51
(4,3)
3345.62
(4,3)
18072.59
(4,4)
3314.203
(4,4)
18057.01
(4,5)
3349.274
(4,5)
18101.12
(5,2)
3349.274
(5,2)
18272.87
(5,3)
3158.749
(5,3)
18131.41
(5,4)
3133.159
(5,4)
18120.7
(5,5)
3176.276
(5,5)
18171.94
Note: 16 different models (Ki , Kj ) have been considered
with i = 1, . . . , 5 and j = 1, . . . , 5.
tion, different numbers of components, or both (see Fraley and Raftery, 1998).
32
Table A5: BFMMY : estimated clusters within the combinations of groups (Ki , Kj , i = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 and j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and
marginally (Ki , i = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 in the last column; Kj , j = 1, 2, 3, 4 in the last row)
K2 = 1
K2 = 2
K2 = 3
K2 = 4
China, El Salvador
Benin, Ghana
Sierra Leone, Zambia
Bangladesh, India
Tajikistan
K1 = 1
Kenya, Mauritania
Mongolia, Pakistan
Senegal, Zimbabwe
Bangladesh, Benin, China
El Salvador, Ghana, India
Kenya, Mauritania, Mongolia
Pakistan, Senegal, Sierra Leone
Tajikistan, Zambia, Zimbabwe
Belize, Jamaica
K1 = 2
Dominican Republic, Fiji
Belize, Botswana, Dominican Republic
Jordan ,Romania
Botswana
Namibia, Swaziland
Guatemala, Maldives
Fiji, Guatemala, Jamaica
Thailand
Nicaragua, Peru
Jordan, Maldives, Namibia
Tunisia, Ukraine
Nicaragua, Peru, Romania
Swaziland, Thailand, Tunisia
Ukraine
Argentina, Bulgaria
K1 = 3
South Africa
Barbados, Brazil
Argentina, Barbados, Brazil
Costa Rica, Costa
Latvia, Lithuania
Bulgaria, Costa Rica, Croatia
Cyprus, Malta
Malaysia, Mauritius
Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania
Panama, Serbia
Malaysia, Malta, Mauritius
33
Panama, Serbia, South Africa
Myanmar
K1 = 4
K1 = 5
Burkina Faso, Burundi
Malawi, Mali
Cambodia, Ethiopia
Niger
Nepal
Burkina Faso, Burundi
Cambodia, Ethiopia, Haiti
Haiti, Lesotho
Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar
Liberia, Madagascar
Malawi, Mali, Mozambique
Mozambique, Rwanda
Myanmar, Nepal, Niger
Togo
Rwanda, Togo, Uganda
Albania, Armenia
Honduras, Morocco
Albania, Armenia, Honduras
Paraguay, Sri Lanka
Philippines
Morocco, Paraguay, Philippines
Sri Lanka
Albania, Argentina
Benin, Botswana
Malawi, Mali
Bangladesh, Barbados
Armenia, Belize
Burkina Faso, Burundi
Namibia, Niger
Brazil, Dominican Republic
Bulgaria, China
Cambodia, Ethiopia
Sierra Leone
Fiji, Guatemala
Costa Rica, Croatia
Ghana, Haiti
South Africa
Honduras, India
Cyprus, El Salvador
Kenya, Lesotho
Swaziland, Zambia
Latvia, Lithuania
Jamaica, Jordan
Liberia, Madagascar
Malaysia, Maldives
Malta, Myanmar
Mauritania, Mozambique
Mauritius, Mongolia
Panama, Paraguay
Rwanda, Senegal
Morocco, Nepal
Romania, Serbia
Togo, Uganda
Nicaragua, Pakistan
Sri Lanka, Tajikistan
Zimbabwe
Peru, Philippines
Thailand
Tunisia, Ukraine
Table A6: BFMMY : income and health
GDP
K1 = 1
life exp
GDP
K1 = 2
life exp
GDP
K1 = 3
life exp
GDP
K1 = 4
life exp
GDP
K1 = 5
life exp
GDP
life exp
K2 = 1
K2 = 2
K2 = 3
K2 = 4
Mean
7.68
7.65
7.38
7.61
7.61
Median
7.60
7.62
7.24
7.52
7.58
St.Dev
0.71
0.27
0.39
0.51
0.46
Mean
65.80
54.38
44.57
59.20
56.24
Median
67.67
55.58
44.55
59.76
56.87
St.Dev.
6.52
6.02
6.51
6.36
8.80
Mean
8.60
8.31
8.65
8.52
8.55
Median
8.62
8.74
8.64
8.49
8.55
St.Dev.
0.49
1.06
0.29
0.44
0.51
Mean
69.43
57.04
55.36
64.78
64.62
Median
69.95
57.33
55.63
66.22
67.01
St.Dev.
3.90
4.57
4.31
7.16
7.44
Mean
9.24
-
9.10
9.22
9.22
Median
9.23
-
9.06
9.35
9.23
St.Dev.
0.58
-
0.15
0.57
0.55
Mean
73.65
-
57.59
69.21
70.61
Median
73.93
-
57.46
70.32
71.81
St.Dev.
3.75
-
2.90
4.31
5.90
Mean
7.02
6.88
6.84
6.95
6.89
Median
6.88
6.90
6.89
6.90
6.90
St.Dev.
0.67
0.40
0.30
0.33
0.40
Mean
58.50
50.21
45.19
53.94
50.01
Median
58.87
49.48
45.89
53.77
49.40
St.Dev.
4.99
7.15
7.20
10.27
7.88
Mean
8.30
-
-
8.12
8.21
Median
8.28
-
-
8.07
8.20
St.Dev.
0.43
-
-
0.32
0.39
Mean
70.32
-
-
63.97
67.25
Median
70.29
-
-
65.23
68.46
St.Dev.
3.39
-
-
6.53
6.05
Mean
8.57
7.21
7.69
8.38
Median
8.62
7.16
7.26
8.37
St.Dev
0.85
0.61
0.93
0.79
Mean
70.04
51.92
48.98
64.11
Median
71.05
52.24
49.49
65.46
St.Dev.
5.72
7.06
8.09
7.67
Note: means, medians and standard deviations of GDP and life expectancy within
the combinations of groups (Ki , Kj , i = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 and j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and marginally
(Ki , i = 1, 2, 3 in the last column; Kj , j = 1, 2, 3, 4 in the last row).
34
Table A7: BFMMg : estimated clusters within the combinations of groups (Ki , Kj , i = 1, 2, 3 and j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and
marginally (Ki , i = 1, 2, 3 in the last column; Kj , j = 1, 2, 3, 4 in the last row)
K1 = 1
K2 = 1
K2 = 2
K2 = 3
K2 = 4
Dominican Republic, Fiji
Albania, Armenia
Namibia, Sierra Leone
Albania, Armenia, Belize
Guatemala, Mongolia
Belize, China
South Africa, Swaziland
China, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic
Morocco, Pakistan
Costa Rica, El Salvador
Zambia
El Salvador, Fiji, Guatemala
Peru, Philippines
Jamaica, Jordan
Jamaica, Jordan, Mongolia
Tunisia, Ukraine
Myanmar, Paraguay
Morocco, Myanmar, Namibia
Sri Lanka
Pakistan, Paraguay, Peru
Philippines, Sierra Leone, South Africa
Sri Lanka, Swaziland, Tunisia
Ukraine, Zambia
Bangladesh, Honduras
Tajikistan
India, Nepal
Malawi, Mali
Benin, Burkina Faso
Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso
Niger
Burundi, Cambodia
Burundi, Cambodia, Ethiopia
Ethiopia, Ghana
Ghana, Haiti, Honduras
Nicaragua
K1 = 2
35
Barbados, Brazil
K1 = 3
Argentina, Bulgaria
Haiti, Kenya
India, Kenya, Lesotho
Lesotho, Liberia
Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi
Madagascar, Mauritania
Mali, Mauritania, Mozambique
Mozambique, Rwanda
Nepal, Nicaragua, Niger
Senegal, Togo
Rwanda, Senegal, Tajikistan
Uganda, Zimbabwe
Togo, Uganda, Zimbabwe
Botswana
Argentina, Barbados, Botswana
Latvia, Lithuania
Croatia,Cyprus
Brazil, Bulgaria, Croatia
Malaysia, Maldives
Malta, Panama
Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania
Mauritius
Romania, Serbia
Malaysia, Maldives, Malta
Thailand
Mauritius, Panama, Romania
Serbia, Thailand
Bangladesh, Barbados
Albania, Argentina
Malawi, Mali
Benin, Botswana
Brazil, Dominican Republic
Armenia, Belize
Namibia, Niger
Burkina Faso
Fiji, Guatemala
Bulgaria, China
Sierra Leone
Burundi, Cambodia
Honduras, India
Costa Rica, Croatia
South Africa
Ethiopia, Ghana
Latvia, Lithuania
Cyprus, El Salvador
Swaziland, Zambia
Malaysia, Maldives
Jamaica, Jordan
Lesotho, Liberia
Mauritius, Mongolia
Malta, Myanmar
Madagascar, Mauritania
Morocco, Nepal
Panama, Paraguay
Mozambique, Rwanda
Haiti, Kenya
Nicaragua, Pakistan
Romania, Serbia
Senegal, Togo
Peru, Philippines
Sri Lanka, Tajikistan
Uganda, Zimbabwe
Tunisia, Ukraine
Thailand
Table A8: BFMMg : GDP growth and health
GDP growth
K1 = 1
life exp.
GDP growth
K1 = 2
life exp.
GDP growth
K1 = 3
life exp.
GDP growth
life exp.
K2 = 1
K2 = 2
K2 = 3
K2 = 4
Mean
2.68
3.05
1.36
-
2.57
Median
2.58
2.79
1.79
-
2.49
St.Dev.
3.27
4.56
4.39
-
4.12
Mean
63.85
68.43
51.36
-
63.26
Median
64.48
69.66
52.88
-
65.24
St.Dev.
6.42
6.14
7.72
-
9.11
Mean
1.48
-1.98
0.36
0.76
0.81
Median
1.49
2.38
0.51
1.04
1.11
St.Dev.
3.33
9.75
3.28
4.83
4.56
Mean
59.57
67.38
45.19
51.63
52.65
Median
60.07
67.51
45.89
51.82
52.48
St.Dev.
8.99
2.46
7.20
7.06
8.65
Mean
3.32
4.12
-
6.79
3.99
Median
3.78
4.18
-
5.99
4.16
St.Dev.
3.95
3.50
-
4.22
3.83
Mean
68.58
72.34
-
57.04
69.76
Median
70.11
72.50
-
57.33
71.20
St.Dev.
5.49
4.29
-
4.57
6.23
Mean
2.56
3.38
0.98
1.08
Median
2.53
3.32
1.38
1.21
St.Dev.
3.55
4.44
4.02
4.99
Mean
64.11
70.04
48.98
51.92
Median
65.46
71.05
49.49
52.24
St.Dev
7.67
5.72
8.09
7.06
Note: means, medians and standard deviations of GDP growth rate and life expectancy within
the combinations of groups (Ki , Kj , i = 1, 2, 3 and j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and marginally (Ki , i = 1, 2, 3
in the last column; Kj , j = 1, 2, 3, 4 in the last row).
36
Observed log of per capita gdp
−2
−1
0
1
2
Observed log of per capita gdp
−2
−1
0
1
2
Figure A1: Residual plots for the models OLS and GMM.
−1
0
1
Residuals OLS FE
2
−2
−1
0
1
Residuals GMM CUE 2
2
−6
−4
−2
0
Residuals GMM CUE 1
2
−2
−1
0
1
Residuals GMM CUE 3
2
Observer log of per capita gdp
−2
−1
0
1
2
Observed log of per capita gdp
−2
−1
0
1
2
−2
37
Figure A2: Residual plots for the models BFMMY .
38
Figure A3: Residual plots for the models BFMMg .
39
Figure A4: GDP over time across countries. The color of the solid line (GDP) represents the belonging of the country to
K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green), K1 = 4 (blue) and K1 = 5 (light blue).
1990
2010
15
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
15
1970
−15 −5
gw
5
15
−15 −5
gw
5
15
gw
−15 −5
2010
2000
1970
1990
Burundi
Cambodia
China
2010
1990
2010
2000
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
1990
2000
1970
1990
year
Costa Rica
Croatia
Cyprus
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Ethiopia
Fiji
1995 2000 2005 2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2010
1970
1990
year
Ghana
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
India
Jamaica
Jordan
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2010
1970
1990
year
Kenya
Latvia
Lesotho
Liberia
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
year
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
year
5
gw
1970
1990
year
2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
2010
−15 −5
gw
year
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
Burkina Faso
15
Bulgaria
15
Brazil
15
Botswana
15
year
15
year
5
1970
1990
year
15
1970
1970
Benin
year
15
1970
5
15
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
Belize
year
−15 −5
gw
2010
Barbados
year
−15 −5
40
gw
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
15
1970
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
2000
Bangladesh
year
15
1980
gw
Armenia
15
Argentina
15
Albania
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A5: GDP over time across countries. The color of the solid line (GDP) represents the belonging of the country to
K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green), K1 = 4 (blue) and K1 = 5 (light blue).
2010
1990
2010
15
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
15
1970
−15 −5
gw
5
15
1990
−15 −5
gw
5
15
gw
−15 −5
1970
2010
1980
2000
Nepal
Nicaragua
Niger
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
1990
15
Namibia
15
Myanmar
15
Mozambique
15
Morocco
15
year
15
year
2010
1970
1990
year
Pakistan
Panama
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Romania
Rwanda
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Senegal
Serbia
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Tajikistan
2006
2010
2014
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
2002
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2000
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
Thailand
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Ukraine
Zambia
Zimbabwe
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
year
5
gw
1970
1990
year
2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
2010
−15 −5
gw
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
5
1970
2010
year
15
1970
1990
Mongolia
year
15
1970
5
15
5
1970
Mauritius
year
−15 −5
gw
2000
Mauritania
year
−15 −5
41
gw
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
2010
Malta
year
15
1970
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
1990
15
1970
gw
Mali
15
Maldives
15
Malaysia
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A6: life exp. over time across countries. The color of the dashed line (life exp.) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green) and K1 = 4 (blue).
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
2010
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
60
life
0 20
1990
1980
2000
1970
1990
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cambodia
China
1970
1990
1980
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2000
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
1980
2000
1970
1990
year
Costa Rica
Croatia
Cyprus
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Ethiopia
Fiji
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
1995 2000 2005 2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
Ghana
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
India
Jamaica
Jordan
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Kenya
Latvia
Lesotho
Liberia
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
year
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
Bulgaria
60
Brazil
60
Botswana
60
year
60
year
60
year
life
1970
1970
year
60
1970
60
1995 2000 2005 2010
Benin
year
0 20
42
1970
Belize
year
60
1970
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2000
Barbados
year
60
1980
Bangladesh
60
Armenia
60
Argentina
60
Albania
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A7: life exp. over time across countries. The color of the dashed line (life exp.) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green) and K1 = 4 (blue).
1980
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
2010
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
2010
1970
1990
2010
1980
2000
Myanmar
Namibia
Nepal
Nicaragua
Niger
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
60
Mozambique
60
Morocco
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Pakistan
Panama
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Romania
Rwanda
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
Senegal
Serbia
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Tajikistan
2002
2006
2010
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2014
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1980
2000
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
Thailand
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Ukraine
Zambia
Zimbabwe
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
life
1970
1990
year
60
1970
60
1970
Mongolia
year
0 20
43
1970
life
2000
Mauritius
year
60
1970
Mauritania
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
60
1970
Malta
60
Mali
60
Maldives
60
Malaysia
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A8: GDP growth over time across countries. The color of the solid line (GDP growth) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red) and K1 = 3 (green).
1990
2010
15
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
15
1970
−15 −5
gw
5
15
−15 −5
gw
5
15
gw
−15 −5
2010
2000
1970
1990
Burundi
Cambodia
China
2010
1990
2010
2000
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
1990
2000
1970
1990
year
Costa Rica
Croatia
Cyprus
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Ethiopia
Fiji
1995 2000 2005 2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2010
1970
1990
year
Ghana
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
India
Jamaica
Jordan
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2010
1970
1990
year
Kenya
Latvia
Lesotho
Liberia
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
year
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
year
5
gw
1970
1990
year
2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
2010
−15 −5
gw
year
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
Burkina Faso
15
Bulgaria
15
Brazil
15
Botswana
15
year
15
year
5
1970
1990
year
15
1970
1970
Benin
year
15
1970
5
15
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
Belize
year
−15 −5
gw
2010
Barbados
year
−15 −5
44
gw
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
15
1970
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
2000
Bangladesh
year
15
1980
gw
Armenia
15
Argentina
15
Albania
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A9: GDP growth over time across countries. The color of the solid line (GDP growth) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red) and K1 = 3 (green).
2010
1990
2010
15
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
15
1970
−15 −5
gw
5
15
1990
−15 −5
gw
5
15
gw
−15 −5
1970
2010
1980
2000
Nepal
Nicaragua
Niger
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
1990
15
Namibia
15
Myanmar
15
Mozambique
15
Morocco
15
year
15
year
2010
1970
1990
year
Pakistan
Panama
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Romania
Rwanda
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1970
1990
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Senegal
Serbia
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Tajikistan
2006
2010
2014
1990
2010
1990
2010
1990
2010
5
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
2002
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
5
−15 −5
2010
2000
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
Thailand
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Ukraine
Zambia
Zimbabwe
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
1990
year
2010
year
5
gw
1970
1990
year
2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1995 2000 2005 2010
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
gw
1970
−15 −5
5
2010
−15 −5
gw
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
1990
2010
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
15
year
5
1970
2010
year
15
1970
1990
Mongolia
year
15
1970
5
15
5
1970
Mauritius
year
−15 −5
gw
2000
Mauritania
year
−15 −5
45
gw
gw
1980
−15 −5
5
gw
2010
Malta
year
15
1970
gw
−15 −5
5
gw
−15 −5
1990
15
1970
gw
Mali
15
Maldives
15
Malaysia
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A10: life exp. over time across countries. The color of the dashed line (life exp.) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green) and K1 = 4 (blue).
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
2010
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
60
life
0 20
1990
1980
2000
1970
1990
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cambodia
China
1970
1990
1980
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2000
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
1980
2000
1970
1990
year
Costa Rica
Croatia
Cyprus
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Ethiopia
Fiji
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
1995 2000 2005 2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
Ghana
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
India
Jamaica
Jordan
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Kenya
Latvia
Lesotho
Liberia
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
year
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
Bulgaria
60
Brazil
60
Botswana
60
year
60
year
60
year
life
1970
1970
year
60
1970
60
1995 2000 2005 2010
Benin
year
0 20
46
1970
Belize
year
60
1970
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2000
Barbados
year
60
1980
Bangladesh
60
Armenia
60
Argentina
60
Albania
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
Figure A11: life exp. over time across countries. The color of the dashed line (life exp.) represents the belonging of
the country to K1 = 1 (black), K1 = 2 (red), K1 = 3 (green) and K1 = 4 (blue).
1980
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
2010
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
60
0 20
life
2010
1970
1990
2010
1980
2000
Myanmar
Namibia
Nepal
Nicaragua
Niger
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
60
Mozambique
60
Morocco
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
year
Pakistan
Panama
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Romania
Rwanda
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
1970
1990
2010
1970
1990
Senegal
Serbia
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Tajikistan
2002
2006
2010
1970
1990
1970
1990
1970
1990
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
2014
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
2010
1980
2000
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
Thailand
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Ukraine
Zambia
Zimbabwe
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010
1995 2000 2005 2010
year
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
1990
2010
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
60
year
life
1970
1990
year
60
1970
60
1970
Mongolia
year
0 20
47
1970
life
2000
Mauritius
year
60
1970
Mauritania
0 20
life
2010
0 20
life
0 20
life
0 20
1990
60
1970
Malta
60
Mali
60
Maldives
60
Malaysia
1970
1990
year
2010
1970
1990
year
2010