Academia.eduAcademia.edu

ACCESS Magazine Spring 2010

2010, ACCESS Magazine

AI-generated Abstract

The Spring 2010 issue of ACCESS Magazine presents a comprehensive examination of key policy issues surrounding transportation in California, emphasizing the importance of effectively aligning transportation policies with land use, energy, and public health in the face of challenges such as economic crises and global warming. The magazine highlights successful initiatives in congestion pricing and climate change legislation, while also addressing equity concerns related to road pricing. It aims to inform policymakers with research-driven insights to enhance innovative transportation policies.

UC Berkeley ACCESS Magazine Title ACCESS Magazine Spring 2010 Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8d59n2g8 Journal ACCESS Magazine, 1(36) Authors Ehrenfeucht, Renia Chapple, Karen Loukaitou-Sideris, Anastasia et al. Publication Date 2010-04-01 Copyright Information This work is made available under the terms of a Creative Commons AttributionNonCommercial License, availalbe at https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ Peer reviewed eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California ACCESS S P R I N G N U M B 2 0 1 0 E R 3 6 Tr a n s p o r t a t i o n R e s e a r c h a t t h e U n i v e r s i t y o f C a l i f o r n i a C O N T E N T A C C E S S 2 S 3 6 • S P R I N G 2 0 1 0 Just Road Pricing L I S A S C H W E I T Z E R A N D B R I A N D . TAY L O R 8 Public Parking Spaces for Shared Cars ANDREA OSGOOD 14 Restricting Transportation Infrastructure: Bad for Business in California? KAREN CHAPPLE AND CARRIE MAKAREWICZ 22 Vibrant Sidewalks in the United States: Re-integrating Walking and a Quintessential Social Realm A N A S TA S I A L O U K A I T O U - S I D E R I S A N D R E N I A E H R E N F E U C H T 30 Fixing Broken Sidewalks DONALD SHOUP 37 Papers in Print 39 Back Issues 41 Order Form The University of California Transportation Center, founded in 1988, facilitates research, education, and public service for the entire UC system. Activities have centered on the Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, Los Angeles, Riverside, and Santa Barbara campuses. Copyright © 2010 The Regents of the University of California University of California Transportation Center Phone: 310-825-5705 Fax: 310-206-5566 www.uctc.net Authors of papers reporting on research here are solely responsible for their content. Most of this research was sponsored by the US Department of Transportation and the California Department of Transportation, neither of which is liable for its content or use. I N T R O D U C T I O N What are the key policy issues? What are the take-aways from this research? What can we do now and what more do we need to know? F 2 0 Y E A R S , researchers at the University ronmental policy, and today it is at the forefront of reducing of California Transportation Center have asked hard the transportation sector’s carbon footprint, having recently OR OVER questions and used the answers to help guide public passed pioneering climate change legislation (AB 32 and SB policy. From its beginning, UCTC’s core research theme has 375). California has been, and can continue to be, a beacon of focused on tying together transportation systems analysis enlightened transportation policy. and policy. We do this by funding research, graduate and One goal of UCTC is to give policymakers the informa- undergraduate education, and special studies for federal, tion they need to enact wise and innovative transportation state and local governments. We also support events that policies. Access magazine is an important way for us to bring together professionals, researchers, and students to disseminate that information. Several articles in this issue confront key issues and identify emerging areas of interest. focus on a complex subject that generates many questions— Our activities are made possible through generous grants transportation infrastructure and how we use it and pay for it. from the US Department of Transportation and Caltrans. Lisa Schweitzer and Brian Taylor address one of the toughest One of the most prominent ways UCTC helps bridge questions of all: who pays for transportation infrastructure, research and practice is through its annual conference and is the payment structure fair? Two other articles focus on on transportation, land use and the environment held at sidewalks, an oft-ignored part of transportation infrastruc- UCLA’s Lake Arrowhead center. Now entering its 20th year, ture. Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Renia Ehrenfeucht this event brings together leading practitioners, researchers, consider how walking has dwindled, which is ironic given and elected officials to debate current policy issues. Last that local regulations have tended to ban many sidewalk October’s conference theme was “Economic Crisis as uses in the name of making it easier for pedestrians to walk. Opportunity for Reform.” The attendees generally agreed that Donald Shoup suggests a creative way to finance sidewalks in transportation policy needs a major overhaul. The challenge these cash-strapped times. presented by global warming suggests that at every level of Andrea Osgood examines another undervalued part of government, transportation policy needs to be better coordi- our infrastructure—curb parking spaces owned by cities. nated with land use, energy, and public health policy. Change She argues that local governments can use this resource to at this scale will require national leadership. Yet the federal encourage carsharing by reserving some spaces and making legislation that authorizes transportation funding recently them free or discounted for shared cars. Finally, Karen expired, and we appear to be in a cycle of continual short-term Chapple and Carrie Makarewicz challenge the conventional extensions simply to keep the system on autopilot. wisdom that transportation infrastructure needs to be There is room for optimism, however. Amid the gloom of expanded in the name of economic development. California ’s the economic crisis, it is easy to forget how much progress we most thriving businesses, they find, are in central cities, have made. In the years since the first Arrowhead conference, where infrastructure already exists. California has introduced two successful congestion pricing We hope that this and future issues of Access will help programs (on State Route 91 in Orange County and Interstate UCTC-funded research inform and inspire policy and practice 15 in San Diego). The state has long been a leader in envi- for years to come. Robert Cervero Karen Trapenberg Frick Just Road Pricing B Y L I S A S C H W E I T Z E R A N D B R I A N D . T AY L O R E CONOMISTS HAVE LONG ADVOCATED road pricing as an efficient way to reduce congestion and improve the environment. Many critics, however, object to road pricing on the grounds that it unfairly burdens low-income drivers. Implicit in these objections is the idea that existing transportation finance methods burden the poor less, or at least spread the burden more fairly. Most of the equity concerns about road pricing stem from the fact that it is regressive; that is, poorer people spend a larger share of their incomes on tolls than do wealthier people. But in the US, road systems are financed primarily through fuel taxes, vehicle registration fees, property taxes, and, increasingly, sales taxes—all of which are also regressive. Thus the relevant question is not simply whether road pricing is regressive, or even if it will burden the poor. The relevant question is whether road pricing will burden the poor more than other ways of paying for roads. Lisa Schweitzer is an associate professor in the School of Policy, Planning, and Development at the University of Southern California and a fellow of the Brookings Institution. Brian D. Taylor, AICP is Professor and Chair of Urban Planning and Director of the Institute of Transportation Studies in the UCLA School of Public A ffairs. A C C E S S 2 This question of road pricing’s fairness is particularly important now because traditional sources of revenue for transportation infrastructure are drying up. Travel is increasing (as are concerns about its social and environmental costs) but the buying power of fuel taxes has been declining for decades. Governments have responded to these funding shortfalls in a number of ways. Some have borrowed money to finance new roads, and some have started tolling roads. Many, however, have turned to general taxes, especially sales taxes, which have proven popular among voters and elected officials. Why are sales taxes, unlike other taxes, so popular? Sales taxes are automatically collected a few cents at a time from all consumers, and are hidden in a large number of transactions. So with sales taxes, unlike property or income taxes, it is almost impossible for residents to see how much they pay over the course of a year. The ease and relative opacity of the sales tax are keys to its ubiquity. Sales taxes also make it easy for cities and counties to shift part of the tax burden onto visitors who spend money in the taxing jurisdiction—the strategy cleverly described by the Monty Python comedy troupe as “taxing foreigners living abroad.” But the fact that sales taxes are popular doesn’t make them inherently fair or effective. ➢ 3 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 F OR W HOM THE R OAD T OLLS We should begin by defining some terms. Arguing that a policy proposal is “fair” assumes that fairness has a set definition, which of course it does not. Fairness is often in the eye of the beholder; what is consummately fair by one definition might be intolerably unfair by another. One common way to measure the fairness of a tax is to ask if it is progressive or regressive. We define a tax (or other charge) as progressive if its burden is proportionally greater for those with higher incomes than for those with lower incomes. The American income tax system, which imposes a higher tax rate on higher income people, is progressive. Likewise, a tax is regressive if its burden falls proportionally more heavily on those with lower-incomes than those with higher-incomes. A typical sales tax, where all consumers pay the same rate (say, 10 percent of purchase price), is regressive, because the tax burden for poor people will be larger as a share of overall income than it will be for rich people. In absolute terms, of course, wealthier people pay more in sales taxes than poorer people, because they spend more. But regressivity is a measure of proportional burden, and sales taxes paid as a percentage of income tends to fall as incomes rise. “Road pricing” is the practice of charging drivers in rough proportion to the costs (congestion delay, damage to roadbeds, emission of pollutants, etc.) they impose on others. Long the apple of economists’ eyes, road pricing can take many different forms. In the US, High Occupancy/Toll, or HOT, lanes are the most common type of priced road. HOT lanes impose congestion tolls on only part of a multilane road, giving drivers the option of paying to drive in the uncongested toll lanes, or of driving for free in the unpriced-butcongested lanes. Many of these facilities also allow carpoolers to use the priced lane for free or at a reduced rate. HOT lanes are a good illustration of how elusive the concept of “fairness” can be. In one sense, HOT lanes are eminently fair, because no one is forced to pay—drivers always have the option of remaining in the free, slow lane. In another sense, however, HOT lanes are unfair, because they discriminate based on ability-to-pay. All drivers pay the same toll, and the toll is a larger burden for those who have only a little money than it is for those who have a lot. HOT lanes are therefore regressive. For this reason critics call HOT lanes “Lexus Lanes,” and argue that they make it easy for the rich to buy their way out of congestion, while leaving the poor stuck in traffic. There is truth in both sides of the argument. Only users pay for HOT lanes, but poor people certainly have a harder time paying, and are therefore less able to be users. On average, wealthier drivers use paid lanes more than poor drivers do (just as they spend more on gas, drive nicer cars, and drive more in general). But income is not the sole determinant of people’s willingness to pay, and there will be instances where low-income drivers are in enough of a hurry to pay their way into uncongested lanes. So while a low-income single mother might not usually pay to bypass traffic, she will do so gladly when rushing to avoid late pick-up fees at daycare. There is also some evidence that HOT lanes pull travelers out of free lanes, and this can make even the free lanes move faster. But does this make the HOT lane fair? C OMPARING T OLLS AND S ALES TAXES In the abstract, it might be difficult to determine if a HOT lane is fair. But the more important question is whether tolls are fairer than a sales tax. For a given road, how much would different households pay in congestion tolls compared with what they pay in sales taxes? We attempted to answer this question by examining the 91 Express Lanes in A C C E S S 4 Southern California. The 91 Express Lanes are HOT lanes in the median of a 10-mile stretch of a congested freeway that links job-rich Orange County with housing-rich San Bernardino and Riverside Counties. The tolls in the Express Lanes serve two purposes: they regulate demand to keep the lanes moving at free-flow speed, and they finance the lanes’ construction, operation, and maintenance. In our analysis, we compare the population who paid the $34 million in tolls collected on the road in 2003 with the population who would have paid that amount had it been collected through sales taxes in Orange County that same year. To make this comparison, we used data from the 2002 Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES). We analyzed household consumer expenditures in Orange County at various income levels and estimated the household sales tax burden that would have accompanied those expenditures. To estimate 91 Express Lanes users’ toll payments by household type, we extrapolated from a survey that examined both travelers in the Express Lanes corridor and a comparison sample of people who traveled in the parallel free lanes. W INNERS AND L OSERS In 2003 the 91 Express Lanes raised $34 million in tolls. All of this money was, naturally, paid by users of the HOT lanes. Our question, again, was where the money would have come from if the same funds had been raised through sales taxes. Specifically, we examined the effects of such a change on three groups: the poor (people whose incomes are below $25,000), the rich (people whose incomes are above $120,000 a year), and those who pay county sales taxes but rarely or never use the toll lanes. (There is considerable overlap The question is not whether road pricing will burden the poor, but whether it will burden the poor more than other ways of paying or roads. between the poor and the non-user group because the poor tend to be non-users). We found that switching from tolls to sales taxes would shift the burden of paying for the road from users to non-users, and away from middle-income people and onto both ➢ 5 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 the rich and the poor. People in the poorest households in Orange County almost never use the 91 Express Lanes. So while few of the poor enjoy the time savings of travel in the tolled lanes, they also don’t pay for the road space that benefits others. But these same poor households pay up to 4 percent of their income each year in sales taxes. Had the lanes been financed by a sales tax, Orange County’s poorest households would have paid over $3 million of the $34 million needed to fund the facility in 2003. The richest households, for their part, would lose the most in absolute terms, because they buy lots of goods and services subject to sales taxes. With tolls, the burden of the Express Lanes falls on the relatively small group of people who choose to pay, and who as a consequence enjoy the time savings the lanes provide. With sales tax finance, virtually all users of the 91 Express Lanes would pay considerably less than they do now, because so many nonusers would pay. In 2003, this burden shift would have benefited frequent users of the 91 Express Lanes by around $700 a year. The additional costs to each sales-tax-paying “loser,” by contrast, would be relatively small, on the order of $5 to $80 per year, depending on the household type. But the relative size of this burden transfer does not obviate the question of whether people who don’t use the lane should subsidize people who do. If the answer is “yes,” the underlying logic implies that any public expenditure, no matter how small its benefits, can be justified, so long as the cost is spread over a large enough base of taxpayers. It also implies that those who drive least should, with every purchase they make, help pay for roads for those who drive most. A C C E S S 6 One caveat: our analysis examined sales tax payments by Orange County residents. FURTHER READING But not all sales taxes collected in Orange County are paid by residents, just as Orange County residents pay some of their sales taxes outside of the county. And because Orange County is home to Disneyland, two other major theme parks, beach resorts, and professional sports teams, it “imports” sales tax paying residents from other counties. But the fact that some of the sales tax burden is exported does not reduce the tax’s regressivity—it may, in fact, worsen it if the visitors to the County are, on average, less affluent than Orange County residents. C ONCLUSIONS Is road pricing regressive with respect to income? The short answer is yes. Whenever Lisa Schweitzer. 2009. “An Overview of the Empirical Research on Transportation Finance,” Sponsored by the National Academy of Sciences Transportation Research Board as a resource paper for Future Directions in Transportation Finance Policy, Washington, DC, September 1, 2009. Available from the author. Lisa Schweitzer and Brian D. Taylor. 2008. “Just Pricing: The Distributional Effects of Congestion Pricing and Sales Taxes,” Transportation, 35(6): 797–812. members of lower income groups pay for services, they tend to pay a larger share of their income than do the wealthy. But whether congestion tolls are regressive is an incomplete, and probably misleading, way to understand the fairness of tolls. A regressive charge is not automatically an unfair charge, and in public finance we frequently must decide between regressive alternatives, not between a regressive and a progressive choice. Hence the Brian D. Taylor and Rebecca Kalauskas. Forthcoming. “Addressing Equity in Political Debates over Road Pricing: Lessons from Recent Projects,” Transportation Research Record: The Journal of the Transportation Research Board. more relevant question is comparative: are congestion tolls fairer than other means of transportation finance? Our examination of the 91 Express Lanes in Orange County, California finds that transportation sales taxes are doubly unfair. They disproportionately burden the poor and those who drive little or not at all. We find that the heaviest users of the 91 Express Lanes— and the largest beneficiaries of them—are primarily from middle- and upper-middle income households both inside and outside of Orange County. From a regional planning perspective, Brian D. Taylor and Alexandra T. Norton. 2009. “Paying for Transportation: What’s a Fair Price?” Journal of Planning Literature, 24(1): 22–36. Matthew Barth and Kanok Boriboonsomsin. 2010. “Traffic Congestion and Greenhouse Gases,” Access, 35(Fall): 2–9. funding freeway capacity with sales taxes is a pro-auto/pro-driving policy that taxes all residents, rich and poor alike, to provide benefits to a much smaller group of drivers and their passengers. This analysis has focused on one side of the ledger: the question of who pays. But transportation systems have both costs and benefits. Indeed, the access benefits of travel are transportation’s raison d’être. So while regressivity can be viewed as a cost of road pricing (and of most other ways of paying for roads), pricing confers transportation benefits that other transportation finance mechanisms do not. Tolls and taxes can both pay to build a road. But congestion pricing can also reduce traffic delays, fuel consumption, and vehicle emissions, often to a surprising degree. Sales tax finance for transportation, by comparison, does none of these things. It is widely understood in public finance that a transparent payment mechanism is a good payment mechanism. Those who use scarce public resources—including space on the roads—should pay for what they use, in proportion to what they use, and know that they are paying. Knowing that resources have a cost is essential to using those resources judiciously, and our road network will function better when drivers pay the costs of their travel. It is entirely appropriate to worry about the burden tolls place on the poor, but the solution is not to forgo tolls altogether. We should not subsidize all drivers (and charge all consumers) to help the small number of poor travelers who use congested freeways in the peak hours and peak directions. Rather we should help those who are less fortunate, and see to it that the rest of us pay our own way on the roads. ◆ 7 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 On-Street Parking Spaces for Shared Cars BY ANDREA OSGOOD A C C E S S 8 I N A D D I T I O N T O T H E I R M A N Y A D VA N T A G E S , cars also cause problems: traffic congestion, air pollution, energy consumption, and even reduced mobility for those who don’t own a car. Carsharing is a new form of vehicle ownership that can help address these problems. Membership in a carsharing organization increases access to cars but also encourages judicious use of them. In essence, carsharing converts the high fixed costs of owning a car (purchase price, insurance, taxes, and maintenance) into smaller units—the per-hour or per-mile price of driving a car. By spreading the fixed costs of a car over many users, carsharing makes automobile travel an option for those who cannot afford to buy their own vehicle. But because users pay a high marginal cost for every hour or mile they drive, carsharing also gives members a strong incentive to drive less. In this way, carsharing can both increase mobility for people who might otherwise be carless and also reduce auto travel among members who previously owned their own car. This reduction in auto travel carries a host of benefits to society, from reducing local traffic congestion to slowing global climate change. W HERE W ILL THE S HARED C ARS PARK ? The largest barrier to expanding carsharing is often finding and financing parking spaces. An effective way for cities to encourage carsharing, therefore, is to offer carsharing firms free or discounted parking. Cities are in a unique position to offer these much-needed parking spaces because they control a large and ubiquitous supply of curb spaces that they can make available to carsharing organizations on favorable terms. Free or discounted parking in any location, off-street or on-street, will help support carsharing. On-street spaces, however, offer three special benefits for shared cars. Visibility. Shared cars are not hidden away in off-street lots, but are placed on streets where everyone can see them. This visibility increases the general awareness of carsharing, and may also remind car owners of the inconvenience and hassle of parking their own car. Convenience. Dedicated curb spaces are nearly as luxurious and worry-free as valet parking or a private garage near one’s front door. When returning home, these dedicated parking spaces allow members to simply pull up to the curb and leave the car. Drivers do not have to worry about finding a space, or about being late because they have to cruise around the block. Most shared cars are located in dense areas with scarce and expensive parking, precisely the areas where residents who own cars but do not have off-street parking spend quite a bit of time cruising the streets in search of a spot to park. Availability. On-street spaces are often the main source of parking in some areas, and car ownership is difficult in these areas as a result. These places are natural targets for carsharing, but without city partnership, carsharing organizations would be unable to expand in these places because they too would have no place to store their cars. ➢ Andrea Osgood received her MA in Urban Planning at UCLA, and currently works on transit- oriented development for Eden Housing. This article is drawn from her MA research at UCLA, which won the Nevill A. Parker Award in 2007 from the Council of University Transportation Centers ([email protected]). 9 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 D ESIGNING AN O N -S TREET PARKING P OLICY FOR S HARED C ARS A city that wants to support carsharing by reserving curb spaces for shared cars must develop a policy to allocate the curb spaces. For example, how much, if anything, should the city charge carsharing organizations for the dedicated spaces? Should the spaces be auctioned? What is necessary to manage the dedicated spaces (procuring and installing signage, striping the pavement, and keeping the spaces clean)? To answer these questions, I conducted cases studies of cities that have adopted ordinances to allocate curb parking spaces to shared cars. When a city dedicates on-street parking for carsharing organizations, it also limits the public’s access to the curb spaces. This loss of access, combined with the fact that local jurisdictions would be allowing private companies to profit from a public resource, can make the allocation of on-street spaces controversial. While there is ample precedent for this kind of privatization—cities across the US regularly dedicate sections of streets for taxi zones, hotel and restaurant valet areas, and commercial loading zones—concerns over unfair allocation of public resources are legitimate, particularly if carsharing organizations are allowed to use street spaces at no cost. In order to diffuse these concerns, any policy that allocates on-street parking spaces to carsharing organizations should be crafted to ensure that the public realizes a return that exceeds the value of these spaces. This return can be realized through direct payments to the municipality, or through other, non-monetary benefits such as reduced air A C C E S S 10 pollution or increased mobility options for low-income populations. Either way, this return should be guaranteed in a privatization agreement that ensures the public gets the best deal possible. C A SE S TUDIES OF O N -S TREET PARKING P OLICY : K EY F INDINGS Several North American cities are currently drafting, or have already implemented, on-street parking policies for carsharing. These jurisdictions include Arlington County, Virginia; San Diego, California; Seattle, Washington; Portland, Oregon; Vancouver, British Columbia; and Washington, DC. In their approach to parking for carsharing, these cities adopted a range of policy approaches. In what follows I summarize the key findings of my case studies that examined these approaches. • Legislative structure. Setting aside street space for a private organization requires legislative action. In general, cities break the legislative mechanism into two parts: (1) an ordinance or other official action by a governing body, and (2) the administrative details. The first component sets out broad parameters for the policy, including key political provisions, and then delegates authority to another department to establish the administrative details of the program, which can be updated and modified as necessary. • Fees. Few cities initially charged carsharing organizations for on-street spaces. As carsharing operators have become more established, however, several cities—such as Vancouver, Portland, and Washington, DC—have moved toward revenue-neutral fee structures; the city sets a fee for each space to defray the public costs of their program and to recoup any lost meter revenue. • Signage and demarcation of spaces. Several cities use orange “Options Zone” poles (first developed in Portland) to designate their on-street carsharing spaces. These brightly colored poles include images meant to highlight alternative transit options such as biking and walking. When combined with brand-neutral marketing brochures and places to secure bikes, these poles help the public to learn more about carsharing and facilitate the use of bikes to get to and from shared cars. Tow-away signs and pavement markings appear to be the most effective way to ensure that other drivers do not mistakenly park in carsharing spaces. • Results. Cities often provide multiple forms of support to carsharing organizations, so isolating the effect of providing on-street parking spaces can be difficult. However, evaluations have consistently shown that carsharing membership increases as more vehicles are added, and that members who previously owned one or more cars reduce their vehicle travel and/or sell a car. The growth in carsharing can greatly benefit even those who do not participate in it. One study found that each shared vehicle removed 9 to 13 other vehicles from the road. Fewer vehicles can lead to significant reductions in traffic congestion, air and water pollution, and parking infrastructure. ➢ 11 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 P L ANNING FOR S HARED C ARS Cities can go beyond responding to carsharing companies’ requests for on-street parking spaces and proactively plan the location of these spaces. Hoboken, NJ, has established its citywide Corner Cars program that places shared cars in on-street spaces at corners throughout the city so that 90 percent of the population lives within a five-minute walk of at least one carsharing location. Because each shared car in Hoboken has been estimated to replace 17 private vehicles, dedicating the corner spaces to shared cars can increase the availability of on-street parking for everyone else. According to Hoboken’s Transportation and Parking Director Ian Sacs, “Instead of taking on millions of dollars in taxpayer debt for structured parking, residents who switch to carsharing will save thousands of dollars. It’s the 21st Century solution to contemporary urban parking woes.” Hoboken requires the fleet of shared cars to maintain an average of 35 miles per gallon. If each shared car replaces several privately-owned cars that have lower fuel efficiency, the on-street Corner Car program can significantly reduce the city’s carbon footprint. 90% of Hoboken residents are within a five minute walk of a Corner Car Corner Car location Five minute walk radius A C C E S S 12 R ECOMMENDATIONS F U R T H E R R E A D I N G Any policy that dedicates on-street spaces for shared cars must have a mechanism to verify and ensure the benefits of carsharing, particularly if local jurisdictions choose not to charge a market-based fee for these spaces. A valid verification mechanism can address concerns about privatization and also ensure that the public realizes a return on its investment. The following provisions should be included in any agreement between Arlington County Commuter Services. 2006. Arlington Carshare Program. Department of Environmental Services, Division of Transportation Website (http://www.commuterpage.com/pdfdocs/ArlCo_ CarshareReport_2006.pdf). cities and carsharing organizations: • Ensure that vehicles emit minimal pollutants. Require that all vehicles parked in on-street spaces meet the EPA’s ultra-low-emissions-vehicle standards, or vary the fees based on the emissions profile of each shared car parked. • Ensure increased mobility for low-income populations. Require a certain number of vehicles in low-income neighborhoods. • Verify benefits. Require that the carsharing organizations provide annual travel behavior data on their members to the municipality. • Ensure expansion—not just subsidization. The city’s investment should help carsharing organizations expand, not simply reduce their current operating costs. Many carsharing organizations have at least some vehicles parked in off-street private locations, and a poorly-designed agreement could allow the organizations to move these cars from off-street spaces (paid) into the on-street ones (free). The organization gains substantially when this happens, but the public doesn’t. To prevent this sort of outcome, cities should mandate that any cars parked in private off-street lots remain there for a period of time after the street spaces are dedicated. C ONCLUSIONS On-street parking spaces for shared cars will encourage the growth of carsharing Robert Cervero, Aaron Golub, and Brendan Nee. 2007. “San Francisco City CarShare: Longer-Term Travel-Demand and Car Ownership Impacts,” Transportation Research Record, Journal of the Transportation Research Board, no. 1992: 70–80. Clayton Lane. 2005. “PhillyCarShare: First-Year Social and Mobility Impacts of Carsharing in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania,” Transportation Research Record, Journal of the Transportation Research Board, no. 1927: 158–166. Elliott Martin, Susan Shaheen, and Jeffrey Lidicker. 2010. “Carsharing’s Impact on Household Vehicle Holdings: Results from North American Shared-Use Vehicle Survey,” presented at the Transportation Research Board Annual Meeting, Washington, DC, 2010 (http://pubsindex.trb.org/view.aspx?id=911080) Adam Millard-Ball, Gail Murray, Jessica ter Schure, Christine Fox, and Jon Burkhart. 2005. “Car-Sharing: Where and How It Succeeds,” TCRP Report 108 for the Transportation Research Board. Susan Shaheen, Adam Cohen, and Elliot Martin. 2010. “Carsharing and Parking Policy: A Review of North American Practices and San Francisco Bay Area Case Study,” Forthcoming in Transportation Research Record. because on-street spaces create extra value in two ways. First, the time savings and convenience of on-street spaces can attract new members to carsharing organizations. Second, the great visibility of shared vehicles prominently parked on the streets will serve Ian Sacs, 2010. “Parking Garages Are So Last Century,” Planetizen, June 17 (http://www.planetizen.com/node/44698). as advertising that can show the benefits of membership. Some drivers may oppose dedicating on-street parking spaces to shared cars because it will reduce access for privately-owned cars. Nevertheless, carsharing’s benefits are well established. If carsharing reduces vehicle travel, particularly at peak hours, it can reduce traffic congestion, air pollution, and energy consumption. It can also increase mobility for a city’s poorest residents. Reducing the on-street parking available to privately owned cars might even encourage more people to become carsharing members, creating a positive cycle that will further increase the benefits of carsharing. Each onstreet parking space dedicated to a shared car can benefit many people, including those who do not carshare. ◆ 13 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 R ESTRICTING N EW I NFRA STRUCTURE : Bad for Business in California? BY KAREN CHAPPLE AND CARRIE MAKAREWICZ P LANNERS THROUGHOUT C A L I F O R N I A are preparing to implement SB 375, a law that requires metropolitan planning organizations (MPOs) to consider the impact of land use decisions on climate change, and requires that future planning decisions reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Among other provisions, the bill encourages municipalities and developers to concentrate infrastructure and development in urban areas or close to public transit hubs in order to reduce vehicle use. The bill also includes a number of provisions to better coordinate the provision of housing and transportation infrastructure. SB 375 could have profound effects on California’s cities. If MPOs and local govern- By encouraging ments change their housing, transportation, and land use plans in response to the law, then infrastructure funds, private investment, and housing will likely be steered into more compact patterns, and development will occur primarily in places where it already exists. infill development, What will compact development patterns mean for business and job creation? Firms, like households, have been decentralizing for decades, largely because of falling transporta- SB 375 could very tion and communication costs. As a result, the conventional wisdom is that the suburbs and exurbs are “business friendly,” and that the ease of locating outside central cities has allowed well help, not businesses to expand more rapidly than they would have in the urban core. If business growth depends on the ability of firms to move to outlying areas, then SB 375, in its effort to help the environment, might harm the economy. Infrastructure planning hinder, California's that encourages infill development, and that constrains public funding for new roads and interchanges in outlying areas, could limit the growth of businesses in California. Indeed, the economic growth. idea that SB 375 might stifle economic growth seems to be the consensus among many of the state’s major business players. The California Chamber of Commerce, the California Manufacturers and Technology Association, the General Contractors of California, and the California Retailers Association all opposed the bill. Lobbyists for these groups raised concerns that the bill would hinder investment in new infrastructure and leave projects that don’t support infill vulnerable to lawsuits. Opponents also argued that SB 375 would increase the cost of any development that significantly increases auto traffic. The developers of these projects would need to pay for their own infrastructure. Developers faced with these new infrastructure costs might pass them on to end users, thereby increasing the costs for their tenants. Or they might scale back or forgo projects, which would limit location options for businesses and drive up costs region-wide. Are the opponents of SB 375 correct to be concerned? Does business growth in California in fact depend on the ability of firms to relocate outward, particularly to places in need of more transportation infrastructure? A look at California business growth patterns— by studying more than three million records of business relocations, startups, and expansions over a fifteen-year period—suggests the reality is more complicated. First of all, inhibiting business relocation is not a big concern, because most businesses never ➢ Karen Chapple is an Associate Professor of City & Regional Planning at the University of California, Berkeley, specializing in regional economic development ([email protected]). Carrie Makarewicz is a PhD student in City and Regional Planning at the University of California, Berkeley ([email protected]). 15 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 relocate. Almost all employment growth occurs when new businesses are formed or when firms expand where they are, not when an existing business moves somewhere else. And while it is true that new businesses tend to start in places with plentiful infrastructure, it is not clear that infrastructure is the decisive factor in the location decision. Location decisions appear instead to be driven by concerns about the labor force (for some firms, the availability of a college-educated workforce, for others, the presence of low-wage labor) and housing (often the concentration of newer, owner-occupied housing in the area). Further, there is little evidence that new firms necessarily prefer the suburbs over central cities. If we compare central cities and suburbs that have roughly the same level of infrastructure, three times as many growing firms locate in the central cities as choose the suburbs. None of this is to say that infrastructure isn’t important; firms overwhelmingly prefer to be near highways and airports. But transportation infrastructure isn’t everything, and it certainly isn’t the only thing. In the remainder of this article we first review what researchers know about firm location, and then discuss our own research on business expansion in California. W HAT WE KNOW ABOUT LOC ATION , RELOC ATION , AND INFRA STRUCTURE Planners, economists and regional scientists have amassed a large body of research on the factors that influence business location and relocation decisions. A firm’s location depends on the costs and benefits associated with a particular place. Transportation infrastructure is a benefit: it improves access to suppliers and customers, and to employees and potential employees. But transportation infrastructure is just one consideration, and a lot of research suggests that the presence of a good workforce is more important than the presence of a highway. Firms that require skilled labor tend to locate in places that have amenities skilled people find attractive: good schools, cultural and recreation opportunities, high-quality housing, and transit. Businesses that rely on low-wage labor, by contrast, tend to locate near large groups of immigrants and in places with plentiful rental housing. To the extent they can, all businesses try to distance themselves from dis-amenities like congestion, crime, pollution, and high local taxes. Although policymakers sometimes worry that a poor “business climate” will drive business away, most evidence suggests this fear is overblown. Once firms establish in a specific location, only a small percentage of them ever move, mainly because moving requires large amounts of money, time, risk, and uncertainty. And when a firm does move, it may be a mistake to assume that it does so out of dissatisfaction with its current location. Some researchers suggest mergers, acquisitions, and takeovers are often as much the cause of a move as is the local business or physical environment. By themselves, then, limits on new suburban and exurban infrastructure should be unlikely to harm California’s economic growth. If the law prevented new infrastructure in places with large labor forces and plentiful housing (i.e., large population centers), that might be different, but that is the opposite of the law’s intent. T RACKING B USINESS G ROWTH IN C ALIFORNIA Business growth can be measured in two ways: by counting firms, and by counting jobs. The Dun and Bradstreet National Establishment Time Series (NETS) data for California lets us do both. Dun & Bradstreet reports annually on almost all the registered firms in California. We focused on firms with at least two employees, of which there were about A C C E S S 16 FIGURE 1 Major transportation infrastrucure in California Major airports Far North Highways Interstates ■ Jurisdictions Sacramento Area Bay Area San Joaquin Valley Sierras Central Coast Inland Empire South Coast 0 0 51 0 30 4 s 0 20 Mile 80 MILES San Diego 1.5 million active in California in 2005, and of which there were just over 3 million between 1990 and 2005. Of the firms active in 2005, a slight majority, 56 percent, were in the state’s 91 central cities, while 41 percent were in suburbs or other non-central-city parts of metropolitan areas. Only two percent of the firms were not in an MSA and not in a central city. The two largest regions, the nine-county Bay Area and three-county South Coast (Los Angeles, Orange and Ventura counties), were home to almost two-thirds of the state’s firms. Figure 1 displays the regions, jurisdictional boundaries, and major infrastructure we used for our analysis. From 1990 to 2005, the largest source of business growth (accounting for 60 percent of new firms and 47 percent of new employees) was startups. The second largest contributor to growth was expansions (29 percent of firms and 36 percent of employees). The relocation of firms—either from within California or from other states—generates only a small share of growth (about 11 percent of firms and 17 percent of employees). ➢ 17 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO F IRMS THAT R ELOC ATE When firms do relocate, they almost always move to the same type of place, i.e. from a central city to a central city or from a suburb to a suburb, and many stay within the same city or county (Figure 2). Only seven percent of relocating firms moved to a different region, and only four percent left California altogether. So very few regions saw their economies suffer because firms moved out, and still fewer saw their regional economies gain because firms moved in. In most of California’s local jurisdictions, fewer than 5 percent of the existing businesses are the result of relocations. Only in a small handful of jurisdictions, primarily in the Imperial Valley and the state’s rural northeast, do relocations account for between 16 and 27 percent of the existing businesses. The firms that move into these places are disproportionately likely to be in the agricultural, construction, manufacturing, or public administration sectors. And the high share of relocations in these places is primarily an artifact of their low initial number of firms, not because a large number of firms chose to move there. The facts that firms rarely move, and that when they do they tend to stay near their initial location, suggest that the presence or absence of infrastructure is probably not a driving force in location decisions. Certainly infrastructure is important, but our analysis suggests that relocating firms also search for a good pool of labor, and a housing stock that suits the preferences of those potential employees. Hence firms that relocate to central cities often do so because the cities are closer to more rental housing, which can support a younger or lower-wage workforce. Firms moving to the suburbs, by contrast, will have increased proximity to owner-occupied housing and lower residential densities, which may help them meet their employees’ housing and lifestyle preferences. FI G U RE 2 Where do firms go? Leaving California 4% Entering California 3% Different region 7% Same city 33% Different county, same region 10% Same county, different city 43% A C C E S S 18 FIGURE 3 Startups as a percent of total firms by jurisdiction PERCENT OF TOTAL FIRMS Far North ■ ■ ■ ■ - 18 % 16% 16 –18%5% 11% -1 11–15% 10 % 6% - 6 –10% 5% %0 0–5% Sacramento Area Bay Area San Joaquin Valley Sierras Central Coast Inland Empire South Coast 0 80 MILES San Diego T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO S TARTUPS In every sector except agriculture a newly-formed firm is more likely to locate where there is at least one highway or interstate, as well as a major airport. Figure 3 shows that startups are concentrated in California’s populous coastal regions, and in the central cities of the Central Valley. And there is a correlation between infrastructure and employment. New firms tend to be small; most have ten or fewer employees in their first year. Even so, in seven of the ten major industries, firms that start up in central cities near highways and airports employ more people than similar firms in jurisdictions that lack highways and airports. As with relocations, however, housing and labor markets also contribute to a new firm’s location decision. In particular, the presence of immigrants in central cities plays an important role for startups—much more so than it does for relocations. The urban concentrations of immigrants in central cities might explain the disproportionate share of startups that begin in central cities, rather than suburbs, since immigrants provide inexpensive labor for business startups, often start small businesses themselves, and provide a large consumer base for other startups. ➢ 19 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 T HE I MPORTANCE OF I NFRA STRUCTURE TO F IRM E XPANSION Expanding firms are concentrated mostly just outside core urban areas, and like startups they are often within 10 miles of airports, highways and interstates. Some growing industry sectors—like manufacturing and wholesale firms, and Finance, Insurance and Real Estate (FIRE) firms—are more likely than others to concentrate in jurisdictions crossed by highways or within 10 miles of an airport. For example, almost two-thirds of expanding manufacturing and wholesale firms locate near transportation infrastructure, as do 59 percent of FIRE firms. And the most rapidly growing firms tend to be in infrastructure-rich areas: for instance, almost three-quarters of the new jobs that result from expansion in the manufacturing, wholesale, and FIRE sectors concentrate near highways and airports. The industry sectors less likely to look for close proximity (less than 10 miles) to highways and airports are agriculture, public administration, and construction, probably because of sensitivity to land costs, as well as proximity to their residential base of customers. A C C E S S 20 Our analysis shows that expanding firms, like new firms and relocating firms, also base their decisions on the type of housing available, and (like startups) many firm expansions take place near large populations of immigrants. In sum, there is no denying that firms locate near transportation infrastructure. In 2005, nearly all firms (98 percent) were in cities crossed by highways or interstates, and within ten miles of a major airport. The preference for infrastructure remains if we examine increases in employment; 72 percent of all new jobs (and 61 percent of firms) develop in jurisdictions with local and interstate highways and that are less than 10 miles from a major airport. On the surface, the fact that most firms are close to transportation infrastructure could lend credence to fears about SB 375. If businesses want to be close to transportation infra- FURTHER READING structure, then restricting the expansion of that infrastructure could, logically, restrict the expansion of businesses as well. But our analysis suggests this is not the case, for two reasons. First, the most dynamic firms are located in the most urban areas of each region. If we compare central cities and suburbs that have the same level of highway and airport infrastructure, growing firms (whether expanding in place, starting up, or relocating) are three times more likely to locate in central cities than suburbs—even though overall just 56 percent of firms are in central cities. This suggests that the type and level of infrastructure needed to support fast business growth can be found in dense, already-built areas, not just in outlying greenfields. Second, our research shows that proximity to a major airport is one of the most important determinants of firm location. With or without SB 375, the state is unlikely to construct more major airports in the near future, for a host of reasons. So most business growth will probably take place near the 13 major airports we already have. And even if California did build a new major airport, it seems unlikely that it would do so in an undeveloped area. Airports are built where the demand for their services is highest, and this tends to be in or near areas that are intensively-developed now (10 of the state’s 13 major Aleid Brouwer, Ilaria Mariotti, and Jos N. van Ommeren. 2004. “The Firm Relocation Decision: An Empirical Investigation,” The Annals of Regional Science, vol. 38, no. 2: 335–347. Karen Chapple, Sara Hinkley, and Carrie Makarewicz. 2008. “Business as Usual in California’s Suburbs?: Exploring the Dynamics of Firm Relocation, 1990–2005,” presented at the joint Congress of the Association of Collegiate Schools of Planning (ACSP) and the Association of European Schools of Planning, Chicago IL, July 6–11. Paul Gottlieb. 1995. “Residential Amenities, Firm Locations, and Economic Development,” Urban Studies, vol. 32, no. 9: 1413–1436. airports are along the heavily-populated coast). C ONCLUSION Fears that environmental legislation might impede economic growth are nothing new, and should not be cavalierly dismissed. Increased environmental protection often involves tradeoffs, and businesses do sometimes lose when the environment gains. In the case of SB 375’s infrastructure restrictions, however, concerns about a chilling effect on business Genevieve Giuliano. 2004. “Land Use Impacts of Transportation Investments: Highway and Transit,” In The Geography of Urban Transportation, Chapter 9. Andrew Haughwout. 1999. “State Infrastructure and the Geography of Employment.” Growth and Change, vol. 30, no. 4: 549–566. appear to be unwarranted. There is little doubt that expanding firms prefer to be near transportation infrastructure, but the recent history of California shows that firms can expand and stay close to infrastructure without leaving dense, already-populated areas. The businesses that have contributed to the majority of growth within the last 15 years have not been expanding on the urban periphery in search of new, undeveloped sites with little infrastructure and no highway. Rather they seek sites with existing major infrastructure that has been in place long enough to attract other city amenities, an ample labor force, and appropriate housing for their workers. In short, businesses can’t expand without access to infrastructure, but businesses can get access to infrastructure without migrating to the periphery. Our analysis Jed Kolko and David Neumark. 2007. Business Location Decisions and Employment Dynamics in California. (Public Policy Institute of California). Available from www.ppic.org. Chad Shirley and Clifford Winston. 2004. “Firm Inventory Behavior and the Returns from Highway Infrastructure Investments,” Journal of Urban Economics, vol. 55, no. 2: 398–415. suggests that if anything, firms would like to see more (and more varied) housing options in areas that are already-developed. If this is the case, then by encouraging infill development SB 375 could very well help, not hinder, California’s economic growth. ◆ 21 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 Vibrant Sidewalks in the United States Re-integrating Walking and a Quintessential Social Realm B Y A N A S TA S I A L O U K A I T O U - S I D E R I S A N D R E N I A E H R E N F E U C H T AS A TRANSPOR TATION MODE, walking is healthy for individuals and beneficial for the environment. Fifteen years ago, the US Surgeon General highlighted the importance of walking for exercise as a means of combating obesity, diabetes, and other diseases. Since then, a wealth of studies published in public health and medical journals have extolled the virtues of walking. Moved by concerns about climate change, energy, and congestion, transportation planners now view walking as an inexpensive and enjoyable activity that could replace short auto trips, thus reducing congestion and fossil fuel consumption. Yet despite the general consensus that walking brings many benefits, policymakers still aren’t sure how to increase the amount of walking people actually do. One of the most obvious approaches is to improve pedestrian infrastructure. Walking is harder in places without good sidewalks, and the sidewalks in many cities are in terrible disrepair. Many other places have no sidewalks at all. But good sidewalks, while important, will not by themselves lead to more walking. Changes in the built environment are a necessary but not sufficient condition for a pedestrian-friendly city. Urban areas where people enjoy walking have more than just a functional pedestrian infrastructure. Sidewalks are not like major streets, many of which are designed solely to move cars. Sidewalk users are more exposed to their environments than drivers, both because pedestrians are not encased in vehicles and because they move through their environments more slowly than do people in cars. For this reason sidewalk users also require more from their environments. A successful sidewalk is more than just a route for getting from Point A to Point B; it is also a place to abide, to meet others, and to participate in neighborhood life. Urban sidewalks, as Jane Jacobs once argued, are a city’s “most vital organs,” where people experience city life, enjoy neighborhood rhythms, and watch what goes on. Pedestrianism—moving on foot, in a wheelchair, or with other mobility devices—is only one dimension of the sidewalk experience. Sidewalks thrive as multi-use environments, not as pure pedestrian thoroughfares. Many sidewalks in US cities lack the people and variety of activities that characterize sidewalks in Europe, Asia, or Latin America, but this was not always the case. Nineteenth and early twentieth century US sidewalks were vibrant spaces. As policy-makers began to perceive sidewalks exclusively as transportation infrastructure, however, they used the goal of unrestricted movement as ➢ Anastasia L oukaitou-Sideris is Professor of Urban Planning at UCLA. Renia Ehrenfeucht is Assistant Professor of Planning and Urban Studies at the University of New Orleans. A C C E S S 22 23 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 a justification to restrict other activities, including public speaking, vending, socializing and loitering. Removing these activities sapped the sidewalk of life and vitality. The singular view of streets and sidewalks as transportation routes, later combined with policies that overwhelmingly favored motorists over pedestrians, inadvertently made walking a less critical dimension of urban living. Planners who want to reinvigorate pedestrian spaces today face a difficult challenge. Building infrastructure alone will not work, because people are more likely to walk in areas that host a diversity of uses. Some uses, however, potentially conflict—a panhandler and a shopper can occupy the same space, but the panhandler might make the shopper uncomfortable. Planners have tried to finesse this problem by encouraging certain kinds of uses, and by encouraging pedestrianism only in certain places, creating upscale pedestrian hubs and leisure destinations. These efforts at control often raise hard questions about democracy and legality, and in any event are rarely effective ways to encourage more walking. We propose that more people will walk or roll in wheelchairs when sidewalks are spaces that accommodate the full range of activities that make cities interesting. In the remainder of this article, we first discuss how a singular focus on sidewalks as spaces of movement contributed to the decline of sidewalk life, and to walking as well. We then examine ways that cities will perpetuate this problem if they continue responding to urban complexity by providing spaces with narrow programs. Finally, we outline five purposes of sidewalks—movement, encounter, confrontation, survival and beauty—and argue that, unlike with automobiles, it is complexity, rather than uninterrupted movement that is central to People are more likely to walk in areas vibrant pedestrianism. T HE R ISE OF THE S INGLE -P URPOSE S IDEWALK In the 19th century, curbs and sidewalks became common along heavily traveled city streets. These early sidewalks were often constructed by the abutting businesses and property owners. By the century’s end, sidewalks had become important elements of the urban infrastructure, and thousands of miles of sidewalks had been paved in American cities. Because sidewalks were often paved before the rest of the street, they were the easiest place to walk, that host a and the easiest place to carry out various economic and social activities. In commercial areas, sidewalks extended the realm of adjacent shops; shopkeepers displayed their merchandise on sidewalks and stored deliveries and overstock on them as well. Street peddlers made a living diversity of uses. outdoors while street speakers and newsboys conveyed information to passersby. Sidewalks were also a realm for social encounters where friends, acquaintances, and strangers mixed. The sidewalks were thus both a route and a destination; a way to move through the city, but also a place of commerce, social interaction, and civic engagement. As sidewalks proliferated, municipalities began to standardize them. Cities specified sidewalk dimensions, construction standards, and materials to ensure consistency and durability. At the same time, cities began to standardize streets and to require durable paving for the roadbed and travel lanes. With this standardization, the nature of the urban sidewalk began to change, and its range of uses began to contract. Municipal engineers began to focus narrowly on efficient transportation and the importance of clean streets. Cities prohibited abutting property owners from using the sidewalks as extensions of their businesses, and the courts— when businesses challenged cities—upheld the cities’ authority to do so. In the process, walking for transportation became sidewalks’ primary purpose and the pedestrian the primary user. The pedestrian’s unobstructed mobility justified subsequent municipal restrictions on A C C E S S 24 other sidewalk activities. Consequently, the pedestrian became the sole “public” for whom the sidewalks were provided. Cities applied a similar logic to streets. The advent of local planning further changed the street from a locally-oriented public space to a transportation corridor. Municipalities developed public paving projects whose primary goal was traffic movement. In the late 19th century pedestrians grumbled about the hindrances that blocked sidewalks; by the turn of the century pedestrians found they had become the hindrance, regarded by local planners as “obstructions” to the automobile. The sidewalk shifted from being the most convenient space for walking to the only legitimate space for walking. As pedestrians became “encroachers” into the roadbed, they were viewed as a source of accidents and congestion. City councils restricted pedestrian crossings to intersections, required pedestrians to obey traffic signals and instituted fines for jaywalking. As automobiles proliferated in the early twentieth century, newspaper editorials blamed pedestrians for accidents because they defied the rules of the road and walked into moving vehicles. “The dumb pedestrian really is pretty dumb,” a columnist from Westways magazine wrote in 1937. “As a pedestrian the average man is not very bright…. As an incorrigible individualist, the pedestrian is intellectually inferior to the motorist in his traffic conduct.” As early as 1912, urban infrastructure trade magazines such as American City advised widening streets at the expense of sidewalks. Pedestrians were banned from streets to make room for cars, and a myriad of activities were banned from sidewalks to make room for pedestrians. But the sidewalks had never been about walking alone, and so in the process of creating an efficient transportation system, public officials, municipal engineers and the courts also enervated sidewalk life. ➢ 25 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 T OO M UCH C ONTROL When cities redefined sidewalks as transportation corridors, they also gave themselves another reason to control sidewalk life. Anything that impeded pedestrian circulation could be restricted or prohibited. Cities throughout the nation issued ordinances to regulate sidewalk activities including loitering, panhandling, street vending, public speaking, and expressions of political dissent. By the middle of the 20th century, urban sidewalks were used for fewer activities, and more people spent time in controlled environments like malls. And despite the recent popular and scholarly attention to walking, in a 2003 survey of the ten largest California cities, we found that public officials continued to deploy four strategies that devalued sidewalks as multi-use spaces. First, they de-emphasized sidewalks by developing sunken and raised plazas and elevated walkways. Second, they gentrified select sidewalk segments to make them attractive destinations with shopping, restaurants and bars while making few if any improvements to the remaining sidewalk network. Third, they privatized particular sidewalks through the designation of business improvement districts and by fencing and enclosing outdoor seating. And lastly, A C C E S S 26 cities sought to contain undesirable sidewalk activities they could not eliminate. We will discuss each of these strategies in turn. De-emphasis. In downtown and commercial areas, cities let (and sometimes encourage) developers of privately provided plazas and open spaces to use enclosing walls, blank facades, and entrances through parking structures, all of which separate their properties from public sidewalks. Cities nationwide have built underground and overhead spaces—sunken plazas and skywalks—to provide pedestrian circulation that avoids the street. In cities such as Minneapolis-St. Paul, Detroit, Boston and Cincinnati, skywalks link high-rise towers to a network of tunnels leading people from underground garages to office cubicles, allowing workers and visitors to move through the downtown without setting foot on public sidewalks. While initially meant to address harsh winters, skywalks also appear in cities with warm climates such as Dallas, Los Angeles, Miami, San Francisco, and Santa Cruz. Gentrification. In the last few decades, many municipalities have invested in historic districts and main streets to draw middle class residents and shoppers back to the city. Their efforts include upgrading the streetscape through a mix of public art, street furniture, and decorative lighting, renovating buildings, and converting old warehouses into trendy shops and restaurants. Cities have also enacted ordinances designating some “pedestrian-oriented” districts, and encouraging specific retail uses (cafes, bakeries, restaurants, flower shops, boutiques, bookstores, galleries, art shops) in these districts. Architectural and landscape design guidelines promote specific themes to retain or enhance an area’s historic character. The objective is to increase land value and overall economic viability. In the process, small, independent businesses such as nail salons, tattoo parlors and small food stores are often replaced by chain stores and upscale retailers. The new consumer orientation reflected in the higher prices and more upscale merchandise creates a subtle but effective screening mechanism and makes the sidewalks comfortable for only higher income populations. We must re-imagine sidewalks as Privatization. Many states have enabled Business Improvement Districts (BIDs) in which business owners tax themselves to augment public services or provide improvements for a designated district. Services offered by BIDs typically include sidewalk beautification, cleaning spaces that can and maintenance, and private security officers. BID security officers ensure that sidewalk activity is not disruptive to businesses. Some urban residents become nuisances if they do not fit the BID’s desired image for the neighborhood. Fencing a part of the sidewalk for outdoor seating is another form of privatization. Fences are boundaries that separate the privatized realm from public space. This might be required by accommodate both enjoyable ordinance, as is the case of California where state law stipulates that alcohol can be served only in enclosed and demarcated areas. While cafes can blend seamlessly into the city sidewalks, as they do in Paris, too often in the US hard boundaries privatize public space and thus preclude and disruptive different public uses. Containment. Who has access to which sidewalks is controversial. To contain undesirable uses, cities directly or indirectly sanction activities in one area to keep them out of another. Local activities. governments restrict prostitution to red light districts and homelessness to skid rows. Some cities have extended this logic to street vending, allowing it in some areas while prohibiting it in others. At times, cities have attempted to confine protest events and political speech to officially-approved protest zones. Some of the strategies above have helped empty public sidewalks of people and activities. Others have encouraged the use of sidewalks, but only by a subset of the population, and in doing so they make the sidewalk less public. ➢ 27 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 W HAT D O W E WANT ? F IVE P URPOSES OF S IDEWALKS Sidewalks will become more vibrant and desirable for walking if they can support five purposes: movement, encounter, confrontation, survival and beauty. To do this, we must re-imagine sidewalks as spaces that can accommodate both enjoyable and disruptive activities. Movement. Sidewalks are spaces for travel, so they must be designed and maintained to accommodate this activity well. Pedestrians need protection from the natural elements such as rain and sun. Sidewalks must be accessible to all people. Comfortably moving on foot, in a wheelchair, or with a cane or other walking device requires smooth pavement with adequate width and curb cuts. Street furniture such as benches and lighting make sidewalks safer, easier to navigate, and more comfortable for users who have different purposes and varying levels of physical stamina. Encounter. As spaces of encounter, sidewalks function best when a diverse range of people use them. On sidewalks, people can greet acquaintances, observe neighbors they have never met, and cross paths with strangers. Urban residents value some fleeting and public interactions, and urban encounters can make cities both intriguing and fun. Ordinary encounters like stopping to chat rarely interrupt traffic flow. Some events, however, override the functionality of streets and sidewalks by blocking traffic, and forcing people to stop, observe, or participate. Processions to celebrate civic, national, religious or secular holidays (such as the Cinco de Mayo, Chinese New Year, Fourth of July, Labor Day, Thanksgiving, Christmas, or Carnival) temporarily redefine the purpose of streets and sidewalks. Spontaneous and planned festivities break the rhythm of everyday life and give collective expression to people’s joy, sorrow or aspirations. Parades and other large events disrupt traffic and can make sidewalks impassable. Although they are not neutral events—they insert cultural practices, issues, and interests into public consciousness—they are often accepted because they are temporary. Confrontation. Some interactions and events are disruptive and intentionally confrontational. Nevertheless, we believe they should be accommodated on democratic sidewalks. Sit-ins and micropolitical acts, such as when African-Americans historically refused to step aside on the sidewalks, are important and protected forms of expression. But not all disruptions are A C C E S S 28 political. Talking loudly, gathering in groups, or even sitting on a stoop can violate local norms FURTHER READING and, through repetition, change an area’s character. Rallies and protests are political events that intentionally disrupt ordinary activities. Although most agree in the abstract that people need access to public space for political speech and events, the immediate effects of many political events irritate those whose trip or day is interrupted. Because unimpeded transportation has been defined as sidewalks’ primary purpose, cities have the authority to control the time, place and manner of such events to reduce their disruption. Survival. Some groups, such as the homeless, street vendors or youth lingering at sidewalk corners, may not intend to be disruptive yet still cause other people discomfort. Most activities that are associated with homelessness, for example, are common—sitting, talking, asking questions and sleeping—but they are perceived differently when the people doing the Nicholas Blomley. 2007. “Civil Rights Meets Civil Engineering: Urban Public Space and Traffic Logic,” Canadian Journal of Law and Society. 22(2):55–72. Nicholas Fyfe (Ed.). 1998. Images of the Street: Planning, Identity, and Control in Public Space. London: Routledge. Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Renia Ehrenfeucht. 2009. Sidewalks: Conflict and Negotiation over Public Space. Cambridge, MA and London, England: MIT Press. sitting, talking and sleeping appear to be homeless. Recent conflicts around street vending and day laboring sites have focused on immigrants, eliciting concern from long-term residents about neighborhood change. Although few would argue that anyone should be absolutely banned from sidewalks, many city councils have assumed that causing other people discomfort is sufficient harm to prohibit ordinar y activities. For some, however, sleeping, sitting or vending on sidewalks is a mechanism of daily or financial survival, and a rich mix of activities Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris, Evelyn Blumenberg and Renia Ehrenfeucht. 2005. “Sidewalk Democracy: Municipalities and the Regulation of Public Space.” In Eran Ben-Joseph and Terry Szwold, (Eds.), Regulating Place: Standards and the Shaping of Urban America. London: Routledge. contributes to urban vitality. Beauty. People like to be in beautiful spaces. Street trees are a way to beautify sidewalks and make them comfortable for walking or waiting for the bus. Trees and other green spaces also provide psychological benefits. In Chicago, residents in the Robert Taylor Homes publichousing development who lived in buildings surrounded by more trees and grass reported fewer incidences of aggressive behavior than those in buildings surrounded by less vegetation. Trees have additional benefits. Shade can decrease repaving costs (by reducing pavement fatigue, cracking, rutting, and other distress) and reduce energy costs to residents (by cooling houses and decreasing the need for air conditioning). Nonetheless, at times, street trees have been banned from long stretches of the sidewalk so as to not hinder the motorists’ vision. The urban forest is often a low priority for cities, and few funds are dedicated to maintaining healthy trees along sidewalks. R E - ENVISIONING S IDEWALKS Counterintuitive though it may seem, if we wish to encourage walking for transportation, we need to make sidewalks places for more than just movement. When sidewalks become both spaces for travel and spaces for living, where people play, stop to talk, vend or buy, and communicate, they become more interesting places to walk. The sidewalks’ draw, danger, and opportunity come from the same place: the people who make the public realm unpredictable, interesting, and democratic. In 1913, Charles Beard wrote that sidewalks “have been likened to the arteries through which flows the life-blood of the city—trade and traffic.” But he also maintained that sidewalks were more than that. “They are the meeting places of the people, the playgrounds of the children, the allurement to recreation, and vice. Here persons of all ages and tastes go to meet one another, to talk over the affairs of the day, to be entertained, to eat, to drink, to inspect shop windows, to do marketing, to buy and sell merchandise, and to perform a thousand offices which the exigencies of city life make profitable, healthful, or agreeable… The city sidewalks connect every household.” This vision did not last, but we may yet be able to recreate it. ◆ 29 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 Fixing Broken Sidewalks BY DONALD SHOUP Property has its duties as well as its rights. —Thomas Drummond P ublic infrastructure often decays invisibly, and we are shocked when a bridge gives way or a water main breaks. Sidewalks, however, decay right before our eyes and under our feet. Perhaps because sidewalks fail gradually rather than collapse spectacularly, many cities have neglected sidewalk repairs and have let neighborhoods become less walkable. In Los Angeles, for example, 4,600 of the city’s 10,750 miles of sidewalks need some degree of repair at an estimated cost of $1.2 billion. Despite this backlog, the city fixed an average of only 67 miles of sidewalks a year between 2000 and 2008. Even if sidewalks miraculously stopped breaking, at that pace it would take 69 years to repair all the existing damage. Donald Shoup, FAICP, is Professor of Urban Planning at the University of California, L os Angeles ([email protected]). A C C E S S 30 T HE A MERIC ANS WITH D IS ABILITIES A CT Broken sidewalks make the city less accessible, especially for the blind and those who use wheelchairs, canes, or walkers. Accessible sidewalks have emerged as an important legal issue since the US Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals ruled in 2002 that the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) applies to sidewalks. In 2003 the US Supreme Court declined to overturn the Ninth Circuit ruling. A class-action suit, Barden v. City of Sacramento, had alleged that Sacramento violated the ADA by allowing its sidewalks to fall into disrepair. The court ruled that the ADA covers “anything a public entity does” and any “normal function of a governmental entity.” To settle the case, Sacramento agreed to dedicate 20 percent of its annual transportation budget for up to 30 years to make public sidewalks accessible. Specifically, the settlement requires, “Changes of level of greater than ½ inch, whether caused by tree roots or any other deterioration or displacement of the surface of the Pedestrian Right of Way, will be remedied by providing a ramp with an appropriate slope or by creating a level path of travel.” Similar ADA lawsuits have since been filed against other cities, including Los Angeles. How will these cities find all the money needed to repair their sidewalks when they already face fiscal hard times? Some cities have adopted a new strategy that doesn’t cost the city anything: require owners to repair broken sidewalks before they sell their property. ➢ 31 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 W HO S HOULD PAY TO R EPAIR S IDEWALKS ? Requiring sidewalk repairs before sale will make the city more accessible, but critics may object that cities are simply shifting the responsibility for repairs onto property owners. In California, however, property owners are already responsible for sidewalks. California’s Streets and Highways Code states, “The owners of lots or portions of lots fronting on any portion of a public street shall maintain any sidewalk in such condition that the sidewalk will not endanger persons or property and maintain it in a condition which will not interfere with the public convenience.” Property owners also pay for sidewalk repairs in many other states. A survey of 82 cities in 45 states found that 40 percent of the cities require property owners to pay the full cost of repairing sidewalks, 46 percent share the cost with property owners, and only 13 percent pay the full cost of repairing sidewalks. Los Angeles followed the state code until 1973, when federal funds became available to repair sidewalks at no cost to property owners. Because of this federal funding, the city assumed responsibility for most sidewalk repairs. Three years later, when the federal funds ran out, Los Angeles was left with no sidewalk repair program. Then, in 1978, California voters adopted Proposition 13, which limited property tax rates, and public funds became even scarcer. By 1980, when the city attempted to reinstate the previous policy of citing property owners for damaged sidewalks and requiring them to pay for repairs, owners objected to the “new” mandate and the city halted citations. Because the city was short of money, it began to make only temporary asphalt patches to cracked sidewalks or—more often—did nothing at all. The resulting sidewalk decay led to the current state of serious disrepair. R EQUIRING S IDEWALK R EPAIRS AT THE P OINT OF S ALE How does a point-of-sale strategy work? Before any sale, the city inspects the sidewalk fronting the property. If the inspector finds that damage or displacement of the sidewalk creates an unsafe condition, the owner must pay to fix it before completing the sale. Piedmont, California, for example, requires, “New sidewalks and/or driveways must be constructed if required by the superintendent of streets . . . in conjunction with the sale of real property.” Piedmont’s ordinance mandates repairs if the vertical displacement of a break is ¾ of an inch or less, and reconstruction if the vertical displacement exceeds ¾ of an inch. Pasadena, California, has a similar at-sale sidewalk repair program. A C C E S S 32 Point-of-sale programs like those in Piedmont and Pasadena have several advantages beyond complying with the ADA. First, the city does not require owners to pay or do anything until they sell a property. The sale then provides the cash to pay for required repairs. Sellers fix only the sidewalk fronting their own property, so they can see exactly where their money is going. Second, sidewalk repairs are gradual but inevitable because about half of all properties are sold at least once every decade. The property turnover rate is similar throughout most cities, so the sidewalks are repaired everywhere in a city at roughly the same rate. Third, sidewalk repairs can increase a property’s “curb appeal” and thus increase its market value. A property’s value will increase not only because of its own sidewalk repairs but also because of all other nearby repairs. Everyone can benefit if property owners accept the obligation to repair their own sidewalks before selling their property. Fourth, the city does not have to raise taxes to pay for sidewalk repairs. The city even saves money because of fewer trip-and-fall lawsuits. Among claims against the city for trip-and-fall incidents on Los Angeles sidewalks between 2001 and 2007, 36 percent of the incidents occurred in front of properties that had been sold within the previous five years. Los Angeles paid $1.4 million to settle the claims for these incidents, which were preventable unless the sidewalks cracked in the five years between the last property sale and the trip-and-fall incident. Finally, sellers include absentee owners and residents who are leaving the city. Their sidewalk repairs will leave the city in better shape for everyone who remains. H OW D OES A P OINT- OF -S ALE P ROGRAM W ORK ? To manage a point-of-sale program, a city can require that the escrow documents at sale include a certificate of compliance with the sidewalk ordinance. The process starts when an owner requests the city to inspect a sidewalk. If the sidewalk is in good repair, the inspector issues a compliance certificate. If the sidewalk is damaged, however, the inspector estimates what the city would charge to repair it. The owner has several options at that point. First, the owner can pay the city to repair the sidewalk. The inspector then issues a compliance certificate and the city makes the repairs. Second, the owner can accept a lien on the property for the estimated cost of the repairs. The inspector then issues a compliance certificate and the city makes the repairs; the city is repaid for the lien plus accrued interest at sale. Finally, the owner can choose to have a private contractor perform the work. In that case, the owner or contractor requests a permit and completes the work; the city inspects the work, and if it is satisfactory the inspector issues a compliance certificate. ➢ 33 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 If the next owner intends to redevelop the property, repairing the sidewalk at sale may be premature. In this case, the city can allow the seller to shift the responsibility for repairs to the buyer. The city can inspect the property at the end of a specific time period after the sale (such as one year), and cite the new owner if the required repairs have not been completed. Piedmont charges $30 for issuing a certificate of compliance, which is the city’s estimated cost of making the inspection. The inspectors can enter the records into a geographic database that shows the condition of sidewalks throughout the city. The point-of-sale program can be part of the city’s plan to make its public sidewalks accessible, and the point-of-sale database will show the city’s progress toward meeting the plan’s goals. Condominiums present a potential hitch in the process. Who would be liable for sidewalk repairs when a unit is sold—the unit’s owner or the condominium association? One solution is to exempt individual units but require condominium associations to repair their sidewalks within a specified time after the ordinance is adopted, with periodic inspections to ensure continued compliance. A C C E S S 34 M ICRO -L OANS FOR P UBLIC I NVESTMENTS Sidewalk repairs in Los Angeles typically cost between $1,000 and $1,500. If owners pay the city before it makes the repairs, the city will have idle funds to invest between the payments and the repairs. A city can also go beyond the basic point-of-sale plan by offering to repair sidewalks before sale and receive payment at sale. The city will, in effect, lend owners the money to pay for sidewalk repairs for as long as they continue to own the property. Owners can repay all or part of the debt before they sell the property, and any remaining debt is due at sale. If owners pay a market interest rate on the debt, the government loses nothing by accelerating the repairs. Some cities already allow property owners to defer paying special assessments, with interest, until they sell their property. This option to pay at sale has several benefits. First, Cash from the sale gives the program increases public investment without any public subsidy. The city runs little risk of borrowers’ defaulting on the debt for sidewalk repairs because cash is available from the sale of the property when the debt is due. A public lien is senior to any mortgage, so even owners the if property values decline and the owner has no equity, the city will be repaid in full. Where land values are high, and sidewalk improvements increase them further, most owners will have more than sufficient equity to repay the cost of repairs, plus accrued interest, at sale. ability to pay. Owners who wish to avoid the interest expense can always opt to repay the debt before sale. Second, deferring payments until sale has a strong political advantage. Finding the cash to repair the sidewalk before sale could be difficult for many owners, but allowing owners to pay at sale will eliminate any cash-flow problem. Cash from the sale gives owners the ability to pay. Elected officials can thus vote for a point-of-sale requirement with a clear conscience. Third, the deferment option will allow the city to cite property owners whose severely damaged sidewalks create an immediate danger to pedestrians. Requiring prompt repairs in these cases will increase public safety, remove barriers to persons with disabilities, and reduce claims from trip-and-fall lawsuits without creating a financial hardship for either property owners or the city. Fourth, the requirement to repair at sale, combined with the ability to delay payment until sale, may spur some owners to make repairs as soon as a sidewalk breaks. They may repair early because (a) they want the safe sidewalk they will eventually have to provide anyway, (b) they expect repairs will be more expensive later, (c) they want to avoid trip-andfall injuries, and/or (d) they want to increase their property value. T HE S PEED OF R EPAIRS How fast will a point-of-sale program repair a city’s sidewalks? How long will it take, for example, before half the broken sidewalks have been repaired? We can answer this question by examining the history of property sales in a city. I used data from the Los Angeles County Assessor to find the last sale date for every property in the City of Los Angeles. Half of the 768,922 properties in the city changed ownership at least once between January 1, 1995 and December 31, 2006. If sidewalks fronting the sold properties are as likely to need repair as sidewalks fronting all properties, a point-of-sale program adopted at the beginning of 1995 would have repaired half the city’s broken sidewalks in 12 years, much faster than the current pace of repairs. ➢ 35 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 P UT TING C ITIES B ACK ON T HEIR F EET In 2002, the US Ninth Circuit Court ruled that the ADA applies to public sidewalks. As a result, cities must develop transition plans to ensure that their sidewalks are accessible. In this case, as in many others, what is good for people with disabilities—repairing broken sidewalks—is also good for everyone else. The ADA will force cities to do what they should be doing anyway: maintain their public infrastructure. To ensure a steady flow of sidewalk improvements, cities can require property owners to fix their sidewalks when they sell their property. Before any real estate is sold, the city will inspect the sidewalk fronting the property. If the sidewalk is in good condition, the owner will not be required to do anything. If the sidewalk is broken, the city will require the owner to repair it before selling the property and the owner can put off paying for the repairs until sale. Deferring the obligation to fix sidewalks until sale will help gain voters’ approval, and enforcing the obligation at sale will help ensure owners’ compliance, both of which will contribute to a successful program. Only property owners with broken sidewalks will pay anything, they will pay only for the cost of repairing their own sidewalks, and they will not have to pay until they sell their property. Because about half the city’s broken sidewalks will be repaired each decade, all residents will be able to say, in the words of Danish urban designer Jan Gehl, “How nice it is to wake up every morning and know that your city is a little better than it was the day before.” A better world often arrives in small steps, but we need reasons to take these steps. With a point-of-sale program, all property owners will have to do their part, sooner or later. Walkable cities need good sidewalks, and requiring sidewalk repairs at sale will help put cities back on their feet. ◆ This article is abridged from a forthcoming publication in the Journal of Urban Planning and Development, with permission from the American Society of Civil Engineers. F U RTHER READING Class Action Settlement Agreement, Barden v. City of Sacramento. 2002. (www.dralegal.org/downloads/cases/barden/settlement.pdf). Donald Shoup. 1994. “Is Underinvestment in Public Infrastructure an Anomaly?” in Gareth Jones and Peter Ward (eds.), Methodology for Land and Housing Market Analysis, London: UCL Press, pp. 236–250. (www.sppsr.ucla.edu//dup/people/faculty/shoup/IsUnder-investment.pdf). Donald Shoup. 1996. “Regulating Land Use at Sale,” Journal of the American Planning Association, vol. 62, no. 3, Summer, pp. 354–372. (http://shoup.bol.ucla.edu/Regulation_at_Sale.pdf). Donald Shoup. 2010. “Putting Cities Back on Their Feet,” Journal of Urban Planning and Development. vol. 136, no. 3, September. A C C E S S 36 R E C E N T P A P E R S I N P R I N T All papers are availa b le a t w w w. uc tc .net /r es e a r ch/f a c ult y p a p ers .s html . Faculty research papers 2010 Sangkapichai Mana, Jean-Daniel Saphores, Oladele Ogunseitan, Stephen Ritchie, Soyoung (Iris) You, and Gunwoo Lee An Analysis of the Health Impacts from PM and NOx Emissions Resulting from Train Operations in the Alameda Corridor, CA. March 2010 Roberto Ayala, Soyoung (Iris) You, Jean-Daniel Saphores, Stephen Ritchie, Gunwoo Lee, and Mana Sangkapichai A Preliminary Analysis of the Environmental Impacts of the Clean Truck Program in the Alameda Corridor, CA. March 2010 Gunwoo Lee, Soyoung (Iris) You, Mana Sangkapichai, Stephen G. Ritchie, Jean-Daniel Saphores, Oladele Ogunseitan, Roberto Ayala, R. Jayakrishnan, and Rodolfo Torres Assessing the Environmental and Health Impacts of PortRelated Freight Movement in a Major Urban Transportation Corridor. March 2010 Soyoung (Iris) You, Gunwoo Lee, Stephen G. Ritchie, Jean-Daniel Saphores, Mana Sangkapichai, and Roberto Ayala Air Pollution Impacts of Shifting San Pedro Bay Ports Freight from Truck to Rail in Southern California. March 2010 Phillip Li Estimation of Sample Selection Models with Two Selection Mechanisms. March 2010 Jinwon Kim and David Brownstone The Impact of Residential Density on Vehicle Usage and Fuel Consumption. March 2010 David Brownstone and Hao (Audrey) Fang A Vehicle Ownership and Utilization Choice Model with Endogenous Residential Density. March 2010 Michael Manville and Donald Shoup Parking Requirements as a Barrier to Housing Development: Regulation and Reform in Los Angeles. March 2010 Tingting Cui, Yanfeng Ouyang, and Zuo-Jun Max Shen Reliable Facility Location Design under the Risk of Disruptions. February 2010 Shadi B. Anani and Samer M. Madanat, Estimation of Highway Maintenance Marginal Cost under Multiple Maintenance Activities. February 2010 Monica Altmaier, Elisa Barbour, Christian Eggleton, Jeffier Gage, Jason Hayter, and Ayrin Zahner Make It Work: Implementing SB 375. Fall 2009 Nikolas Geroliminis and Carlos F. Daganzo Existence of Urban-Scale Macroscopic Fundamental Diagrams: Some Experimental Findings. Fall 2009 Dev E. Millstein and Robert A. Harley Effects of an Accelerated Diesel Engine Replacement/Retrofit Program. Fall 2009 Jacqueline Leavitt and Gar y Blasi The Los Angeles Taxi Workers Alliance. Fall 2009 Evelyn Blumenberg and Michael Smart Travel In the ’Hood: Ethnic Neighborhoods and Mode Choice. Fall 2009 Paul M. Ong Measuring Travel Behavior of Low-Income Households Using GPS-Enabled Cell Phones; Multimodal Monitoring with Integrated GPS, Diary and Prompted Recall Methods. Fall 2009 Seo Young Yoon and Konstadinos Goulias Constraint-based Assessment of Intra-Household Bargaining on Time Allocation to Activities and Travel Using Individual Accessibility Measures. Fall 2009 Kate Deutsch and Konstadinos Goulias Exploring Sense of Place Attitudes as Indicators of Travel Behavior. Fall 2009 Evelyn Blumenberg Moving In and Moving Around: Immigrants, Travel Behavior, and Implications for Transport Policy. Fall 2009 2009 Ricard Gil and Justin Marion The Role of Repeated Interactions, Self-Enforcing Agreements and Relational [Sub]Contracting: Evidence from California Highway Procurement Auctions. Fall 2009 37 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 R E C E N T P A P E Kate Deutsch and Konstadinos Goulias Investigating the Impact of Sense of Place on Travel Behavior Using an Intercept Survey Methodology. Fall 2009 Megan Smirti and Mark Hansen Capturing the Impact of Fuel Price on Jet Aircraft Operating Costs with Engineering and Econometric Models (revised). Summer 2009 Marlon G. Boarnet, Rufus Edwards, Marko Princevac, Jun Wu, Hansheng Pan, Christian Bartolome, Gavin Ferguson, Anahita Fazl, and Raul Lejano Near-Source Modeling of Transportation Emissions in Built Environments Surrounding Major Arterials. Summer 2009 Megan Smirti and Mark Hansen The Potential of Turboprops to Reduce Aviation Fuel Consumption. Summer 2009 Robert Cer vero, Arlie Adkins, and Cathleen Sullivan Are TODs Over-Parked? Summer 2009 Megan Smirti and Mark Hansen Assessing the Role of Operating, Passenger, and Infrastructure Costs in Fleet Planning under Fuel Price Uncertainty. Summer 2009 Erin Machell, Troy Reinhalter, and Karen Chapple Building Support for TransitOriented Development: Do Community-Engagement Toolkits Work? Summer 2009 B R S I N P R I N T Greg Marsden, Karen T. Frick, Anthony D. May and Elizabeth Deakin Good Practice in the Exploitation of Innovative Strategies in Sustainable Urban Transport: City Interview Synthesis. Summer 2009 Chris Ganson The Transportation Greenhouse Gas Inventory: A First Step toward City-Driven Emissions Rationalization. Spring 2009 Joshua Michael Pilachowski An Approach to Reducing Bus Bunching. UC Berkeley, 2009 Elliot William Martin, New Vehicle Choice, Fuel Economy and Vehicle Incentives: An Analysis of Hybrid Tax Credits and the Gasoline Tax. UC Berkeley, 2009 Dissertations David Andrew King Exploring the Localization of Transportation Planning: Essays on Research and Policy Implications from Shifting Goals in Transportation Planning. UC Los Angeles, 2009 Stella Kin-Mang So Managing City Evacuations. UC Berkeley, 2010 Policy Briefs Gian-Claudia Sciara Planners and the Pork Barrel: Metropolitan Engagement in and Resistance to Congressional Transportation Earmarking. UC Berkeley, 2009 The Price of Unwanted Parking. Re-pricing Highway Pavement Deterioration. Are TOD’s Over-Parked? O O K S Please contact the publishe r s f o r i nf o rma t io n a b o ut the b oo ks li s t ed he re . Boarnet, Marlon and Randall Crane Travel by Design: The Influence of Urban Form on Travel (Oxford University Press, 2001) Garrison, William L., and David Levinson The Transportation Experience: Policy, Planning, and Deployment (Oxford University Press, 2005) Hall, Peter Geoffrey Cities of Tomorrow: An Intellectual History of Urban Planning and Design in the Twentieth Century (Blackwell Publishers, 2002) A C C E S S 38 Jacobs, Allan B., Elizabeth S. Macdonald, and Yodan Y. Rofé The Boulevard Book: History, Evolution, Design of Multi-Way Boulevards (MIT Press, 2002) Shoup, Donald C. The High Cost of Free Parking (Planner’s Press, 2005) Loukaitou-Sideris, Anastasia and Renia Ehrenfeucht Sidewalks: Conflict and Negotiation over Public Space. (MIT Press, 2009) Sperling, Daniel and James Cannon, eds. Driving Climate Change: Cutting Carbon from Transportation (Elsevier Academic Press, 2006) Shoup, Donald C. Parking Cash Out (Planning Advisory Service, 2005) Sperling, Daniel and James Cannon, eds. The Hydrogen Energy Transition: Moving Toward the Post Petroleum Age in Transportation (Elsevier Academic Press, 2004) Sperling, Daniel and Deborah Gordon Two Billion Cars: Driving Toward Sustainability (Oxford University Press, 2009) A C C E S S B A C K I S S U E S ACCES S 1, FALL 1992 ACCESS 4, SPRING 1994 ACCESS 7, FAL L 1 99 5 ACCES S 1 0 , S PRI NG 1 99 7 ACCES S 1 3 , FAL L 19 9 8 ACCES S 1 7 , FAL L 2 0 0 0 Introduction Melvin M. Webber Introduction Melvin M. Webber Introduction Luci Yamamoto Director’s Comment Martin Wachs Nonconventional Research Melvin M. Webber Autonomous Decongestants Melvin M. Webber Cars and Demographics Charles Lave Time Again for Rail? Peter Hall The High Cost of Free Parking Donald C. Shoup Congress Okays Cash Out Donald C. Shoup Brooklyn’s Boulevards Elizabeth Macdonald Compulsory Ridesharing in Los Angeles Martin Wachs and Genevieve Giuliano No Rush to Catch the Train Adib Kanafani The TransportationLand Use Connection Still Matters Robert Cervero and John D. Landis Dividing the Federal Pie Lewison Lee Lem Global Transportation Wilfred Owen A Question of Timing Rosella Picado New Highways and Economic Growth: Rethinking the Link Marlon G. Boarnet Can Welfare Recipients Afford to Work Far From Home? Evelyn Blumenberg Taxing Foreigners Living Abroad David Levinson Redundancy: The Lesson from the Loma Prieta Earthquake Melvin M. Webber Will Congestion Pricing Ever Be Adopted? Martin Wachs Taking Turns: Rx for Congestion Carlos Daganzo Cashing in on Curb Parking Donald C. Shoup Environmentally Benign Automobiles Daniel Sperling, et al. Reviving Transit Corridors and Transit Riding Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris Do New Highways Generate Traffic? Mark Hansen Telecommunication vs. Transportation Pnina Ohanna Plaut Pavement Friendly Buses and Trucks J. Karl Hedrick, et al. THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Love, Lies, and Transportation in LA Charles Lave Higher Speed Limits May Save Lives Charles Lave Why Don’t You Telecommute? Ilan Salomon and Patricia L. Mokhtarian Is Oxygen Enough? Robert Harley THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Speed Limits Raised, Fatalities Fall Charles Lave Commuter Stress Raymond W. Novaco ACCESS 8, SPRI NG 19 9 6 ACCESS 5, FALL 199 4 ACCES S 2, SPRING 1993* Preface Melvin M. Webber Introduction Lydia Chen Cashing Out Employer-Paid Parking Donald C. Shoup Highway Blues: Nothing a Little Accessibility Can’t Cure Susan Handy Congestion Pricing: New Life for an Old Idea? Kenneth A. Small Transit Villages: From Idea to Implementation Robert Cervero Private Toll Roads in America—The First Time Around Daniel B. Klein A New Tool for Land Use and Transportation Planning John D. Landis Investigating Toll Roads in California Gordon J. Fielding Telecommuting: What’s the Payoff? Patricia L. Mokhtarian Surviving in the Suburbs: Transit’s Untapped Frontier Robert Cervero ACCES S 3, FALL 1993 Introduction Melvin M. Webber Clean for a Day: California Versus the EPA’s Smog Check Mandate Charles Lave Southern California: The Detroit of Electric Cars? Allen J. Scott The Promise of Fuel-Cell Vehicles Mark Delucchi and David Swan Great Streets: Monument Avenue, Richmond, Virginia Allan B. Jacobs Why California Stopped Building Freeways Brian D. Taylor THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Trends in Our Times Charles Lave *Out of print; photocopies available. It Wasn’t Supposed to Turn Out Like This: Federal Subsidies and Declining Transit Productivity Charles Lave The Marriage of Autos and Transit: How to Make Transit Popular Again Melvin M. Webber THE ACCESS ALMANAC: The CAFE Standards Worked Amihai Glazer ACCESS 6, SPRING 1995 Introduction Lydia Chen The Weakening Transportation-Land Use Connection Genevieve Giuliano Bringing Electric Cars to Market Daniel Sperling Who Will Buy Electric Cars? Thomas Turrentine Are HOV Lanes Really Better? Joy Dahlgren THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Slowdown Ahead for the Domestic Auto Industry Charles Lave Introduction Luci Yamamoto ACCES S 1 1 , FAL L 19 9 7 Parking and Affordable Housing Wenyu Jia and Martin Wachs Lost Riders Brian D. Taylor and William S. McCullough The Road Ahead: Managing Pavements Samer Madanat ACCES S 1 4 , SPRI NG 1 99 9 The Land Use/Transportation Connection (cont’d) Melvin M. Webber Middle Age Sprawl: BART and Urban Development John D. Landis and Robert Cervero Free to Cruise: Creating Curb Space for Jitneys Daniel B. Klein, Adrian T. Moore, and Binyam Reja Director’s Comment Martin Wachs Access to Choice Jonathan Levine A New Agenda Daniel Sperling Total Cost of Motor-Vehicle Use Mark A. Delucchi Hot Lanes: Introducing Congestion Pricing One Lane at a Time Gordon J. Fielding and Daniel B. Klein Splitting the Ties: The Privatization of British Rail José A. Gómez-Ibáñez Are Americans Really Driving So Much More? Charles Lave SmartMaps for Public Transit Michael Southworth Decision-Making After Disasters: Responding to the Northridge Earthquake Martin Wachs and Nabil Kamel THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Autos Save Energy Sharon Sarmiento ACCESS 9, FAL L 1 99 6 Introduction Luci Yamamoto There’s No There There: Or Why Neighborhoods Don’t Readily Develop Near Light-Rail Transit Stations Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Tridib Banerjee The Century Freeway: Design by Court Decree Joseph DiMento, Drusilla van Hengel, and Sherry Ryan Transit Villages: Tools For Revitalizing the Inner City Michael Bernick Food Access for the Transit-Dependent Robert Gottlieb and Andrew Fisher The Full Cost of Intercity Travel David Levinson The Freeway’s Guardian Angels Robert L. Bertini THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Travel by Carless Households Richard Crepeau and Charles Lave Objects in Mirror Are Closer Than They Appear Theodore E. Cohn Balancing Act: Traveling in the California Corridor Adib Kanafani THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Gas Tax Dilemma Mary Hill, Brian Taylor, and Martin Wachs Does Contracting Transit Service Save Money? William S. McCullough, Brian D. Taylor, and Martin Wachs ACCES S 1 5 , FAL L 19 9 9 Tracking Accessibility Robert Cervero THE ACCESS ALMANAC: The Pedigree of a Statistic Donald C. Shoup ACCES S 1 2 , S PRI NG 1 99 8 Traditions and Neotraditions Melvin M. Webber Travel by Design? Randall Crane Traditional Shopping Centers Ruth L. Steiner Simulating Highway and Transit Effects John D. Landis Cars for the Poor Katherine M. O’Regan and John M. Quigley Will Electronic Home Shopping Reduce Travel? Jane Gould and Thomas F. Golob What Can a Trucker Do? Amelia Regan THE ACCESS ALMANAC: The Parking of Nations Donald Shoup and Seth Stark ACCES S 1 8 , S PRING 2 0 0 1 Sustainability Melvin M. Webber R&D Partnership for the Next Cars Daniel Sperling How Federal Subsidies Shape Local Transit Choices Jianling Li and Martin Wachs Informal Transit: Learning from the Developing World Robert Cervero The Value of Value Pricing Kenneth A. Small Eclecticism Melvin M. Webber Requiem for Potholes Carl Monismith as told to Melanie Curry Instead of Free Parking Donald Shoup Partners in Transit Eugene Bardach, Timothy Deal, and Mary Walther Pooled Cars Susan Shaheen Why Bicyclists Hate Stop Signs Joel Fajans and Melanie Curry THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Census Undercount Paul Ong ACCES S 1 9 , FAL L 2 0 0 1 Transportation and the Environment Elizabeth A. Deakin A New CAFE Charles Lave Reconsider the Gas Tax: Paying for What You Get Jeffrey Brown Travel for the Fun of It Patricia L. Mokhtarian and Ilan Salomon ACCES S 1 6 , SPRI NG 2 00 0 Surprises Melanie Curry What If Cars Could Drive Themselves? Steven E. Shladover Power From the Fuel Cell Timothy E. Lipman Should We Try to Get the Prices Right? Mark Delucchi Clean Diesel: Overcoming Noxious Fumes Christie-Joy Brodrick, Daniel Sperling, and Harry A. Dwyer High-Speed Rail Comes to London Sir Peter Hall THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Unlimited Access: Prepaid Transit at Universities Jeffrey Brown, Daniel Baldwin Hess, and Donald Shoup An Eye on the Fast Lane: Making Freeway Systems Work Pravin Varaiya On Bus-Stop Crime Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Robin Liggett 39 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 A C S S B A C K I S S U E S ACCESS 23, FALL 2003 ACCESS 26, S PRI NG 2 00 5 ACCESS 2 9, FALL 200 6 ACCES S 3 0 , S PRI NG 2 0 0 7 ACCES S 3 3 , FAL L 2 0 0 8 Nobel Prize Melvin M. Webber University of California Transportation Center: 15 Years of Accomplishment Elizabeth A. Deakin Earmarking Threatens University Research Martin Wachs and Ann Brach Paying for Roads: New Technology for an Old Dilemma Paul Sorensen and Brian Taylor We’re All Transportation Planners Melanie Curry Change Happens Melanie Curry Transportation Planning as an Integral Part of Urban Development: The Emerging Paradigm Elizabeth A. Deakin Reforming Infrastructure Planning David Dowall In the Dark: Seeing Bikes at Night Karen De Valois, Tatsuto Takeuchi, and Michael Disch Roughly Right or Precisely Wrong Donald Shoup Transforming the Freight Industry: From Regulation to Competition to Decentralization in the Information Age Amelia Regan THE ACCESS ALMANAC: The Freeway-Congestion Paradox Chao Chen and Pravin Varaiya Turning Small Change Into Big Changes Douglas Kolozsvari and Donald Shoup Older Drivers: Should We Test Them Off the Road? Sandi Rosenbloom As Jobs Sprawl, Whither the Commute? Randall Crane and Daniel G. Chatman Driving Less Susan Handy Trends and Policy Choices: A Research Agenda Elizabeth A. Deakin THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Transportation Costs and Economic Opportunity Among the Poor Evelyn Blumenberg ACCESS 24, SPRING 2 004 ACCES S 21, FALL 2002 No Lying Game Luci Yamamoto Spread-City Everywhere Melvin M. Webber Brazil’s Buses: Simply Successful Aaron Golub Are SUVs Really Safer Than Cars? Tom Wenzel and Marc Ross Rethinking Traffic Congestion Brian D. Taylor Motorizing the Developing World Daniel Sperling and Eileen Claussen On the Back of the Bus Theodore E. Cohn Keeping Children Safe in Cars Jill Cooper Location Matters Markus Hesse Scrapping Old Cars Jennifer Dill Complications at Off-ramps Michael Cassidy Reconsidering the Cul-de-sac Michael Southworth and Eran Ben-Joseph THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Travel Patterns Among Welfare Recipients Paul Ong and Douglas Houston ACCESS 25, FALL 2004 ACCES S 22, SPRING 2003 Shuttles for the First and Last Mile Elizabeth A. Deakin Obsolescence Named Progress William L. Garrison People, Parking, and Cities Michael Manville and Donald Shoup Putting Pleasure Back in the Drive: Reclaiming Urban Parkways for the 21st Century Anastasia Loukaitou-Sideris and Robert Gottlieb The Price of Regulation Daniel Sperling Local Option Transportation Taxes: Devolution as Revolution Martin Wachs The Private Sector’s Role in Highway Finance: Lessons from SR 91 Marlon G. Boarnet and Joseph F. DiMento Ports, Boats, and Automobiles Peter V. Hall Are Induced-Travel Studies Inducing Bad Investments? Robert Cervero Why Traffic Congestion Is Here to Stay . . . and Will Get Worse Anthony Downs THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Auto Insurance Redlining in the Inner City Paul Ong Making Communities Safe for Bicycles Gian-Claudia Sciara C E ACCES S 20, SPRING 2002 The Path to Discrete-Choice Models Daniel L. McFadden A C C E S S 40 Unnoticed Lessons from London: Road Pricing and Public Transit Kenneth A. Small Which Comes First: The Neighborhood or the Walking? Susan Handy and Patricia Mokhtarian Discounting Transit Passes Cornelius Nuworsoo Economic Consequences of Transport Improvements T.R. Lakshmanan and Lata R. Chatterjee ACCESS 27, FAL L 20 0 5 In Praise of Diversity Paul Craig What We’ve Learned About Highway Congestion Pravin Varaiya The Transition to Hydrogen Joan Ogden Hydrogen Highways Timothy Lipman Progressive Transport and the Poor: Bogotá’s Bold Steps Forward Robert Cervero Innovations in Travel Modeling Frank S. Koppelman ACCESS 28, S PRI NG 2 00 6 Terrorist Attacks and Transport Systems Brian D. Taylor Building a Boulevard Elizabeth Macdonald Must a Bridge Be Beautiful Too? Matthew Dresden How Privatization Became a Train Wreck Eric A. Morris Transit and Contracts: What’s Best for Drivers? Songju Kim and Martin Wachs THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Floating Cars Daniel Baldwin Hess Dispatch from London John D. Landis Asilomar Declaration on Climate Policy Daniel Sperling Down to the Meter: Localized Vehicle Pollution Matters Douglas Houston, Jun Wu, Paul Ong, and Arthur Winer Stuck at Home: When Driving Isn’t a Choice Annie Decker From Horse Power to Horsepower Eric A. Morris Beyond the Automobile? Sir Peter Hall Cruising for Parking Donald Shoup Multimodal Transportation in California: Connecting Planes, Trains, and Automobiles Adib Kanafani Dispatch from Sydney: Transport in the Land of Oz John Landis Planning Water Use in California William Eisenstein and G. Mathias Kondolf SPECIAL ISSUE, WINTER 2006–07 THE ACCESS ALMANAC: The Incredible Shrinking Energy R&D Budget Daniel M. Kammen and Gregory F. Nemet Integrating Infrastructure Planning: The Role of Schools Deborah McKoy, Jeff Vincent, and Carrie Makarewicz Mel Webber: 1920 – 2006 Melanie Curry ACCES S 3 1 , FAL L 2 0 0 7 A Legacy of Skepticism: Remembering Mel Webber Martin Wachs Flexible Transit, the American City, and Mel Webber Robert Cervero Skeptical Optimism in Transportation and Planning Research Brian D. Taylor Melvin M. Webber: Maker and Breaker of Planning Paradigms Sir Peter Hall Teaching with Mel Elizabeth Deakin Learning from Mel Jonathan Richmond Urgent Action Required Melanie Curry For Whom the Road Tolls: The Politics of Congestion Pricing David King, Michael Manville, and Donald Shoup If Cars Were More Efficient, Would We Use Less Fuel? Kenneth A. Small and Kurt Van Dender Fuel Economy: What Drives Consumer Choice? Tom Turrentine, Kenneth Kurani, and Rusty Heffner The Intersection of Trees and Safety Elizabeth Macdonald Melvin Webber and the “Nonplace Urban Realm” Michael B. Teitz Smarter Parking at Transit Stations Susan Shaheen and Charlene Kemmerer Beyond ITS and the Transportation Monoculture Daniel Sperling ACCES S 3 2 , S PRI NG 2 0 0 8 The Mel Webber Index THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Love, Lies, and Transportation in LA, Again Charles Lave California’s Growth: An Uncertain Future Michael B. Teitz California Futures: Accommodating Growth in an Era of Climate Change and Rising Fuel Prices Elizabeth Deakin The Challenge of Urban Transportation in California Elizabeth Deakin and Robert Cervero A Strategy for Infrastructure: The California Infrastructure Initiative David E. Dowall and Robin Ried California’s Housing Problem Cynthia Kroll and Krute Singa Transportation Infrastructure and Sustainable Development: New Planning Approaches for Urban Growth Marlon G. Boarnet ACCES S 3 4 , SPRI NG 2 0 0 9 Transportation Technologies for the 21st Century Elizabeth Deakin Saving Fuel, Reducing Emissions: Making Plug-In Hybrid Electric Vehicles Cost-Effective Daniel M. Kammen, Samuel M. Arons, Derek M. Lemoine, and Holmes Hummel Moving Forward With Fuel Economy Standards Lee Schipper Transforming the Oil Industry into the Energy Industry Daniel Sperling and Sonia Yeh Intelligent Transport Systems: Linking Technology and Transport Policy to Help Steer the Future Elizabeth Deakin, Karen Trapenberg Frick, and Alexander Skabardonis ACCES S 3 5 , FAL L 2 0 1 0 Access moves to LA Michael Manville Traffic Congestion and Greenhouse Gases Matthew Barth and Kanok Boriboonsomsin Airport Congestion Management: Prices or Quantities? Jan Brueckner Moving Los Angeles Paul Sorensen TOD and Carsharing: A Natural Marriage Robert Cervero Paved With Good Intentions: Fiscal Politics, Freeways, and the 20th Century American City Jeffrey Brown, Eric A. Morris, and Brian Taylor O UCTC # R D E R F O AUTHOR R M TITLE ACCESS NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 UCTC Director Robert Cer vero Editor Donald Shoup Associate Editor Michael Manville Design Mitche Manitou Try our website first: Most papers are available for downloading (www.uctc.net) N A M E __________________________________________________________________________________________ ADDRESS _____________________________________________________________________________________ Access Editorial Board Elizabeth A. Deakin Robert Cer vero Donald Shoup Brian Taylor Amelia Regan __________________________________________________________________________________________________ PHONE ________________________________________________________________________________________ E M A I L _________________________________________________________________________________________ Send to: Publications, University of California Transportation Center 2614 Dwight Way, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720–1782 Fax: (510) 643-5456 Email: [email protected] PHOTO CREDITS pp. 10–11, 30–36: Donald Shoup Subscriptions to ACCESS To receive email notifications for issues of ACCESS, please send an email to [email protected]. We will send you a message with a digest of each issue's articles and a link to the online edition when the issue is published. To receive a subscription to hard copies of ACCESS, please send an email with your name and postal address to [email protected]. Hard copies of ACCESS are mailed only to domestic US addresses.. Or visit the ACCESS page on the website: http://www.uctc.net/access/ A D D R E S S C O R R E C T I O N If your mailing address on the back cover is incorrect, please provide the correct address in the space provided AND either print the incorrect address below or cut it out from the back cover and affix below. OL D ADDR ESS: NAM E _________________________________________________________________________________________ ADDRES S _____________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________________ University of California Transportation Center V I S I T O U R W E B S I T E AT www.uctc.net Printed on recycled paper 41 A C C E S S NUMBER 36, SPRING 2010 N O N - P R O F I T O R G A N I Z AT I O N U . S . P O S TA G E PA I D UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA T R A N S P O R TAT I O N C E N T E R B E R K E L E Y, C A 9 4 7 2 0 – 1 7 8 2 ADDRESS SERVICE REQUESTED UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA