UC Berkeley
ACCESS Magazine
Title
ACCESS Magazine Spring 2010
Permalink
https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8d59n2g8
Journal
ACCESS Magazine, 1(36)
Authors
Ehrenfeucht, Renia
Chapple, Karen
Loukaitou-Sideris, Anastasia
et al.
Publication Date
2010-04-01
Copyright Information
This work is made available under the terms of a Creative Commons AttributionNonCommercial License, availalbe at https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/
Peer reviewed
eScholarship.org
Powered by the California Digital Library
University of California
ACCESS
S P R I N G
N
U
M
B
2 0 1 0
E
R
3
6
Tr a n s p o r t a t i o n R e s e a r c h a t t h e U n i v e r s i t y o f C a l i f o r n i a
C
O
N
T
E
N
T
A C C E S S
2
S
3 6
•
S P R I N G
2 0 1 0
Just Road Pricing
L I S A S C H W E I T Z E R A N D B R I A N D . TAY L O R
8
Public Parking Spaces for Shared Cars
ANDREA OSGOOD
14
Restricting Transportation Infrastructure:
Bad for Business in California?
KAREN CHAPPLE AND CARRIE MAKAREWICZ
22
Vibrant Sidewalks in the United States: Re-integrating
Walking and a Quintessential Social Realm
A N A S TA S I A L O U K A I T O U - S I D E R I S A N D R E N I A E H R E N F E U C H T
30
Fixing Broken Sidewalks
DONALD SHOUP
37 Papers in Print
39 Back Issues
41 Order Form
The University of California Transportation Center,
founded in 1988, facilitates research, education, and
public service for the entire UC system. Activities have
centered on the Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, Los Angeles,
Riverside, and Santa Barbara campuses.
Copyright © 2010 The Regents of the University of
California
University of California
Transportation Center
Phone: 310-825-5705
Fax: 310-206-5566
www.uctc.net
Authors of papers reporting on research here are
solely responsible for their content. Most of this
research was sponsored by the US Department of
Transportation and the California Department of
Transportation, neither of which is liable for its
content or use.
I N T R O D U C T I O N
What are the key policy issues? What are the take-aways from this
research? What can we do now and what more do we need to know?
F
2 0 Y E A R S , researchers at the University
ronmental policy, and today it is at the forefront of reducing
of California Transportation Center have asked hard
the transportation sector’s carbon footprint, having recently
OR OVER
questions and used the answers to help guide public
passed pioneering climate change legislation (AB 32 and SB
policy. From its beginning, UCTC’s core research theme has
375). California has been, and can continue to be, a beacon of
focused on tying together transportation systems analysis
enlightened transportation policy.
and policy. We do this by funding research, graduate and
One goal of UCTC is to give policymakers the informa-
undergraduate education, and special studies for federal,
tion they need to enact wise and innovative transportation
state and local governments. We also support events that
policies. Access magazine is an important way for us to
bring together professionals, researchers, and students to
disseminate that information. Several articles in this issue
confront key issues and identify emerging areas of interest.
focus on a complex subject that generates many questions—
Our activities are made possible through generous grants
transportation infrastructure and how we use it and pay for it.
from the US Department of Transportation and Caltrans.
Lisa Schweitzer and Brian Taylor address one of the toughest
One of the most prominent ways UCTC helps bridge
questions of all: who pays for transportation infrastructure,
research and practice is through its annual conference
and is the payment structure fair? Two other articles focus on
on transportation, land use and the environment held at
sidewalks, an oft-ignored part of transportation infrastruc-
UCLA’s Lake Arrowhead center. Now entering its 20th year,
ture. Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Renia Ehrenfeucht
this event brings together leading practitioners, researchers,
consider how walking has dwindled, which is ironic given
and elected officials to debate current policy issues. Last
that local regulations have tended to ban many sidewalk
October’s conference theme was “Economic Crisis as
uses in the name of making it easier for pedestrians to walk.
Opportunity for Reform.” The attendees generally agreed that
Donald Shoup suggests a creative way to finance sidewalks in
transportation policy needs a major overhaul. The challenge
these cash-strapped times.
presented by global warming suggests that at every level of
Andrea Osgood examines another undervalued part of
government, transportation policy needs to be better coordi-
our infrastructure—curb parking spaces owned by cities.
nated with land use, energy, and public health policy. Change
She argues that local governments can use this resource to
at this scale will require national leadership. Yet the federal
encourage carsharing by reserving some spaces and making
legislation that authorizes transportation funding recently
them free or discounted for shared cars. Finally, Karen
expired, and we appear to be in a cycle of continual short-term
Chapple and Carrie Makarewicz challenge the conventional
extensions simply to keep the system on autopilot.
wisdom that transportation infrastructure needs to be
There is room for optimism, however. Amid the gloom of
expanded in the name of economic development. California ’s
the economic crisis, it is easy to forget how much progress we
most thriving businesses, they find, are in central cities,
have made. In the years since the first Arrowhead conference,
where infrastructure already exists.
California has introduced two successful congestion pricing
We hope that this and future issues of Access will help
programs (on State Route 91 in Orange County and Interstate
UCTC-funded research inform and inspire policy and practice
15 in San Diego). The state has long been a leader in envi-
for years to come.
Robert Cervero
Karen Trapenberg Frick
Just Road Pricing
B Y L I S A S C H W E I T Z E R A N D B R I A N D . T AY L O R
E
CONOMISTS HAVE LONG ADVOCATED
road pricing as an
efficient way to reduce congestion and improve the environment. Many
critics, however, object to road pricing on the grounds that it unfairly
burdens low-income drivers. Implicit in these objections is the idea that existing
transportation finance methods burden the poor less, or at least spread the burden
more fairly. Most of the equity concerns about road pricing stem from the fact that
it is regressive; that is, poorer people spend a larger share of their incomes on tolls
than do wealthier people. But in the US, road systems are financed primarily
through fuel taxes, vehicle registration fees, property taxes, and, increasingly,
sales taxes—all of which are also regressive. Thus the relevant question is not
simply whether road pricing is regressive, or even if it will burden the poor.
The relevant question is whether road pricing will burden the poor more than
other ways of paying for roads.
Lisa Schweitzer is an associate professor in the School of Policy, Planning, and Development at the University of Southern California
and a fellow of the Brookings Institution. Brian D. Taylor, AICP is Professor and Chair of Urban Planning and Director of the
Institute of Transportation Studies in the UCLA School of Public A ffairs.
A
C
C
E
S
S
2
This question of road pricing’s fairness is particularly important now because traditional
sources of revenue for transportation infrastructure are drying up. Travel is increasing (as
are concerns about its social and environmental costs) but the buying power of fuel taxes has
been declining for decades. Governments have responded to these funding shortfalls in a
number of ways. Some have borrowed money to finance new roads, and some have started
tolling roads. Many, however, have turned to general taxes, especially sales taxes, which
have proven popular among voters and elected officials. Why are sales taxes, unlike other
taxes, so popular? Sales taxes are automatically collected a few cents at a time from all
consumers, and are hidden in a large number of transactions. So with sales taxes, unlike
property or income taxes, it is almost impossible for residents to see how much they pay over
the course of a year. The ease and relative opacity of the sales tax are keys to its ubiquity.
Sales taxes also make it easy for cities and counties to shift part of the tax burden onto
visitors who spend money in the taxing jurisdiction—the strategy cleverly described by the
Monty Python comedy troupe as “taxing foreigners living abroad.” But the fact that sales
taxes are popular doesn’t make them inherently fair or effective. ➢
3
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
F OR W HOM THE R OAD T OLLS
We should begin by defining some terms. Arguing that a policy proposal is “fair”
assumes that fairness has a set definition, which of course it does not. Fairness is often in
the eye of the beholder; what is consummately fair by one definition might be intolerably
unfair by another. One common way to measure the fairness of a tax is to ask if it is
progressive or regressive. We define a tax (or other charge) as progressive if its burden is
proportionally greater for those with higher incomes than for those with lower incomes. The
American income tax system, which imposes a higher tax rate on higher income people, is
progressive. Likewise, a tax is regressive if its burden falls proportionally more heavily on
those with lower-incomes than those with higher-incomes. A typical sales tax, where all
consumers pay the same rate (say, 10 percent of purchase price), is regressive, because the
tax burden for poor people will be larger as a share of overall income than it will be for rich
people. In absolute terms, of course, wealthier people pay more in sales taxes than poorer
people, because they spend more. But regressivity is a measure of proportional burden, and
sales taxes paid as a percentage of income tends to fall as incomes rise.
“Road pricing” is the practice of charging drivers in rough proportion to the costs
(congestion delay, damage to roadbeds, emission of pollutants, etc.) they impose on others.
Long the apple of economists’ eyes, road pricing can take many different forms. In the
US, High Occupancy/Toll, or HOT, lanes are the most common type of priced road. HOT
lanes impose congestion tolls on only part of a multilane road, giving drivers the option of
paying to drive in the uncongested toll lanes, or of driving for free in the unpriced-butcongested lanes. Many of these facilities also allow carpoolers to use the priced lane for free
or at a reduced rate. HOT lanes are a good illustration of how elusive the concept of
“fairness” can be. In one sense, HOT lanes are eminently fair, because no one is forced to
pay—drivers always have the option of remaining in the free, slow lane. In another sense,
however, HOT lanes are unfair, because they discriminate based on ability-to-pay. All drivers
pay the same toll, and the toll is a larger burden for those who have only a little money than
it is for those who have a lot. HOT lanes are therefore regressive. For this reason critics call
HOT lanes “Lexus Lanes,” and argue that they make it easy for the rich to buy their way out
of congestion, while leaving the poor stuck in traffic.
There is truth in both sides of the argument. Only users pay for HOT lanes, but poor
people certainly have a harder time paying, and are therefore less able to be users. On
average, wealthier drivers use paid lanes more than poor drivers do (just as they spend more
on gas, drive nicer cars, and drive more in general). But income is not the sole determinant
of people’s willingness to pay, and there will be instances where low-income drivers are in
enough of a hurry to pay their way into uncongested lanes. So while a low-income single
mother might not usually pay to bypass traffic, she will do so gladly when rushing to avoid
late pick-up fees at daycare. There is also some evidence that HOT lanes pull travelers
out of free lanes, and this can make even the free lanes move faster. But does this make the
HOT lane fair?
C OMPARING T OLLS AND S ALES TAXES
In the abstract, it might be difficult to determine if a HOT lane is fair. But the more
important question is whether tolls are fairer than a sales tax. For a given road, how much
would different households pay in congestion tolls compared with what they pay in sales
taxes? We attempted to answer this question by examining the 91 Express Lanes in
A
C
C
E
S
S
4
Southern California. The 91 Express Lanes are HOT lanes in the median of a 10-mile stretch
of a congested freeway that links job-rich Orange County with housing-rich San Bernardino
and Riverside Counties. The tolls in the Express Lanes serve two purposes: they regulate
demand to keep the lanes moving at free-flow speed, and they finance the lanes’ construction, operation, and maintenance. In our analysis, we compare the population who paid the
$34 million in tolls collected on the road in 2003 with the population who would have paid that
amount had it been collected through sales taxes in Orange County that same year.
To make this comparison, we used data from the 2002 Bureau of Labor Statistics’
Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES). We analyzed household consumer expenditures in
Orange County at various income levels and estimated the household sales tax burden
that would have accompanied those expenditures. To estimate 91 Express Lanes users’ toll
payments by household type, we extrapolated from a survey that examined both travelers
in the Express Lanes corridor and a comparison sample of people who traveled in the
parallel free lanes.
W INNERS AND L OSERS
In 2003 the 91 Express Lanes raised $34 million in tolls. All of this money was, naturally,
paid by users of the HOT lanes. Our question, again, was where the money would have come
from if the same funds had been raised through sales taxes. Specifically, we examined the
effects of such a change on three groups: the poor (people whose incomes are below
$25,000), the rich (people whose incomes are above $120,000 a year), and those who pay
county sales taxes but rarely or never use the toll lanes. (There is considerable overlap
The question
is not whether
road pricing
will burden
the poor, but
whether it will
burden the poor
more than other
ways of paying
or roads.
between the poor and the non-user group because the poor tend to be non-users).
We found that switching from tolls to sales taxes would shift the burden of paying for
the road from users to non-users, and away from middle-income people and onto both ➢
5
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
the rich and the poor. People in the poorest households in Orange County almost never use
the 91 Express Lanes. So while few of the poor enjoy the time savings of travel in the tolled
lanes, they also don’t pay for the road space that benefits others. But these same poor
households pay up to 4 percent of their income each year in sales taxes. Had the lanes been
financed by a sales tax, Orange County’s poorest households would have paid over
$3 million of the $34 million needed to fund the facility in 2003. The richest households,
for their part, would lose the most in absolute terms, because they buy lots of goods and
services subject to sales taxes.
With tolls, the burden of the Express Lanes falls on the relatively small group of
people who choose to pay, and who as a consequence enjoy the time savings the lanes
provide. With sales tax finance, virtually all users of the 91 Express Lanes would pay
considerably less than they do now, because so many nonusers would pay. In 2003, this
burden shift would have benefited frequent users of the 91 Express Lanes by around $700 a
year. The additional costs to each sales-tax-paying “loser,” by contrast, would be relatively
small, on the order of $5 to $80 per year, depending on the household type. But the relative
size of this burden transfer does not obviate the question of whether people who don’t use
the lane should subsidize people who do. If the answer is “yes,” the underlying logic implies
that any public expenditure, no matter how small its benefits, can be justified, so long as the
cost is spread over a large enough base of taxpayers. It also implies that those who drive least
should, with every purchase they make, help pay for roads for those who drive most.
A
C
C
E
S
S
6
One caveat: our analysis examined sales tax payments by Orange County residents.
FURTHER
READING
But not all sales taxes collected in Orange County are paid by residents, just as Orange
County residents pay some of their sales taxes outside of the county. And because Orange
County is home to Disneyland, two other major theme parks, beach resorts, and professional
sports teams, it “imports” sales tax paying residents from other counties. But the fact that
some of the sales tax burden is exported does not reduce the tax’s regressivity—it may,
in fact, worsen it if the visitors to the County are, on average, less affluent than Orange
County residents.
C ONCLUSIONS
Is road pricing regressive with respect to income? The short answer is yes. Whenever
Lisa Schweitzer. 2009. “An Overview of the
Empirical Research on Transportation
Finance,” Sponsored by the National
Academy of Sciences Transportation
Research Board as a resource paper for
Future Directions in Transportation Finance
Policy, Washington, DC, September 1, 2009.
Available from the author.
Lisa Schweitzer and Brian D. Taylor. 2008.
“Just Pricing: The Distributional Effects of
Congestion Pricing and Sales Taxes,”
Transportation, 35(6): 797–812.
members of lower income groups pay for services, they tend to pay a larger share of their
income than do the wealthy. But whether congestion tolls are regressive is an incomplete,
and probably misleading, way to understand the fairness of tolls. A regressive charge is
not automatically an unfair charge, and in public finance we frequently must decide between
regressive alternatives, not between a regressive and a progressive choice. Hence the
Brian D. Taylor and Rebecca Kalauskas.
Forthcoming. “Addressing Equity in Political
Debates over Road Pricing: Lessons from
Recent Projects,” Transportation Research
Record: The Journal of the Transportation
Research Board.
more relevant question is comparative: are congestion tolls fairer than other means of
transportation finance?
Our examination of the 91 Express Lanes in Orange County, California finds that
transportation sales taxes are doubly unfair. They disproportionately burden the poor and
those who drive little or not at all. We find that the heaviest users of the 91 Express Lanes—
and the largest beneficiaries of them—are primarily from middle- and upper-middle income
households both inside and outside of Orange County. From a regional planning perspective,
Brian D. Taylor and Alexandra T. Norton.
2009. “Paying for Transportation:
What’s a Fair Price?” Journal of Planning
Literature, 24(1): 22–36.
Matthew Barth and Kanok Boriboonsomsin.
2010. “Traffic Congestion and Greenhouse
Gases,” Access, 35(Fall): 2–9.
funding freeway capacity with sales taxes is a pro-auto/pro-driving policy that taxes all
residents, rich and poor alike, to provide benefits to a much smaller group of drivers and
their passengers.
This analysis has focused on one side of the ledger: the question of who pays. But
transportation systems have both costs and benefits. Indeed, the access benefits of travel
are transportation’s raison d’être. So while regressivity can be viewed as a cost of road
pricing (and of most other ways of paying for roads), pricing confers transportation benefits
that other transportation finance mechanisms do not. Tolls and taxes can both pay to build a
road. But congestion pricing can also reduce traffic delays, fuel consumption, and vehicle
emissions, often to a surprising degree. Sales tax finance for transportation, by comparison,
does none of these things.
It is widely understood in public finance that a transparent payment mechanism is a
good payment mechanism. Those who use scarce public resources—including space on the
roads—should pay for what they use, in proportion to what they use, and know that they are
paying. Knowing that resources have a cost is essential to using those resources judiciously,
and our road network will function better when drivers pay the costs of their travel. It is
entirely appropriate to worry about the burden tolls place on the poor, but the solution is not
to forgo tolls altogether. We should not subsidize all drivers (and charge all consumers) to
help the small number of poor travelers who use congested freeways in the peak hours and
peak directions. Rather we should help those who are less fortunate, and see to it that the
rest of us pay our own way on the roads. ◆
7
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
On-Street Parking
Spaces for
Shared Cars
BY ANDREA OSGOOD
A
C
C
E
S
S
8
I
N A D D I T I O N T O T H E I R M A N Y A D VA N T A G E S , cars also cause problems: traffic
congestion, air pollution, energy consumption, and even reduced mobility for
those who don’t own a car. Carsharing is a new form of vehicle ownership that can
help address these problems. Membership in a carsharing organization increases access
to cars but also encourages judicious use of them.
In essence, carsharing converts the high fixed costs of owning a car (purchase price,
insurance, taxes, and maintenance) into smaller units—the per-hour or per-mile price of
driving a car. By spreading the fixed costs of a car over many users, carsharing makes
automobile travel an option for those who cannot afford to buy their own vehicle. But
because users pay a high marginal cost for every hour or mile they drive, carsharing also
gives members a strong incentive to drive less. In this way, carsharing can both increase
mobility for people who might otherwise be carless and also reduce auto travel among
members who previously owned their own car. This reduction in auto travel carries a host
of benefits to society, from reducing local traffic congestion to slowing global climate
change.
W HERE W ILL THE S HARED C ARS PARK ?
The largest barrier to expanding carsharing is often finding and financing parking
spaces. An effective way for cities to encourage carsharing, therefore, is to offer carsharing firms free or discounted parking. Cities are in a unique position to offer these
much-needed parking spaces because they control a large and ubiquitous supply of curb
spaces that they can make available to carsharing organizations on favorable terms.
Free or discounted parking in any location, off-street or on-street, will help support
carsharing. On-street spaces, however, offer three special benefits for shared cars.
Visibility. Shared cars are not hidden away in off-street lots, but are placed on streets
where everyone can see them. This visibility increases the general awareness of carsharing, and may also remind car owners of the inconvenience and hassle of parking their
own car.
Convenience. Dedicated curb spaces are nearly as luxurious and worry-free as valet
parking or a private garage near one’s front door. When returning home, these dedicated
parking spaces allow members to simply pull up to the curb and leave the car. Drivers do
not have to worry about finding a space, or about being late because they have to cruise
around the block. Most shared cars are located in dense areas with scarce and expensive
parking, precisely the areas where residents who own cars but do not have off-street
parking spend quite a bit of time cruising the streets in search of a spot to park.
Availability. On-street spaces are often the main source of parking in some areas, and
car ownership is difficult in these areas as a result. These places are natural targets for
carsharing, but without city partnership, carsharing organizations would be unable to
expand in these places because they too would have no place to store their cars. ➢
Andrea Osgood received her MA in Urban Planning at UCLA, and currently works on transit- oriented development for Eden Housing. This article is drawn
from her MA research at UCLA, which won the Nevill A. Parker Award in 2007 from the Council of University Transportation Centers
(
[email protected]).
9
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
D ESIGNING AN O N -S TREET PARKING P OLICY FOR S HARED C ARS
A city that wants to support carsharing by reserving curb spaces for shared cars must
develop a policy to allocate the curb spaces. For example, how much, if anything, should
the city charge carsharing organizations for the dedicated spaces? Should the spaces be
auctioned? What is necessary to manage the dedicated spaces (procuring and installing
signage, striping the pavement, and keeping the spaces clean)? To answer these questions,
I conducted cases studies of cities that have adopted ordinances to allocate curb parking
spaces to shared cars.
When a city dedicates on-street parking for carsharing organizations, it also limits the
public’s access to the curb spaces. This loss of access, combined with the fact that local
jurisdictions would be allowing private companies to profit from a public resource, can
make the allocation of on-street spaces controversial. While there is ample precedent for
this kind of privatization—cities across the US regularly dedicate sections of streets for
taxi zones, hotel and restaurant valet areas, and commercial loading zones—concerns
over unfair allocation of public resources are legitimate, particularly if carsharing organizations are allowed to use street spaces at no cost.
In order to diffuse these concerns, any policy that allocates on-street parking spaces
to carsharing organizations should be crafted to ensure that the public realizes a return
that exceeds the value of these spaces. This return can be realized through direct payments to the municipality, or through other, non-monetary benefits such as reduced air
A
C
C
E
S
S
10
pollution or increased mobility options for low-income populations. Either way, this return
should be guaranteed in a privatization agreement that ensures the public gets the best
deal possible.
C A SE S TUDIES OF O N -S TREET PARKING P OLICY : K EY F INDINGS
Several North American cities are currently drafting, or have already implemented,
on-street parking policies for carsharing. These jurisdictions include Arlington County,
Virginia; San Diego, California; Seattle, Washington; Portland, Oregon; Vancouver, British
Columbia; and Washington, DC. In their approach to parking for carsharing, these cities
adopted a range of policy approaches. In what follows I summarize the key findings of my
case studies that examined these approaches.
• Legislative structure. Setting aside street space for a private organization
requires legislative action. In general, cities break the legislative mechanism
into two parts: (1) an ordinance or other official action by a governing body,
and (2) the administrative details. The first component sets out broad
parameters for the policy, including key political provisions, and then
delegates authority to another department to establish the administrative
details of the program, which can be updated and modified as necessary.
• Fees. Few cities initially charged carsharing organizations for on-street
spaces. As carsharing operators have become more established, however,
several cities—such as Vancouver, Portland, and Washington, DC—have
moved toward revenue-neutral fee structures; the city sets a fee for each
space to defray the public costs of their program and to recoup any lost meter
revenue.
• Signage and demarcation of spaces. Several cities use orange “Options Zone”
poles (first developed in Portland) to designate their on-street carsharing
spaces. These brightly colored poles include images meant to highlight
alternative transit options such as biking and walking. When combined with
brand-neutral marketing brochures and places to secure bikes, these poles
help the public to learn more about carsharing and facilitate the use of bikes
to get to and from shared cars. Tow-away signs and pavement markings
appear to be the most effective way to ensure that other drivers do not
mistakenly park in carsharing spaces.
• Results. Cities often provide multiple forms of support to carsharing
organizations, so isolating the effect of providing on-street parking spaces
can be difficult. However, evaluations have consistently shown that
carsharing membership increases as more vehicles are added, and that
members who previously owned one or more cars reduce their vehicle travel
and/or sell a car.
The growth in carsharing can greatly benefit even those who do not participate in it.
One study found that each shared vehicle removed 9 to 13 other vehicles from the road.
Fewer vehicles can lead to significant reductions in traffic congestion, air and water
pollution, and parking infrastructure. ➢
11
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
P L ANNING FOR S HARED C ARS
Cities can go beyond responding to carsharing companies’ requests for on-street
parking spaces and proactively plan the location of these spaces. Hoboken, NJ, has
established its citywide Corner Cars program that places shared cars in on-street spaces
at corners throughout the city so that 90 percent of the population lives within a
five-minute walk of at least one carsharing location.
Because each shared car in Hoboken has been estimated to replace 17 private vehicles, dedicating the corner spaces to shared cars can increase the availability of on-street
parking for everyone else. According to Hoboken’s Transportation and Parking Director
Ian Sacs, “Instead of taking on millions of dollars in taxpayer debt for structured parking,
residents who switch to carsharing will save thousands of dollars. It’s the 21st Century
solution to contemporary urban parking woes.”
Hoboken requires the fleet of shared cars to maintain an average of 35 miles per
gallon. If each shared car replaces several privately-owned cars that have lower fuel
efficiency, the on-street Corner Car program can significantly reduce the city’s carbon
footprint.
90% of Hoboken residents are within a
five minute walk of a Corner Car
Corner Car location
Five minute walk radius
A
C
C
E
S
S
12
R ECOMMENDATIONS
F U R T H E R
R E A D I N G
Any policy that dedicates on-street spaces for shared cars must have a mechanism
to verify and ensure the benefits of carsharing, particularly if local jurisdictions choose
not to charge a market-based fee for these spaces. A valid verification mechanism can
address concerns about privatization and also ensure that the public realizes a return on
its investment. The following provisions should be included in any agreement between
Arlington County Commuter Services. 2006.
Arlington Carshare Program. Department of
Environmental Services, Division of
Transportation Website
(http://www.commuterpage.com/pdfdocs/ArlCo_
CarshareReport_2006.pdf).
cities and carsharing organizations:
• Ensure that vehicles emit minimal pollutants. Require that all vehicles
parked in on-street spaces meet the EPA’s ultra-low-emissions-vehicle
standards, or vary the fees based on the emissions profile of each shared
car parked.
• Ensure increased mobility for low-income populations. Require a certain
number of vehicles in low-income neighborhoods.
• Verify benefits. Require that the carsharing organizations provide annual
travel behavior data on their members to the municipality.
• Ensure expansion—not just subsidization. The city’s investment should
help carsharing organizations expand, not simply reduce their current
operating costs. Many carsharing organizations have at least some
vehicles parked in off-street private locations, and a poorly-designed
agreement could allow the organizations to move these cars from
off-street spaces (paid) into the on-street ones (free). The organization
gains substantially when this happens, but the public doesn’t. To prevent
this sort of outcome, cities should mandate that any cars parked in
private off-street lots remain there for a period of time after the street
spaces are dedicated.
C ONCLUSIONS
On-street parking spaces for shared cars will encourage the growth of carsharing
Robert Cervero, Aaron Golub, and Brendan Nee.
2007. “San Francisco City CarShare: Longer-Term
Travel-Demand and Car Ownership Impacts,”
Transportation Research Record, Journal of the
Transportation Research Board, no. 1992: 70–80.
Clayton Lane. 2005. “PhillyCarShare: First-Year
Social and Mobility Impacts of Carsharing in
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania,” Transportation
Research Record, Journal of the Transportation
Research Board, no. 1927: 158–166.
Elliott Martin, Susan Shaheen, and Jeffrey
Lidicker. 2010. “Carsharing’s Impact on
Household Vehicle Holdings: Results from North
American Shared-Use Vehicle Survey,” presented
at the Transportation Research Board Annual
Meeting, Washington, DC, 2010
(http://pubsindex.trb.org/view.aspx?id=911080)
Adam Millard-Ball, Gail Murray, Jessica ter
Schure, Christine Fox, and Jon Burkhart. 2005.
“Car-Sharing: Where and How It Succeeds,”
TCRP Report 108 for the Transportation
Research Board.
Susan Shaheen, Adam Cohen, and Elliot Martin.
2010. “Carsharing and Parking Policy: A Review
of North American Practices and San Francisco
Bay Area Case Study,” Forthcoming in
Transportation Research Record.
because on-street spaces create extra value in two ways. First, the time savings and
convenience of on-street spaces can attract new members to carsharing organizations.
Second, the great visibility of shared vehicles prominently parked on the streets will serve
Ian Sacs, 2010. “Parking Garages Are So Last
Century,” Planetizen, June 17
(http://www.planetizen.com/node/44698).
as advertising that can show the benefits of membership.
Some drivers may oppose dedicating on-street parking spaces to shared cars because
it will reduce access for privately-owned cars. Nevertheless, carsharing’s benefits are
well established. If carsharing reduces vehicle travel, particularly at peak hours, it can
reduce traffic congestion, air pollution, and energy consumption. It can also increase
mobility for a city’s poorest residents. Reducing the on-street parking available to
privately owned cars might even encourage more people to become carsharing members,
creating a positive cycle that will further increase the benefits of carsharing. Each onstreet parking space dedicated to a shared car can benefit many people, including those
who do not carshare. ◆
13
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
R ESTRICTING N EW
I NFRA STRUCTURE :
Bad for Business in California?
BY KAREN CHAPPLE AND CARRIE MAKAREWICZ
P
LANNERS THROUGHOUT
C A L I F O R N I A are preparing to implement SB
375, a law that requires metropolitan planning organizations (MPOs) to consider
the impact of land use decisions on climate change, and requires that future planning decisions reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Among other provisions, the bill encourages municipalities and developers to concentrate infrastructure and development in urban areas or
close to public transit hubs in order to reduce vehicle use. The bill also includes a number of
provisions to better coordinate the provision of housing and transportation infrastructure.
SB 375 could have profound effects on California’s cities. If MPOs and local govern-
By encouraging
ments change their housing, transportation, and land use plans in response to the law, then
infrastructure funds, private investment, and housing will likely be steered into more
compact patterns, and development will occur primarily in places where it already exists.
infill development,
What will compact development patterns mean for business and job creation? Firms,
like households, have been decentralizing for decades, largely because of falling transporta-
SB 375 could very
tion and communication costs. As a result, the conventional wisdom is that the suburbs and
exurbs are “business friendly,” and that the ease of locating outside central cities has allowed
well help, not
businesses to expand more rapidly than they would have in the urban core.
If business growth depends on the ability of firms to move to outlying areas, then SB
375, in its effort to help the environment, might harm the economy. Infrastructure planning
hinder, California's
that encourages infill development, and that constrains public funding for new roads and
interchanges in outlying areas, could limit the growth of businesses in California. Indeed, the
economic growth.
idea that SB 375 might stifle economic growth seems to be the consensus among many of
the state’s major business players. The California Chamber of Commerce, the California
Manufacturers and Technology Association, the General Contractors of California, and the
California Retailers Association all opposed the bill. Lobbyists for these groups raised concerns that the bill would hinder investment in new infrastructure and leave projects that don’t
support infill vulnerable to lawsuits. Opponents also argued that SB 375 would increase the
cost of any development that significantly increases auto traffic. The developers of these
projects would need to pay for their own infrastructure. Developers faced with these new
infrastructure costs might pass them on to end users, thereby increasing the costs for their
tenants. Or they might scale back or forgo projects, which would limit location options for
businesses and drive up costs region-wide.
Are the opponents of SB 375 correct to be concerned? Does business growth in
California in fact depend on the ability of firms to relocate outward, particularly to places in
need of more transportation infrastructure? A look at California business growth patterns—
by studying more than three million records of business relocations, startups, and expansions over a fifteen-year period—suggests the reality is more complicated. First of all,
inhibiting business relocation is not a big concern, because most businesses never ➢
Karen Chapple is an Associate Professor of City & Regional Planning at the University of
California, Berkeley, specializing in regional economic development (
[email protected]).
Carrie Makarewicz is a PhD student in City and Regional Planning at the
University of California, Berkeley (
[email protected]).
15
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
relocate. Almost all employment growth occurs when new businesses are formed or when
firms expand where they are, not when an existing business moves somewhere else. And
while it is true that new businesses tend to start in places with plentiful infrastructure, it is
not clear that infrastructure is the decisive factor in the location decision. Location decisions
appear instead to be driven by concerns about the labor force (for some firms, the availability of a college-educated workforce, for others, the presence of low-wage labor) and
housing (often the concentration of newer, owner-occupied housing in the area). Further,
there is little evidence that new firms necessarily prefer the suburbs over central cities. If we
compare central cities and suburbs that have roughly the same level of infrastructure, three
times as many growing firms locate in the central cities as choose the suburbs.
None of this is to say that infrastructure isn’t important; firms overwhelmingly prefer
to be near highways and airports. But transportation infrastructure isn’t everything, and it
certainly isn’t the only thing. In the remainder of this article we first review what researchers
know about firm location, and then discuss our own research on business expansion in
California.
W HAT WE KNOW ABOUT LOC ATION , RELOC ATION , AND INFRA STRUCTURE
Planners, economists and regional scientists have amassed a large body of research on
the factors that influence business location and relocation decisions. A firm’s location
depends on the costs and benefits associated with a particular place. Transportation infrastructure is a benefit: it improves access to suppliers and customers, and to employees and
potential employees. But transportation infrastructure is just one consideration, and a lot of
research suggests that the presence of a good workforce is more important than the presence of a highway. Firms that require skilled labor tend to locate in places that have amenities skilled people find attractive: good schools, cultural and recreation opportunities,
high-quality housing, and transit. Businesses that rely on low-wage labor, by contrast, tend
to locate near large groups of immigrants and in places with plentiful rental housing. To the
extent they can, all businesses try to distance themselves from dis-amenities like congestion,
crime, pollution, and high local taxes.
Although policymakers sometimes worry that a poor “business climate” will drive business away, most evidence suggests this fear is overblown. Once firms establish in a specific
location, only a small percentage of them ever move, mainly because moving requires large
amounts of money, time, risk, and uncertainty. And when a firm does move, it may be a
mistake to assume that it does so out of dissatisfaction with its current location. Some
researchers suggest mergers, acquisitions, and takeovers are often as much the cause of a
move as is the local business or physical environment.
By themselves, then, limits on new suburban and exurban infrastructure should be
unlikely to harm California’s economic growth. If the law prevented new infrastructure in
places with large labor forces and plentiful housing (i.e., large population centers), that might
be different, but that is the opposite of the law’s intent.
T RACKING B USINESS G ROWTH IN C ALIFORNIA
Business growth can be measured in two ways: by counting firms, and by counting jobs.
The Dun and Bradstreet National Establishment Time Series (NETS) data for California
lets us do both. Dun & Bradstreet reports annually on almost all the registered firms in
California. We focused on firms with at least two employees, of which there were about
A
C
C
E
S
S
16
FIGURE 1
Major transportation infrastrucure in California
Major airports
Far North
Highways
Interstates
■
Jurisdictions
Sacramento
Area
Bay Area
San Joaquin
Valley
Sierras
Central
Coast
Inland Empire
South
Coast
0
0 51
0
30 4
s
0 20
Mile
80 MILES
San Diego
1.5 million active in California in 2005, and of which there were just over 3 million between
1990 and 2005. Of the firms active in 2005, a slight majority, 56 percent, were in the state’s
91 central cities, while 41 percent were in suburbs or other non-central-city parts of
metropolitan areas. Only two percent of the firms were not in an MSA and not in a central
city. The two largest regions, the nine-county Bay Area and three-county South Coast (Los
Angeles, Orange and Ventura counties), were home to almost two-thirds of the state’s firms.
Figure 1 displays the regions, jurisdictional boundaries, and major infrastructure we used
for our analysis.
From 1990 to 2005, the largest source of business growth (accounting for 60 percent of
new firms and 47 percent of new employees) was startups. The second largest contributor
to growth was expansions (29 percent of firms and 36 percent of employees). The relocation
of firms—either from within California or from other states—generates only a small share of
growth (about 11 percent of firms and 17 percent of employees). ➢
17
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO F IRMS THAT R ELOC ATE
When firms do relocate, they almost always move to the same type of place, i.e. from a
central city to a central city or from a suburb to a suburb, and many stay within the same city
or county (Figure 2). Only seven percent of relocating firms moved to a different region, and
only four percent left California altogether. So very few regions saw their economies suffer
because firms moved out, and still fewer saw their regional economies gain because firms
moved in. In most of California’s local jurisdictions, fewer than 5 percent of the existing
businesses are the result of relocations. Only in a small handful of jurisdictions, primarily in
the Imperial Valley and the state’s rural northeast, do relocations account for between 16 and
27 percent of the existing businesses. The firms that move into these places are disproportionately likely to be in the agricultural, construction, manufacturing, or public administration sectors. And the high share of relocations in these places is primarily an artifact of their
low initial number of firms, not because a large number of firms chose to move there.
The facts that firms rarely move, and that when they do they tend to stay near their
initial location, suggest that the presence or absence of infrastructure is probably not a
driving force in location decisions. Certainly infrastructure is important, but our analysis
suggests that relocating firms also search for a good pool of labor, and a housing stock
that suits the preferences of those potential employees. Hence firms that relocate to central
cities often do so because the cities are closer to more rental housing, which can support a
younger or lower-wage workforce. Firms moving to the suburbs, by contrast, will have
increased proximity to owner-occupied housing and lower residential densities, which may
help them meet their employees’ housing and lifestyle preferences.
FI G U RE 2
Where do firms go?
Leaving California 4%
Entering California 3%
Different region 7%
Same city
33%
Different county,
same region
10%
Same county,
different city
43%
A
C
C
E
S
S
18
FIGURE 3
Startups as a percent of total firms by jurisdiction
PERCENT OF TOTAL FIRMS
Far North
■
■
■
■
- 18
%
16%
16
–18%5%
11%
-1
11–15%
10 %
6%
-
6 –10%
5%
%0
0–5%
Sacramento
Area
Bay Area
San Joaquin
Valley
Sierras
Central
Coast
Inland Empire
South
Coast
0
80 MILES
San Diego
T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO S TARTUPS
In every sector except agriculture a newly-formed firm is more likely to locate where
there is at least one highway or interstate, as well as a major airport. Figure 3 shows that
startups are concentrated in California’s populous coastal regions, and in the central cities of
the Central Valley. And there is a correlation between infrastructure and employment. New
firms tend to be small; most have ten or fewer employees in their first year. Even so, in seven
of the ten major industries, firms that start up in central cities near highways and airports
employ more people than similar firms in jurisdictions that lack highways and airports.
As with relocations, however, housing and labor markets also contribute to a new firm’s
location decision. In particular, the presence of immigrants in central cities plays an important role for startups—much more so than it does for relocations. The urban concentrations
of immigrants in central cities might explain the disproportionate share of startups that begin
in central cities, rather than suburbs, since immigrants provide inexpensive labor for
business startups, often start small businesses themselves, and provide a large consumer
base for other startups. ➢
19
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO F IRM E XPANSION
Expanding firms are concentrated mostly just outside core urban areas, and like startups they are often within 10 miles of airports, highways and interstates. Some growing industry sectors—like manufacturing and wholesale firms, and Finance, Insurance and Real
Estate (FIRE) firms—are more likely than others to concentrate in jurisdictions crossed by
highways or within 10 miles of an airport. For example, almost two-thirds of expanding manufacturing and wholesale firms locate near transportation infrastructure, as do 59 percent of
FIRE firms. And the most rapidly growing firms tend to be in infrastructure-rich areas: for
instance, almost three-quarters of the new jobs that result from expansion in the manufacturing, wholesale, and FIRE sectors concentrate near highways and airports. The industry
sectors less likely to look for close proximity (less than 10 miles) to highways and airports
are agriculture, public administration, and construction, probably because of sensitivity to
land costs, as well as proximity to their residential base of customers.
A
C
C
E
S
S
20
Our analysis shows that expanding firms, like new firms and relocating firms, also base
their decisions on the type of housing available, and (like startups) many firm expansions
take place near large populations of immigrants.
In sum, there is no denying that firms locate near transportation infrastructure. In 2005,
nearly all firms (98 percent) were in cities crossed by highways or interstates, and within ten
miles of a major airport. The preference for infrastructure remains if we examine increases
in employment; 72 percent of all new jobs (and 61 percent of firms) develop in jurisdictions
with local and interstate highways and that are less than 10 miles from a major airport.
On the surface, the fact that most firms are close to transportation infrastructure could
lend credence to fears about SB 375. If businesses want to be close to transportation infra-
FURTHER
READING
structure, then restricting the expansion of that infrastructure could, logically, restrict the
expansion of businesses as well. But our analysis suggests this is not the case, for two reasons. First, the most dynamic firms are located in the most urban areas of each region. If we
compare central cities and suburbs that have the same level of highway and airport infrastructure, growing firms (whether expanding in place, starting up, or relocating) are three
times more likely to locate in central cities than suburbs—even though overall just 56 percent of firms are in central cities. This suggests that the type and level of infrastructure
needed to support fast business growth can be found in dense, already-built areas, not just
in outlying greenfields. Second, our research shows that proximity to a major airport is one
of the most important determinants of firm location. With or without SB 375, the state is
unlikely to construct more major airports in the near future, for a host of reasons. So most
business growth will probably take place near the 13 major airports we already have. And
even if California did build a new major airport, it seems unlikely that it would do so in an
undeveloped area. Airports are built where the demand for their services is highest, and
this tends to be in or near areas that are intensively-developed now (10 of the state’s 13 major
Aleid Brouwer, Ilaria Mariotti, and Jos N.
van Ommeren. 2004. “The Firm Relocation
Decision: An Empirical Investigation,” The
Annals of Regional Science, vol. 38, no. 2:
335–347.
Karen Chapple, Sara Hinkley, and Carrie
Makarewicz. 2008. “Business as Usual in
California’s Suburbs?: Exploring the
Dynamics of Firm Relocation, 1990–2005,”
presented at the joint Congress of the
Association of Collegiate Schools of
Planning (ACSP) and the Association of
European Schools of Planning, Chicago IL,
July 6–11.
Paul Gottlieb. 1995. “Residential
Amenities, Firm Locations, and Economic
Development,” Urban Studies, vol. 32,
no. 9: 1413–1436.
airports are along the heavily-populated coast).
C ONCLUSION
Fears that environmental legislation might impede economic growth are nothing new,
and should not be cavalierly dismissed. Increased environmental protection often involves
tradeoffs, and businesses do sometimes lose when the environment gains. In the case of SB
375’s infrastructure restrictions, however, concerns about a chilling effect on business
Genevieve Giuliano. 2004. “Land Use
Impacts of Transportation Investments:
Highway and Transit,” In The Geography of
Urban Transportation, Chapter 9.
Andrew Haughwout. 1999. “State
Infrastructure and the Geography of
Employment.” Growth and Change,
vol. 30, no. 4: 549–566.
appear to be unwarranted. There is little doubt that expanding firms prefer to be near transportation infrastructure, but the recent history of California shows that firms can expand and
stay close to infrastructure without leaving dense, already-populated areas. The businesses
that have contributed to the majority of growth within the last 15 years have not been expanding on the urban periphery in search of new, undeveloped sites with little infrastructure and
no highway. Rather they seek sites with existing major infrastructure that has been in place
long enough to attract other city amenities, an ample labor force, and appropriate housing
for their workers. In short, businesses can’t expand without access to infrastructure, but
businesses can get access to infrastructure without migrating to the periphery. Our analysis
Jed Kolko and David Neumark. 2007.
Business Location Decisions and
Employment Dynamics in California.
(Public Policy Institute of California).
Available from www.ppic.org.
Chad Shirley and Clifford Winston. 2004.
“Firm Inventory Behavior and the Returns
from Highway Infrastructure Investments,”
Journal of Urban Economics, vol. 55, no. 2:
398–415.
suggests that if anything, firms would like to see more (and more varied) housing options in
areas that are already-developed. If this is the case, then by encouraging infill development
SB 375 could very well help, not hinder, California’s economic growth. ◆
21
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
Vibrant Sidewalks in the
United States
Re-integrating Walking and a Quintessential Social Realm
B Y A N A S TA S I A L O U K A I T O U - S I D E R I S A N D R E N I A E H R E N F E U C H T
AS
A TRANSPOR TATION MODE,
walking is healthy for individuals and beneficial for
the environment. Fifteen years ago, the US Surgeon General highlighted the importance
of walking for exercise as a means of combating obesity, diabetes, and other diseases. Since then, a wealth
of studies published in public health and medical journals have extolled the virtues of walking. Moved by
concerns about climate change, energy, and congestion, transportation planners now view walking as an
inexpensive and enjoyable activity that could replace short auto trips, thus reducing congestion and fossil
fuel consumption. Yet despite the general consensus that walking brings many benefits, policymakers still
aren’t sure how to increase the amount of walking people actually do. One of the most obvious approaches
is to improve pedestrian infrastructure. Walking is harder in places without good sidewalks, and the
sidewalks in many cities are in terrible disrepair. Many other places have no sidewalks at all. But good
sidewalks, while important, will not by themselves lead to more walking. Changes in the built environment
are a necessary but not sufficient condition for a pedestrian-friendly city.
Urban areas where people enjoy walking have more than just a functional pedestrian infrastructure.
Sidewalks are not like major streets, many of which are designed solely to move cars. Sidewalk users are
more exposed to their environments than drivers, both because pedestrians are not encased in vehicles
and because they move through their environments more slowly than do people in cars. For this reason
sidewalk users also require more from their environments. A successful sidewalk is more than just a route
for getting from Point A to Point B; it is also a place to abide, to meet others, and to participate in neighborhood life. Urban sidewalks, as Jane Jacobs once argued, are a city’s “most vital organs,” where people
experience city life, enjoy neighborhood rhythms, and watch what goes on. Pedestrianism—moving on
foot, in a wheelchair, or with other mobility devices—is only one dimension of the sidewalk experience.
Sidewalks thrive as multi-use environments, not as pure pedestrian thoroughfares.
Many sidewalks in US cities lack the people and variety of activities that characterize
sidewalks in Europe, Asia, or Latin America, but this was not always the case. Nineteenth and early
twentieth century US sidewalks were vibrant spaces. As policy-makers began to perceive sidewalks
exclusively as transportation infrastructure, however, they used the goal of unrestricted movement as ➢
Anastasia L oukaitou-Sideris is Professor of Urban Planning at UCLA. Renia Ehrenfeucht is Assistant
Professor of Planning and Urban Studies at the University of New Orleans.
A
C
C
E
S
S
22
23
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
a justification to restrict other activities, including public speaking, vending, socializing
and loitering. Removing these activities sapped the sidewalk of life and vitality. The singular
view of streets and sidewalks as transportation routes, later combined with policies that overwhelmingly favored motorists over pedestrians, inadvertently made walking a less critical
dimension of urban living.
Planners who want to reinvigorate pedestrian spaces today face a difficult challenge.
Building infrastructure alone will not work, because people are more likely to walk in areas
that host a diversity of uses. Some uses, however, potentially conflict—a panhandler and
a shopper can occupy the same space, but the panhandler might make the shopper uncomfortable. Planners have tried to finesse this problem by encouraging certain kinds of uses, and by
encouraging pedestrianism only in certain places, creating upscale pedestrian hubs and leisure
destinations. These efforts at control often raise hard questions about democracy and legality,
and in any event are rarely effective ways to encourage more walking. We propose that more
people will walk or roll in wheelchairs when sidewalks are spaces that accommodate the full
range of activities that make cities interesting.
In the remainder of this article, we first discuss how a singular focus on sidewalks as
spaces of movement contributed to the decline of sidewalk life, and to walking as well. We then
examine ways that cities will perpetuate this problem if they continue responding to urban
complexity by providing spaces with narrow programs. Finally, we outline five purposes of
sidewalks—movement, encounter, confrontation, survival and beauty—and argue that, unlike
with automobiles, it is complexity, rather than uninterrupted movement that is central to
People are
more likely to
walk in areas
vibrant pedestrianism.
T HE R ISE OF THE S INGLE -P URPOSE S IDEWALK
In the 19th century, curbs and sidewalks became common along heavily traveled city
streets. These early sidewalks were often constructed by the abutting businesses and property
owners. By the century’s end, sidewalks had become important elements of the urban infrastructure, and thousands of miles of sidewalks had been paved in American cities. Because
sidewalks were often paved before the rest of the street, they were the easiest place to walk,
that host a
and the easiest place to carry out various economic and social activities. In commercial areas,
sidewalks extended the realm of adjacent shops; shopkeepers displayed their merchandise on
sidewalks and stored deliveries and overstock on them as well. Street peddlers made a living
diversity of
uses.
outdoors while street speakers and newsboys conveyed information to passersby. Sidewalks
were also a realm for social encounters where friends, acquaintances, and strangers mixed. The
sidewalks were thus both a route and a destination; a way to move through the city, but also a
place of commerce, social interaction, and civic engagement.
As sidewalks proliferated, municipalities began to standardize them. Cities specified sidewalk dimensions, construction standards, and materials to ensure consistency and durability.
At the same time, cities began to standardize streets and to require durable paving for the
roadbed and travel lanes. With this standardization, the nature of the urban sidewalk began to
change, and its range of uses began to contract. Municipal engineers began to focus narrowly
on efficient transportation and the importance of clean streets. Cities prohibited abutting
property owners from using the sidewalks as extensions of their businesses, and the courts—
when businesses challenged cities—upheld the cities’ authority to do so. In the process,
walking for transportation became sidewalks’ primary purpose and the pedestrian the primary
user. The pedestrian’s unobstructed mobility justified subsequent municipal restrictions on
A
C
C
E
S
S
24
other sidewalk activities. Consequently, the pedestrian became the sole “public” for whom
the sidewalks were provided.
Cities applied a similar logic to streets. The advent of local planning further changed the
street from a locally-oriented public space to a transportation corridor. Municipalities developed
public paving projects whose primary goal was traffic movement. In the late 19th century
pedestrians grumbled about the hindrances that blocked sidewalks; by the turn of the century
pedestrians found they had become the hindrance, regarded by local planners as “obstructions”
to the automobile. The sidewalk shifted from being the most convenient space for walking to
the only legitimate space for walking. As pedestrians became “encroachers” into the roadbed,
they were viewed as a source of accidents and congestion. City councils restricted pedestrian
crossings to intersections, required pedestrians to obey traffic signals and instituted fines for
jaywalking.
As automobiles proliferated in the early twentieth century, newspaper editorials blamed
pedestrians for accidents because they defied the rules of the road and walked into moving
vehicles. “The dumb pedestrian really is pretty dumb,” a columnist from Westways magazine
wrote in 1937. “As a pedestrian the average man is not very bright…. As an incorrigible
individualist, the pedestrian is intellectually inferior to the motorist in his traffic conduct.”
As early as 1912, urban infrastructure trade magazines such as American City advised widening
streets at the expense of sidewalks. Pedestrians were banned from streets to make room for
cars, and a myriad of activities were banned from sidewalks to make room for pedestrians.
But the sidewalks had never been about walking alone, and so in the process of creating an
efficient transportation system, public officials, municipal engineers and the courts also
enervated sidewalk life. ➢
25
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
T OO M UCH C ONTROL
When cities redefined sidewalks as transportation corridors, they also gave themselves
another reason to control sidewalk life. Anything that impeded pedestrian circulation could be
restricted or prohibited. Cities throughout the nation issued ordinances to regulate sidewalk
activities including loitering, panhandling, street vending, public speaking, and expressions of
political dissent.
By the middle of the 20th century, urban sidewalks were used for fewer activities, and more
people spent time in controlled environments like malls. And despite the recent popular and
scholarly attention to walking, in a 2003 survey of the ten largest California cities, we found that
public officials continued to deploy four strategies that devalued sidewalks as multi-use spaces.
First, they de-emphasized sidewalks by developing sunken and raised plazas and elevated walkways. Second, they gentrified select sidewalk segments to make them attractive destinations
with shopping, restaurants and bars while making few if any improvements to the remaining
sidewalk network. Third, they privatized particular sidewalks through the designation of
business improvement districts and by fencing and enclosing outdoor seating. And lastly,
A
C
C
E
S
S
26
cities sought to contain undesirable sidewalk activities they could not eliminate. We will discuss
each of these strategies in turn.
De-emphasis. In downtown and commercial areas, cities let (and sometimes encourage)
developers of privately provided plazas and open spaces to use enclosing walls, blank facades,
and entrances through parking structures, all of which separate their properties from public
sidewalks. Cities nationwide have built underground and overhead spaces—sunken plazas
and skywalks—to provide pedestrian circulation that avoids the street. In cities such as
Minneapolis-St. Paul, Detroit, Boston and Cincinnati, skywalks link high-rise towers to a
network of tunnels leading people from underground garages to office cubicles, allowing
workers and visitors to move through the downtown without setting foot on public sidewalks.
While initially meant to address harsh winters, skywalks also appear in cities with warm
climates such as Dallas, Los Angeles, Miami, San Francisco, and Santa Cruz.
Gentrification. In the last few decades, many municipalities have invested in historic
districts and main streets to draw middle class residents and shoppers back to the city. Their
efforts include upgrading the streetscape through a mix of public art, street furniture, and
decorative lighting, renovating buildings, and converting old warehouses into trendy shops and
restaurants. Cities have also enacted ordinances designating some “pedestrian-oriented”
districts, and encouraging specific retail uses (cafes, bakeries, restaurants, flower shops,
boutiques, bookstores, galleries, art shops) in these districts. Architectural and landscape
design guidelines promote specific themes to retain or enhance an area’s historic character. The
objective is to increase land value and overall economic viability. In the process, small, independent businesses such as nail salons, tattoo parlors and small food stores are often replaced
by chain stores and upscale retailers. The new consumer orientation reflected in the higher
prices and more upscale merchandise creates a subtle but effective screening mechanism and
makes the sidewalks comfortable for only higher income populations.
We must
re-imagine
sidewalks as
Privatization. Many states have enabled Business Improvement Districts (BIDs) in which
business owners tax themselves to augment public services or provide improvements for a
designated district. Services offered by BIDs typically include sidewalk beautification, cleaning
spaces that can
and maintenance, and private security officers. BID security officers ensure that sidewalk
activity is not disruptive to businesses. Some urban residents become nuisances if they do not
fit the BID’s desired image for the neighborhood.
Fencing a part of the sidewalk for outdoor seating is another form of privatization. Fences
are boundaries that separate the privatized realm from public space. This might be required by
accommodate
both enjoyable
ordinance, as is the case of California where state law stipulates that alcohol can be served only
in enclosed and demarcated areas. While cafes can blend seamlessly into the city sidewalks, as
they do in Paris, too often in the US hard boundaries privatize public space and thus preclude
and disruptive
different public uses.
Containment. Who has access to which sidewalks is controversial. To contain undesirable
uses, cities directly or indirectly sanction activities in one area to keep them out of another. Local
activities.
governments restrict prostitution to red light districts and homelessness to skid rows. Some
cities have extended this logic to street vending, allowing it in some areas while prohibiting it
in others. At times, cities have attempted to confine protest events and political speech to
officially-approved protest zones.
Some of the strategies above have helped empty public sidewalks of people and activities.
Others have encouraged the use of sidewalks, but only by a subset of the population, and in
doing so they make the sidewalk less public. ➢
27
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
W HAT D O W E WANT ? F IVE P URPOSES OF S IDEWALKS
Sidewalks will become more vibrant and desirable for walking if they can support five
purposes: movement, encounter, confrontation, survival and beauty. To do this, we must
re-imagine sidewalks as spaces that can accommodate both enjoyable and disruptive activities.
Movement. Sidewalks are spaces for travel, so they must be designed and maintained to
accommodate this activity well. Pedestrians need protection from the natural elements such as
rain and sun. Sidewalks must be accessible to all people. Comfortably moving on foot, in a
wheelchair, or with a cane or other walking device requires smooth pavement with adequate
width and curb cuts. Street furniture such as benches and lighting make sidewalks safer, easier
to navigate, and more comfortable for users who have different purposes and varying levels of
physical stamina.
Encounter. As spaces of encounter, sidewalks function best when a diverse range of people
use them. On sidewalks, people can greet acquaintances, observe neighbors they have never
met, and cross paths with strangers. Urban residents value some fleeting and public interactions, and urban encounters can make cities both intriguing and fun. Ordinary encounters
like stopping to chat rarely interrupt traffic flow. Some events, however, override the
functionality of streets and sidewalks by blocking traffic, and forcing people to stop, observe, or
participate. Processions to celebrate civic, national, religious or secular holidays (such as the
Cinco de Mayo, Chinese New Year, Fourth of July, Labor Day, Thanksgiving, Christmas, or
Carnival) temporarily redefine the purpose of streets and sidewalks. Spontaneous and planned
festivities break the rhythm of everyday life and give collective expression to people’s joy,
sorrow or aspirations. Parades and other large events disrupt traffic and can make sidewalks
impassable. Although they are not neutral events—they insert cultural practices, issues, and
interests into public consciousness—they are often accepted because they are temporary.
Confrontation. Some interactions and events are disruptive and intentionally confrontational. Nevertheless, we believe they should be accommodated on democratic sidewalks.
Sit-ins and micropolitical acts, such as when African-Americans historically refused to step aside
on the sidewalks, are important and protected forms of expression. But not all disruptions are
A
C
C
E
S
S
28
political. Talking loudly, gathering in groups, or even sitting on a stoop can violate local norms
FURTHER
READING
and, through repetition, change an area’s character.
Rallies and protests are political events that intentionally disrupt ordinary activities.
Although most agree in the abstract that people need access to public space for political speech
and events, the immediate effects of many political events irritate those whose trip or day
is interrupted. Because unimpeded transportation has been defined as sidewalks’ primary
purpose, cities have the authority to control the time, place and manner of such events to
reduce their disruption.
Survival. Some groups, such as the homeless, street vendors or youth lingering at
sidewalk corners, may not intend to be disruptive yet still cause other people discomfort. Most
activities that are associated with homelessness, for example, are common—sitting, talking,
asking questions and sleeping—but they are perceived differently when the people doing the
Nicholas Blomley. 2007. “Civil Rights
Meets Civil Engineering: Urban Public
Space and Traffic Logic,” Canadian
Journal of Law and Society. 22(2):55–72.
Nicholas Fyfe (Ed.). 1998. Images of the
Street: Planning, Identity, and Control in
Public Space. London: Routledge.
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Renia
Ehrenfeucht. 2009. Sidewalks: Conflict
and Negotiation over Public Space.
Cambridge, MA and London, England:
MIT Press.
sitting, talking and sleeping appear to be homeless. Recent conflicts around street vending and
day laboring sites have focused on immigrants, eliciting concern from long-term residents
about neighborhood change. Although few would argue that anyone should be absolutely
banned from sidewalks, many city councils have assumed that causing other people discomfort
is sufficient harm to prohibit ordinar y activities. For some, however, sleeping, sitting or
vending on sidewalks is a mechanism of daily or financial survival, and a rich mix of activities
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris, Evelyn
Blumenberg and Renia Ehrenfeucht.
2005. “Sidewalk Democracy:
Municipalities and the Regulation of
Public Space.” In Eran Ben-Joseph and
Terry Szwold, (Eds.), Regulating Place:
Standards and the Shaping of Urban
America. London: Routledge.
contributes to urban vitality.
Beauty. People like to be in beautiful spaces. Street trees are a way to beautify sidewalks
and make them comfortable for walking or waiting for the bus. Trees and other green spaces
also provide psychological benefits. In Chicago, residents in the Robert Taylor Homes publichousing development who lived in buildings surrounded by more trees and grass reported
fewer incidences of aggressive behavior than those in buildings surrounded by less vegetation.
Trees have additional benefits. Shade can decrease repaving costs (by reducing pavement
fatigue, cracking, rutting, and other distress) and reduce energy costs to residents (by cooling
houses and decreasing the need for air conditioning). Nonetheless, at times, street trees have
been banned from long stretches of the sidewalk so as to not hinder the motorists’ vision.
The urban forest is often a low priority for cities, and few funds are dedicated to maintaining
healthy trees along sidewalks.
R E - ENVISIONING S IDEWALKS
Counterintuitive though it may seem, if we wish to encourage walking for transportation,
we need to make sidewalks places for more than just movement. When sidewalks become both
spaces for travel and spaces for living, where people play, stop to talk, vend or buy, and communicate, they become more interesting places to walk. The sidewalks’ draw, danger, and
opportunity come from the same place: the people who make the public realm unpredictable,
interesting, and democratic.
In 1913, Charles Beard wrote that sidewalks “have been likened to the arteries through
which flows the life-blood of the city—trade and traffic.” But he also maintained that sidewalks
were more than that. “They are the meeting places of the people, the playgrounds of the
children, the allurement to recreation, and vice. Here persons of all ages and tastes go to meet
one another, to talk over the affairs of the day, to be entertained, to eat, to drink, to inspect shop
windows, to do marketing, to buy and sell merchandise, and to perform a thousand offices
which the exigencies of city life make profitable, healthful, or agreeable… The city sidewalks
connect every household.” This vision did not last, but we may yet be able to recreate it. ◆
29
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
Fixing Broken Sidewalks
BY DONALD SHOUP
Property has its duties as well as its rights.
—Thomas Drummond
P
ublic infrastructure often decays invisibly, and we are shocked when a bridge
gives way or a water main breaks. Sidewalks, however, decay right before our
eyes and under our feet. Perhaps because sidewalks fail gradually rather than collapse
spectacularly, many cities have neglected sidewalk
repairs and have let neighborhoods become less
walkable. In Los Angeles, for example, 4,600 of
the city’s 10,750 miles of sidewalks need some
degree of repair at an estimated cost of $1.2 billion.
Despite this backlog, the city fixed an average of
only 67 miles of sidewalks a year between 2000 and
2008. Even if sidewalks miraculously stopped
breaking, at that pace it would take 69 years to
repair all the existing damage.
Donald Shoup, FAICP, is Professor of Urban Planning at the University of California, L os Angeles (
[email protected]).
A
C
C
E
S
S
30
T HE A MERIC ANS WITH D IS ABILITIES A CT
Broken sidewalks make the city less accessible, especially for the blind and those who
use wheelchairs, canes, or walkers. Accessible sidewalks have emerged as an important
legal issue since the US Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals ruled in 2002 that the Americans with
Disabilities Act (ADA) applies to sidewalks. In 2003 the US Supreme Court declined to
overturn the Ninth Circuit ruling.
A class-action suit, Barden v. City of Sacramento, had alleged that Sacramento violated
the ADA by allowing its sidewalks to fall into disrepair. The court ruled that the ADA covers
“anything a public entity does” and any “normal function of a governmental entity.” To settle
the case, Sacramento agreed to dedicate 20 percent of its annual transportation budget for
up to 30 years to make public sidewalks accessible. Specifically, the settlement requires,
“Changes of level of greater than ½ inch, whether caused by tree roots or any other deterioration or displacement of the surface of the Pedestrian Right of Way, will be remedied by
providing a ramp with an appropriate slope or by creating a level path of travel.”
Similar ADA lawsuits have since been filed against other cities, including Los Angeles.
How will these cities find all the money needed to repair their sidewalks when they already
face fiscal hard times? Some cities have adopted a new strategy that doesn’t cost the city
anything: require owners to repair broken sidewalks before they sell their property. ➢
31
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
W HO S HOULD PAY TO R EPAIR S IDEWALKS ?
Requiring sidewalk repairs before sale will make the city more accessible, but critics
may object that cities are simply shifting the responsibility for repairs onto property owners.
In California, however, property owners are already responsible for sidewalks. California’s
Streets and Highways Code states, “The owners of lots or portions of lots fronting on any
portion of a public street shall maintain any sidewalk in such condition that the sidewalk will
not endanger persons or property and maintain it in a condition which will not interfere with
the public convenience.” Property owners also pay for sidewalk repairs in many other states.
A survey of 82 cities in 45 states found that 40 percent of the cities require property owners
to pay the full cost of repairing
sidewalks, 46 percent share the cost
with property owners, and only 13
percent pay the full cost of repairing
sidewalks.
Los Angeles followed the state
code until 1973, when federal funds
became available to repair sidewalks
at no cost to property owners.
Because of this federal funding, the
city assumed responsibility for most
sidewalk repairs. Three years later,
when the federal funds ran out, Los
Angeles was left with no sidewalk
repair program. Then, in 1978, California voters adopted Proposition 13,
which limited property tax rates, and
public funds became even scarcer.
By 1980, when the city attempted to
reinstate the previous policy of citing property owners for damaged sidewalks and requiring
them to pay for repairs, owners objected to the “new” mandate and the city halted citations.
Because the city was short of money, it began to make only temporary asphalt patches to
cracked sidewalks or—more often—did nothing at all. The resulting sidewalk decay led to
the current state of serious disrepair.
R EQUIRING S IDEWALK R EPAIRS AT THE P OINT OF S ALE
How does a point-of-sale strategy work? Before any sale, the city inspects the sidewalk
fronting the property. If the inspector finds that damage or displacement of the sidewalk
creates an unsafe condition, the owner must pay to fix it before completing the
sale. Piedmont, California, for example, requires, “New sidewalks and/or driveways must be
constructed if required by the superintendent of streets . . . in conjunction with the sale of
real property.” Piedmont’s ordinance mandates repairs if the vertical displacement of a break
is ¾ of an inch or less, and reconstruction if the vertical displacement exceeds ¾ of an inch.
Pasadena, California, has a similar at-sale sidewalk repair program.
A
C
C
E
S
S
32
Point-of-sale programs like those in Piedmont and Pasadena have several advantages
beyond complying with the ADA. First, the city does not require owners to pay or do
anything until they sell a property. The sale then provides the cash to pay for required
repairs. Sellers fix only the sidewalk fronting their own property, so they can see exactly
where their money is going.
Second, sidewalk repairs are gradual but
inevitable because about half of all properties are sold
at least once every decade. The property turnover rate
is similar throughout most cities, so the sidewalks are
repaired everywhere in a city at roughly the same rate.
Third, sidewalk repairs can increase a property’s
“curb appeal” and thus increase its market value. A
property’s value will increase not only because of its
own sidewalk repairs but also because of all other
nearby repairs. Everyone can benefit if property owners accept the obligation to repair their own sidewalks
before selling their property.
Fourth, the city does not have to raise taxes to pay
for sidewalk repairs. The city even saves money
because of fewer trip-and-fall lawsuits. Among claims
against the city for trip-and-fall incidents on Los Angeles sidewalks between 2001 and 2007, 36 percent of the
incidents occurred in front of properties that had been
sold within the previous five years. Los Angeles paid $1.4 million to settle the claims for these
incidents, which were preventable unless the sidewalks cracked in the five years between
the last property sale and the trip-and-fall incident.
Finally, sellers include absentee owners and residents who are leaving the city. Their
sidewalk repairs will leave the city in better shape for everyone who remains.
H OW D OES A P OINT- OF -S ALE P ROGRAM W ORK ?
To manage a point-of-sale program, a city can require that the escrow documents at sale
include a certificate of compliance with the sidewalk ordinance. The process starts when an
owner requests the city to inspect a sidewalk. If the sidewalk is in good repair, the inspector
issues a compliance certificate. If the sidewalk is damaged, however, the inspector estimates
what the city would charge to repair it. The owner has several options at that point.
First, the owner can pay the city to repair the sidewalk. The inspector then issues a
compliance certificate and the city makes the repairs. Second, the owner can accept a lien
on the property for the estimated cost of the repairs. The inspector then issues a
compliance certificate and the city makes the repairs; the city is repaid for the lien plus
accrued interest at sale. Finally, the owner can choose to have a private contractor perform
the work. In that case, the owner or contractor requests a permit and completes the
work; the city inspects the work, and if it is satisfactory the inspector issues a compliance
certificate. ➢
33
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
If the next owner intends to redevelop the property, repairing the sidewalk at sale
may be premature. In this case, the city can allow the seller to shift the responsibility for
repairs to the buyer. The city can inspect the property at the end of a specific time period
after the sale (such as one year), and cite the new owner if the required repairs have not
been completed.
Piedmont charges $30 for issuing a certificate of compliance, which is the city’s estimated cost of making the inspection. The inspectors can enter the records into a geographic
database that shows the condition of sidewalks throughout the city. The point-of-sale
program can be part of the city’s plan to make its public sidewalks accessible, and the
point-of-sale database will show the city’s progress toward meeting the plan’s goals.
Condominiums present a potential hitch in the process. Who would be liable for
sidewalk repairs when a unit is sold—the unit’s owner or the condominium association?
One solution is to exempt individual units but require condominium associations to repair
their sidewalks within a specified time after the ordinance is adopted, with periodic inspections to ensure continued compliance.
A
C
C
E
S
S
34
M ICRO -L OANS FOR P UBLIC I NVESTMENTS
Sidewalk repairs in Los Angeles typically cost between $1,000 and $1,500. If owners
pay the city before it makes the repairs, the city will have idle funds to invest between the
payments and the repairs. A city can also go beyond the basic point-of-sale plan by offering
to repair sidewalks before sale and receive payment at sale. The city will, in effect, lend owners the money to pay for sidewalk repairs for as long as they continue to own the property.
Owners can repay all or part of the debt before they sell the property, and any remaining debt
is due at sale. If owners pay a market interest rate on the debt, the government loses nothing by accelerating the repairs.
Some cities already allow property owners to defer paying special assessments, with
interest, until they sell their property. This option to pay at sale has several benefits. First,
Cash from the
sale gives
the program increases public investment without any public subsidy. The city runs little risk
of borrowers’ defaulting on the debt for sidewalk repairs because cash is available from
the sale of the property when the debt is due. A public lien is senior to any mortgage, so even
owners the
if property values decline and the owner has no equity, the city will be repaid in full. Where
land values are high, and sidewalk improvements increase them further, most owners will
have more than sufficient equity to repay the cost of repairs, plus accrued interest, at sale.
ability to pay.
Owners who wish to avoid the interest expense can always opt to repay the debt before sale.
Second, deferring payments until sale has a strong political advantage. Finding the cash
to repair the sidewalk before sale could be difficult for many owners, but allowing owners to
pay at sale will eliminate any cash-flow problem. Cash from the sale gives owners the ability
to pay. Elected officials can thus vote for a point-of-sale requirement with a clear conscience.
Third, the deferment option will allow the city to cite property owners whose severely
damaged sidewalks create an immediate danger to pedestrians. Requiring prompt repairs in
these cases will increase public safety, remove barriers to persons with disabilities, and
reduce claims from trip-and-fall lawsuits without creating a financial hardship for either
property owners or the city.
Fourth, the requirement to repair at sale, combined with the ability to delay payment
until sale, may spur some owners to make repairs as soon as a sidewalk breaks. They may
repair early because (a) they want the safe sidewalk they will eventually have to provide
anyway, (b) they expect repairs will be more expensive later, (c) they want to avoid trip-andfall injuries, and/or (d) they want to increase their property value.
T HE S PEED OF R EPAIRS
How fast will a point-of-sale program repair a city’s sidewalks? How long will it take, for
example, before half the broken sidewalks have been repaired? We can answer this question
by examining the history of property sales in a city. I used data from the Los Angeles County
Assessor to find the last sale date for every property in the City of Los Angeles. Half of the
768,922 properties in the city changed ownership at least once between January 1, 1995 and
December 31, 2006. If sidewalks fronting the sold properties are as likely to need repair
as sidewalks fronting all properties, a point-of-sale program adopted at the beginning of
1995 would have repaired half the city’s broken sidewalks in 12 years, much faster than the
current pace of repairs. ➢
35
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
P UT TING C ITIES B ACK ON T HEIR F EET
In 2002, the US Ninth Circuit Court ruled that the ADA applies to public sidewalks.
As a result, cities must develop transition plans to ensure that their sidewalks are accessible.
In this case, as in many others, what is good for people with disabilities—repairing broken
sidewalks—is also good for everyone else. The ADA will force cities to do what they should
be doing anyway: maintain their public infrastructure.
To ensure a steady flow of sidewalk improvements, cities can require property owners
to fix their sidewalks when they sell their property. Before any real estate is sold, the city will
inspect the sidewalk fronting the property. If the sidewalk is in good condition, the owner will
not be required to do anything. If the sidewalk is broken, the city will require the owner to
repair it before selling the property and the owner can put off paying for the repairs until sale.
Deferring the obligation to fix sidewalks until sale will help gain voters’ approval, and
enforcing the obligation at sale will help ensure owners’ compliance, both of which will
contribute to a successful program. Only property owners with broken sidewalks will pay
anything, they will pay only for the cost of repairing their own sidewalks, and they will not
have to pay until they sell their property. Because about half the city’s broken sidewalks will
be repaired each decade, all residents will be able to say, in the words of Danish urban
designer Jan Gehl, “How nice it is to wake up every morning and know that your city is a
little better than it was the day before.”
A better world often arrives in small steps, but we need reasons to take these steps. With
a point-of-sale program, all property owners will have to do their part, sooner or later.
Walkable cities need good sidewalks, and requiring sidewalk repairs at sale will help put
cities back on their feet. ◆
This article is abridged from a forthcoming publication in the Journal of Urban Planning and
Development, with permission from the American Society of Civil Engineers.
F U RTHER
READING
Class Action Settlement Agreement, Barden v. City of Sacramento. 2002.
(www.dralegal.org/downloads/cases/barden/settlement.pdf).
Donald Shoup. 1994. “Is Underinvestment in Public Infrastructure an Anomaly?” in Gareth Jones
and Peter Ward (eds.), Methodology for Land and Housing Market Analysis, London: UCL Press,
pp. 236–250. (www.sppsr.ucla.edu//dup/people/faculty/shoup/IsUnder-investment.pdf).
Donald Shoup. 1996. “Regulating Land Use at Sale,” Journal of the American Planning
Association, vol. 62, no. 3, Summer, pp. 354–372. (http://shoup.bol.ucla.edu/Regulation_at_Sale.pdf).
Donald Shoup. 2010. “Putting Cities Back on Their Feet,” Journal of Urban Planning and
Development. vol. 136, no. 3, September.
A
C
C
E
S
S
36
R E
C
E
N T
P A
P E
R S
I
N
P R I
N T
All papers are availa b le a t w w w. uc tc .net /r es e a r ch/f a c ult y p a p ers .s html .
Faculty research papers
2010
Sangkapichai Mana,
Jean-Daniel Saphores,
Oladele Ogunseitan,
Stephen Ritchie,
Soyoung (Iris) You,
and Gunwoo Lee
An Analysis of the Health
Impacts from PM and NOx
Emissions Resulting from Train
Operations in the Alameda
Corridor, CA.
March 2010
Roberto Ayala,
Soyoung (Iris) You,
Jean-Daniel Saphores,
Stephen Ritchie,
Gunwoo Lee, and
Mana Sangkapichai
A Preliminary Analysis of the
Environmental Impacts of the
Clean Truck Program in the
Alameda Corridor, CA.
March 2010
Gunwoo Lee,
Soyoung (Iris) You,
Mana Sangkapichai,
Stephen G. Ritchie,
Jean-Daniel Saphores,
Oladele Ogunseitan,
Roberto Ayala,
R. Jayakrishnan,
and Rodolfo Torres
Assessing the Environmental
and Health Impacts of PortRelated Freight Movement in a
Major Urban Transportation
Corridor.
March 2010
Soyoung (Iris) You,
Gunwoo Lee,
Stephen G. Ritchie,
Jean-Daniel Saphores,
Mana Sangkapichai,
and Roberto Ayala
Air Pollution Impacts of Shifting
San Pedro Bay Ports Freight
from Truck to Rail in Southern
California.
March 2010
Phillip Li
Estimation of Sample Selection
Models with Two Selection
Mechanisms.
March 2010
Jinwon Kim and
David Brownstone
The Impact of Residential
Density on Vehicle Usage
and Fuel Consumption.
March 2010
David Brownstone and
Hao (Audrey) Fang
A Vehicle Ownership and
Utilization Choice Model with
Endogenous Residential Density.
March 2010
Michael Manville and
Donald Shoup
Parking Requirements as
a Barrier to Housing
Development: Regulation and
Reform in Los Angeles.
March 2010
Tingting Cui, Yanfeng Ouyang,
and Zuo-Jun Max Shen
Reliable Facility Location Design
under the Risk of Disruptions.
February 2010
Shadi B. Anani and
Samer M. Madanat,
Estimation of Highway
Maintenance Marginal Cost
under Multiple Maintenance
Activities.
February 2010
Monica Altmaier,
Elisa Barbour,
Christian Eggleton,
Jeffier Gage, Jason Hayter,
and Ayrin Zahner
Make It Work: Implementing
SB 375.
Fall 2009
Nikolas Geroliminis and
Carlos F. Daganzo
Existence of Urban-Scale
Macroscopic Fundamental
Diagrams: Some Experimental
Findings.
Fall 2009
Dev E. Millstein and
Robert A. Harley
Effects of an Accelerated
Diesel Engine
Replacement/Retrofit Program.
Fall 2009
Jacqueline Leavitt and
Gar y Blasi
The Los Angeles Taxi
Workers Alliance.
Fall 2009
Evelyn Blumenberg and
Michael Smart
Travel In the ’Hood: Ethnic
Neighborhoods and Mode
Choice. Fall 2009
Paul M. Ong
Measuring Travel Behavior of
Low-Income Households Using
GPS-Enabled Cell Phones;
Multimodal Monitoring with
Integrated GPS, Diary and
Prompted Recall Methods.
Fall 2009
Seo Young Yoon and
Konstadinos Goulias
Constraint-based Assessment of
Intra-Household Bargaining on
Time Allocation to Activities and
Travel Using Individual
Accessibility Measures.
Fall 2009
Kate Deutsch and
Konstadinos Goulias
Exploring Sense of Place
Attitudes as Indicators of Travel
Behavior.
Fall 2009
Evelyn Blumenberg
Moving In and Moving Around:
Immigrants, Travel Behavior,
and Implications for Transport
Policy.
Fall 2009
2009
Ricard Gil and Justin Marion
The Role of Repeated
Interactions, Self-Enforcing
Agreements and Relational
[Sub]Contracting: Evidence
from California Highway
Procurement Auctions.
Fall 2009
37
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
R E
C
E
N T
P A
P E
Kate Deutsch and
Konstadinos Goulias
Investigating the Impact of
Sense of Place on Travel
Behavior Using an Intercept
Survey Methodology.
Fall 2009
Megan Smirti and
Mark Hansen
Capturing the Impact of Fuel
Price on Jet Aircraft Operating
Costs with Engineering and
Econometric Models (revised).
Summer 2009
Marlon G. Boarnet,
Rufus Edwards,
Marko Princevac,
Jun Wu, Hansheng Pan,
Christian Bartolome,
Gavin Ferguson,
Anahita Fazl, and
Raul Lejano
Near-Source Modeling of
Transportation Emissions in
Built Environments Surrounding
Major Arterials.
Summer 2009
Megan Smirti and
Mark Hansen
The Potential of Turboprops
to Reduce Aviation Fuel
Consumption.
Summer 2009
Robert Cer vero, Arlie Adkins,
and Cathleen Sullivan
Are TODs Over-Parked?
Summer 2009
Megan Smirti and
Mark Hansen
Assessing the Role of Operating,
Passenger, and Infrastructure
Costs in Fleet Planning under
Fuel Price Uncertainty.
Summer 2009
Erin Machell, Troy Reinhalter,
and Karen Chapple
Building Support for TransitOriented Development: Do
Community-Engagement
Toolkits Work?
Summer 2009
B
R S
I
N
P R I
N T
Greg Marsden,
Karen T. Frick,
Anthony D. May and
Elizabeth Deakin
Good Practice in the Exploitation
of Innovative Strategies in
Sustainable Urban Transport:
City Interview Synthesis.
Summer 2009
Chris Ganson
The Transportation Greenhouse
Gas Inventory: A First Step
toward City-Driven Emissions
Rationalization.
Spring 2009
Joshua Michael Pilachowski
An Approach to Reducing
Bus Bunching.
UC Berkeley, 2009
Elliot William Martin,
New Vehicle Choice, Fuel
Economy and Vehicle
Incentives: An Analysis of
Hybrid Tax Credits and the
Gasoline Tax.
UC Berkeley, 2009
Dissertations
David Andrew King
Exploring the Localization
of Transportation Planning:
Essays on Research and Policy
Implications from Shifting Goals
in Transportation Planning.
UC Los Angeles, 2009
Stella Kin-Mang So
Managing City Evacuations.
UC Berkeley, 2010
Policy Briefs
Gian-Claudia Sciara
Planners and the Pork Barrel:
Metropolitan Engagement in and
Resistance to Congressional
Transportation Earmarking.
UC Berkeley, 2009
The Price of Unwanted Parking.
Re-pricing Highway Pavement
Deterioration.
Are TOD’s Over-Parked?
O O K S
Please contact the publishe r s f o r i nf o rma t io n a b o ut the b oo ks li s t ed he re .
Boarnet, Marlon and
Randall Crane
Travel by Design: The Influence
of Urban Form on Travel
(Oxford University Press, 2001)
Garrison, William L.,
and David Levinson
The Transportation Experience:
Policy, Planning, and Deployment
(Oxford University Press, 2005)
Hall, Peter Geoffrey
Cities of Tomorrow: An
Intellectual History of
Urban Planning and Design
in the Twentieth Century
(Blackwell Publishers, 2002)
A
C
C
E
S
S
38
Jacobs, Allan B.,
Elizabeth S. Macdonald,
and Yodan Y. Rofé
The Boulevard Book: History,
Evolution, Design of Multi-Way
Boulevards (MIT Press, 2002)
Shoup, Donald C.
The High Cost of Free Parking
(Planner’s Press, 2005)
Loukaitou-Sideris, Anastasia
and Renia Ehrenfeucht
Sidewalks: Conflict and
Negotiation over Public Space.
(MIT Press, 2009)
Sperling, Daniel and
James Cannon, eds.
Driving Climate Change: Cutting
Carbon from Transportation
(Elsevier Academic Press, 2006)
Shoup, Donald C.
Parking Cash Out (Planning
Advisory Service, 2005)
Sperling, Daniel and
James Cannon, eds.
The Hydrogen Energy Transition:
Moving Toward the Post
Petroleum Age in Transportation
(Elsevier Academic Press, 2004)
Sperling, Daniel and
Deborah Gordon
Two Billion Cars: Driving
Toward Sustainability (Oxford
University Press, 2009)
A
C
C
E
S S
B
A
C
K
I
S S U E
S
ACCES S 1, FALL 1992
ACCESS 4, SPRING 1994
ACCESS 7, FAL L 1 99 5
ACCES S 1 0 , S PRI NG 1 99 7
ACCES S 1 3 , FAL L 19 9 8
ACCES S 1 7 , FAL L 2 0 0 0
Introduction
Melvin M. Webber
Introduction
Melvin M. Webber
Introduction
Luci Yamamoto
Director’s Comment
Martin Wachs
Nonconventional Research
Melvin M. Webber
Autonomous Decongestants
Melvin M. Webber
Cars and Demographics
Charles Lave
Time Again for Rail?
Peter Hall
The High Cost of Free Parking
Donald C. Shoup
Congress Okays Cash Out
Donald C. Shoup
Brooklyn’s Boulevards
Elizabeth Macdonald
Compulsory Ridesharing
in Los Angeles
Martin Wachs and
Genevieve Giuliano
No Rush to Catch the Train
Adib Kanafani
The TransportationLand Use Connection
Still Matters
Robert Cervero and John D. Landis
Dividing the Federal Pie
Lewison Lee Lem
Global Transportation
Wilfred Owen
A Question of Timing
Rosella Picado
New Highways and Economic
Growth: Rethinking the Link
Marlon G. Boarnet
Can Welfare Recipients Afford
to Work Far From Home?
Evelyn Blumenberg
Taxing Foreigners Living Abroad
David Levinson
Redundancy: The Lesson from
the Loma Prieta Earthquake
Melvin M. Webber
Will Congestion Pricing
Ever Be Adopted?
Martin Wachs
Taking Turns: Rx for
Congestion
Carlos Daganzo
Cashing in on Curb Parking
Donald C. Shoup
Environmentally Benign
Automobiles
Daniel Sperling, et al.
Reviving Transit Corridors
and Transit Riding
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris
Do New Highways Generate
Traffic?
Mark Hansen
Telecommunication vs.
Transportation
Pnina Ohanna Plaut
Pavement Friendly
Buses and Trucks
J. Karl Hedrick, et al.
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Love, Lies, and Transportation
in LA
Charles Lave
Higher Speed Limits
May Save Lives
Charles Lave
Why Don’t You Telecommute?
Ilan Salomon and Patricia L.
Mokhtarian
Is Oxygen Enough?
Robert Harley
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Speed Limits Raised,
Fatalities Fall
Charles Lave
Commuter Stress
Raymond W. Novaco
ACCESS 8, SPRI NG 19 9 6
ACCESS 5, FALL 199 4
ACCES S 2, SPRING 1993*
Preface
Melvin M. Webber
Introduction
Lydia Chen
Cashing Out Employer-Paid
Parking
Donald C. Shoup
Highway Blues: Nothing
a Little Accessibility
Can’t Cure
Susan Handy
Congestion Pricing: New Life
for an Old Idea?
Kenneth A. Small
Transit Villages: From Idea
to Implementation
Robert Cervero
Private Toll Roads in
America—The First
Time Around
Daniel B. Klein
A New Tool for Land Use and
Transportation Planning
John D. Landis
Investigating Toll Roads
in California
Gordon J. Fielding
Telecommuting: What’s
the Payoff?
Patricia L. Mokhtarian
Surviving in the Suburbs:
Transit’s Untapped Frontier
Robert Cervero
ACCES S 3, FALL 1993
Introduction
Melvin M. Webber
Clean for a Day: California
Versus the EPA’s Smog
Check Mandate
Charles Lave
Southern California:
The Detroit of Electric Cars?
Allen J. Scott
The Promise of Fuel-Cell
Vehicles
Mark Delucchi and David Swan
Great Streets: Monument
Avenue, Richmond, Virginia
Allan B. Jacobs
Why California Stopped
Building Freeways
Brian D. Taylor
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Trends in Our Times
Charles Lave
*Out of print; photocopies available.
It Wasn’t Supposed to
Turn Out Like This: Federal
Subsidies and Declining
Transit Productivity
Charles Lave
The Marriage of Autos
and Transit: How to Make
Transit Popular Again
Melvin M. Webber
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
The CAFE Standards Worked
Amihai Glazer
ACCESS 6, SPRING 1995
Introduction
Lydia Chen
The Weakening
Transportation-Land Use
Connection
Genevieve Giuliano
Bringing Electric Cars
to Market
Daniel Sperling
Who Will Buy Electric Cars?
Thomas Turrentine
Are HOV Lanes Really
Better?
Joy Dahlgren
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Slowdown Ahead for the
Domestic Auto Industry
Charles Lave
Introduction
Luci Yamamoto
ACCES S 1 1 , FAL L 19 9 7
Parking and Affordable Housing
Wenyu Jia and Martin Wachs
Lost Riders
Brian D. Taylor and
William S. McCullough
The Road Ahead:
Managing Pavements
Samer Madanat
ACCES S 1 4 , SPRI NG 1 99 9
The Land Use/Transportation
Connection (cont’d)
Melvin M. Webber
Middle Age Sprawl: BART
and Urban Development
John D. Landis and Robert Cervero
Free to Cruise: Creating
Curb Space for Jitneys
Daniel B. Klein, Adrian T. Moore,
and Binyam Reja
Director’s Comment
Martin Wachs
Access to Choice
Jonathan Levine
A New Agenda
Daniel Sperling
Total Cost of Motor-Vehicle Use
Mark A. Delucchi
Hot Lanes: Introducing
Congestion Pricing One
Lane at a Time
Gordon J. Fielding and
Daniel B. Klein
Splitting the Ties: The
Privatization of British Rail
José A. Gómez-Ibáñez
Are Americans Really Driving
So Much More?
Charles Lave
SmartMaps for Public Transit
Michael Southworth
Decision-Making After
Disasters: Responding to the
Northridge Earthquake
Martin Wachs and Nabil Kamel
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Autos Save Energy
Sharon Sarmiento
ACCESS 9, FAL L 1 99 6
Introduction
Luci Yamamoto
There’s No There There:
Or Why Neighborhoods
Don’t Readily Develop Near
Light-Rail Transit Stations
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and
Tridib Banerjee
The Century Freeway:
Design by Court Decree
Joseph DiMento, Drusilla van Hengel,
and Sherry Ryan
Transit Villages: Tools For
Revitalizing the Inner City
Michael Bernick
Food Access for the
Transit-Dependent
Robert Gottlieb and Andrew Fisher
The Full Cost of Intercity Travel
David Levinson
The Freeway’s Guardian
Angels
Robert L. Bertini
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Travel by Carless Households
Richard Crepeau and Charles Lave
Objects in Mirror Are Closer
Than They Appear
Theodore E. Cohn
Balancing Act: Traveling
in the California Corridor
Adib Kanafani
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Gas Tax Dilemma
Mary Hill, Brian Taylor,
and Martin Wachs
Does Contracting Transit
Service Save Money?
William S. McCullough, Brian D.
Taylor, and Martin Wachs
ACCES S 1 5 , FAL L 19 9 9
Tracking Accessibility
Robert Cervero
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
The Pedigree of a Statistic
Donald C. Shoup
ACCES S 1 2 , S PRI NG 1 99 8
Traditions and Neotraditions
Melvin M. Webber
Travel by Design?
Randall Crane
Traditional Shopping Centers
Ruth L. Steiner
Simulating Highway and
Transit Effects
John D. Landis
Cars for the Poor
Katherine M. O’Regan and
John M. Quigley
Will Electronic Home
Shopping Reduce Travel?
Jane Gould and Thomas F. Golob
What Can a Trucker Do?
Amelia Regan
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
The Parking of Nations
Donald Shoup and Seth Stark
ACCES S 1 8 , S PRING 2 0 0 1
Sustainability
Melvin M. Webber
R&D Partnership for
the Next Cars
Daniel Sperling
How Federal Subsidies Shape
Local Transit Choices
Jianling Li and Martin Wachs
Informal Transit: Learning
from the Developing World
Robert Cervero
The Value of Value Pricing
Kenneth A. Small
Eclecticism
Melvin M. Webber
Requiem for Potholes
Carl Monismith as told to Melanie Curry
Instead of Free Parking
Donald Shoup
Partners in Transit
Eugene Bardach, Timothy Deal,
and Mary Walther
Pooled Cars
Susan Shaheen
Why Bicyclists Hate
Stop Signs
Joel Fajans and Melanie Curry
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Census Undercount
Paul Ong
ACCES S 1 9 , FAL L 2 0 0 1
Transportation and the
Environment
Elizabeth A. Deakin
A New CAFE
Charles Lave
Reconsider the Gas Tax:
Paying for What You Get
Jeffrey Brown
Travel for the Fun of It
Patricia L. Mokhtarian and
Ilan Salomon
ACCES S 1 6 , SPRI NG 2 00 0
Surprises
Melanie Curry
What If Cars Could Drive
Themselves?
Steven E. Shladover
Power From the Fuel Cell
Timothy E. Lipman
Should We Try to Get
the Prices Right?
Mark Delucchi
Clean Diesel: Overcoming
Noxious Fumes
Christie-Joy Brodrick, Daniel Sperling,
and Harry A. Dwyer
High-Speed Rail Comes
to London
Sir Peter Hall
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Unlimited Access: Prepaid
Transit at Universities
Jeffrey Brown, Daniel Baldwin Hess,
and Donald Shoup
An Eye on the Fast Lane:
Making Freeway Systems
Work
Pravin Varaiya
On Bus-Stop Crime
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris
and Robin Liggett
39
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
A
C
S S
B
A
C
K
I
S S U E
S
ACCESS 23, FALL 2003
ACCESS 26, S PRI NG 2 00 5
ACCESS 2 9, FALL 200 6
ACCES S 3 0 , S PRI NG 2 0 0 7
ACCES S 3 3 , FAL L 2 0 0 8
Nobel Prize
Melvin M. Webber
University of California
Transportation Center:
15 Years of Accomplishment
Elizabeth A. Deakin
Earmarking Threatens
University Research
Martin Wachs and Ann Brach
Paying for Roads: New
Technology for an Old
Dilemma
Paul Sorensen and Brian Taylor
We’re All Transportation
Planners
Melanie Curry
Change Happens
Melanie Curry
Transportation Planning as
an Integral Part of Urban
Development: The Emerging
Paradigm
Elizabeth A. Deakin
Reforming Infrastructure
Planning
David Dowall
In the Dark: Seeing Bikes
at Night
Karen De Valois, Tatsuto Takeuchi,
and Michael Disch
Roughly Right or Precisely
Wrong
Donald Shoup
Transforming the Freight
Industry: From Regulation
to Competition to
Decentralization in the
Information Age
Amelia Regan
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
The Freeway-Congestion
Paradox
Chao Chen and Pravin Varaiya
Turning Small Change Into
Big Changes
Douglas Kolozsvari and
Donald Shoup
Older Drivers: Should We
Test Them Off the Road?
Sandi Rosenbloom
As Jobs Sprawl, Whither the
Commute?
Randall Crane and Daniel G. Chatman
Driving Less
Susan Handy
Trends and Policy Choices:
A Research Agenda
Elizabeth A. Deakin
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Transportation Costs and
Economic Opportunity
Among the Poor
Evelyn Blumenberg
ACCESS 24, SPRING 2 004
ACCES S 21, FALL 2002
No Lying Game
Luci Yamamoto
Spread-City Everywhere
Melvin M. Webber
Brazil’s Buses: Simply
Successful
Aaron Golub
Are SUVs Really Safer
Than Cars?
Tom Wenzel and Marc Ross
Rethinking Traffic Congestion
Brian D. Taylor
Motorizing the Developing
World
Daniel Sperling and Eileen Claussen
On the Back of the Bus
Theodore E. Cohn
Keeping Children Safe in Cars
Jill Cooper
Location Matters
Markus Hesse
Scrapping Old Cars
Jennifer Dill
Complications at Off-ramps
Michael Cassidy
Reconsidering the Cul-de-sac
Michael Southworth and
Eran Ben-Joseph
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Travel Patterns Among
Welfare Recipients
Paul Ong and Douglas Houston
ACCESS 25, FALL 2004
ACCES S 22, SPRING 2003
Shuttles for the First
and Last Mile
Elizabeth A. Deakin
Obsolescence Named Progress
William L. Garrison
People, Parking, and Cities
Michael Manville and Donald Shoup
Putting Pleasure Back in the
Drive: Reclaiming Urban
Parkways for the 21st
Century
Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris
and Robert Gottlieb
The Price of Regulation
Daniel Sperling
Local Option Transportation
Taxes: Devolution as
Revolution
Martin Wachs
The Private Sector’s Role
in Highway Finance:
Lessons from SR 91
Marlon G. Boarnet and
Joseph F. DiMento
Ports, Boats, and
Automobiles
Peter V. Hall
Are Induced-Travel Studies
Inducing Bad Investments?
Robert Cervero
Why Traffic Congestion Is
Here to Stay . . . and Will
Get Worse
Anthony Downs
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Auto Insurance Redlining
in the Inner City
Paul Ong
Making Communities Safe
for Bicycles
Gian-Claudia Sciara
C
E
ACCES S 20, SPRING 2002
The Path to Discrete-Choice
Models
Daniel L. McFadden
A
C
C
E
S
S
40
Unnoticed Lessons from
London: Road Pricing and
Public Transit
Kenneth A. Small
Which Comes First:
The Neighborhood
or the Walking?
Susan Handy and Patricia Mokhtarian
Discounting Transit Passes
Cornelius Nuworsoo
Economic Consequences of
Transport Improvements
T.R. Lakshmanan and
Lata R. Chatterjee
ACCESS 27, FAL L 20 0 5
In Praise of Diversity
Paul Craig
What We’ve Learned About
Highway Congestion
Pravin Varaiya
The Transition to Hydrogen
Joan Ogden
Hydrogen Highways
Timothy Lipman
Progressive Transport and
the Poor: Bogotá’s Bold
Steps Forward
Robert Cervero
Innovations in Travel
Modeling
Frank S. Koppelman
ACCESS 28, S PRI NG 2 00 6
Terrorist Attacks and
Transport Systems
Brian D. Taylor
Building a Boulevard
Elizabeth Macdonald
Must a Bridge Be
Beautiful Too?
Matthew Dresden
How Privatization Became
a Train Wreck
Eric A. Morris
Transit and Contracts:
What’s Best for Drivers?
Songju Kim and Martin Wachs
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Floating Cars
Daniel Baldwin Hess
Dispatch from London
John D. Landis
Asilomar Declaration on
Climate Policy
Daniel Sperling
Down to the Meter: Localized
Vehicle Pollution Matters
Douglas Houston, Jun Wu, Paul Ong,
and Arthur Winer
Stuck at Home: When Driving
Isn’t a Choice
Annie Decker
From Horse Power to
Horsepower
Eric A. Morris
Beyond the Automobile?
Sir Peter Hall
Cruising for Parking
Donald Shoup
Multimodal Transportation in
California: Connecting Planes,
Trains, and Automobiles
Adib Kanafani
Dispatch from Sydney:
Transport in the Land of Oz
John Landis
Planning Water Use
in California
William Eisenstein and
G. Mathias Kondolf
SPECIAL ISSUE, WINTER 2006–07
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
The Incredible Shrinking
Energy R&D Budget
Daniel M. Kammen and Gregory F.
Nemet
Integrating Infrastructure
Planning: The Role of Schools
Deborah McKoy, Jeff Vincent,
and Carrie Makarewicz
Mel Webber: 1920 – 2006
Melanie Curry
ACCES S 3 1 , FAL L 2 0 0 7
A Legacy of Skepticism:
Remembering Mel Webber
Martin Wachs
Flexible Transit, the American
City, and Mel Webber
Robert Cervero
Skeptical Optimism in
Transportation and Planning
Research
Brian D. Taylor
Melvin M. Webber: Maker
and Breaker of Planning
Paradigms
Sir Peter Hall
Teaching with Mel
Elizabeth Deakin
Learning from Mel
Jonathan Richmond
Urgent Action Required
Melanie Curry
For Whom the Road Tolls:
The Politics of Congestion
Pricing
David King, Michael Manville,
and Donald Shoup
If Cars Were More Efficient,
Would We Use Less Fuel?
Kenneth A. Small and
Kurt Van Dender
Fuel Economy: What Drives
Consumer Choice?
Tom Turrentine, Kenneth Kurani,
and Rusty Heffner
The Intersection of Trees
and Safety
Elizabeth Macdonald
Melvin Webber and the
“Nonplace Urban Realm”
Michael B. Teitz
Smarter Parking at
Transit Stations
Susan Shaheen and
Charlene Kemmerer
Beyond ITS and the
Transportation Monoculture
Daniel Sperling
ACCES S 3 2 , S PRI NG 2 0 0 8
The Mel Webber Index
THE ACCESS ALMANAC:
Love, Lies, and Transportation
in LA, Again
Charles Lave
California’s Growth:
An Uncertain Future
Michael B. Teitz
California Futures:
Accommodating Growth in
an Era of Climate Change
and Rising Fuel Prices
Elizabeth Deakin
The Challenge of Urban
Transportation in California
Elizabeth Deakin and Robert Cervero
A Strategy for Infrastructure:
The California Infrastructure
Initiative
David E. Dowall and Robin Ried
California’s Housing Problem
Cynthia Kroll and Krute Singa
Transportation Infrastructure
and Sustainable Development:
New Planning Approaches
for Urban Growth
Marlon G. Boarnet
ACCES S 3 4 , SPRI NG 2 0 0 9
Transportation Technologies
for the 21st Century
Elizabeth Deakin
Saving Fuel, Reducing
Emissions: Making Plug-In
Hybrid Electric Vehicles
Cost-Effective
Daniel M. Kammen, Samuel M.
Arons, Derek M. Lemoine, and
Holmes Hummel
Moving Forward With Fuel
Economy Standards
Lee Schipper
Transforming the Oil Industry
into the Energy Industry
Daniel Sperling and Sonia Yeh
Intelligent Transport Systems:
Linking Technology and
Transport Policy to Help
Steer the Future
Elizabeth Deakin, Karen Trapenberg
Frick, and Alexander Skabardonis
ACCES S 3 5 , FAL L 2 0 1 0
Access moves to LA
Michael Manville
Traffic Congestion and
Greenhouse Gases
Matthew Barth and Kanok Boriboonsomsin
Airport Congestion
Management:
Prices or Quantities?
Jan Brueckner
Moving Los Angeles
Paul Sorensen
TOD and Carsharing: A
Natural Marriage
Robert Cervero
Paved With Good Intentions:
Fiscal Politics, Freeways, and
the 20th Century American
City
Jeffrey Brown, Eric A. Morris, and
Brian Taylor
O
UCTC #
R
D
E
R
F
O
AUTHOR
R
M
TITLE
ACCESS NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
UCTC Director
Robert Cer vero
Editor
Donald Shoup
Associate Editor
Michael Manville
Design
Mitche Manitou
Try our website first: Most papers are available for
downloading (www.uctc.net)
N A M E __________________________________________________________________________________________
ADDRESS
_____________________________________________________________________________________
Access Editorial Board
Elizabeth A. Deakin
Robert Cer vero
Donald Shoup
Brian Taylor
Amelia Regan
__________________________________________________________________________________________________
PHONE
________________________________________________________________________________________
E M A I L _________________________________________________________________________________________
Send to:
Publications, University of California Transportation Center
2614 Dwight Way, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720–1782
Fax: (510) 643-5456
Email:
[email protected]
PHOTO CREDITS
pp. 10–11, 30–36: Donald Shoup
Subscriptions to ACCESS
To receive email notifications for issues of ACCESS, please send an email to
[email protected]. We will send you a message with a digest of each
issue's articles and a link to the online edition when the issue is published.
To receive a subscription to hard copies of ACCESS, please send an email with
your name and postal address to
[email protected]. Hard copies of
ACCESS are mailed only to domestic US addresses..
Or visit the ACCESS page on the website: http://www.uctc.net/access/
A D D R E S S
C O R R E C T I O N
If your mailing address on the back cover is incorrect, please provide the correct address
in the space provided AND either print the incorrect address below or cut it out from the
back cover and affix below.
OL D ADDR ESS:
NAM E _________________________________________________________________________________________
ADDRES S _____________________________________________________________________________________
_______________________________________________________________________________________________
University of California
Transportation Center
V I S I T O U R W E B S I T E AT
www.uctc.net
Printed on recycled paper
41
A
C
C
E
S
S
NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010
N O N - P R O F I T O R G A N I Z AT I O N
U . S . P O S TA G E PA I D
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA
T R A N S P O R TAT I O N C E N T E R
B E R K E L E Y, C A 9 4 7 2 0 – 1 7 8 2
ADDRESS SERVICE REQUESTED
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA