The Journal of Asian Studies Vol. 69, No. 4 (November) 2010: 963–983.
© The Association for Asian Studies, Inc., 2010 doi:10.1017/S0021911810002858
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
PRASENJIT DUARA
ASIA APPEARED as a region and been conceived as such in the last
hundred years? While there is a long-standing and still burgeoning historiography of Asian connections through the study of the precolonial and early
modern maritime trade, the nineteenth and twentieth centuries are generally
not seen as a time of growing Asian connections. The recent rise of interest in
Asian connections in the current time is thus unable to grasp the continuities
and discontinuities that form the present. Even more, it is unable to evaluate
the risks and possibilities of the present moment.
Before launching upon the subject, we need to question how, where, and why
a region appears. I will approach this question from the perspective of historical
sociology. Scholars have made a useful distinction between a region and regionalization, distinguishing between the relatively unplanned or evolutionary emergence of an area of interaction and interdependence as a “region,” and the
more active, often ideologically driven political process of creating a region, or
“regionalization.”
While understanding the history of the concept of the Asian region requires
us to utilize both of these conceptions and their complex interactions, I believe
that there is a more fundamental issue underlying why regions and regionalisms
succeed or fail, and also why they take the shape they do, as few will argue that
the Asian region reflects a cartographic representation of Asia. After all, Asia was
merely the name of the area east of the Greek ecumene in ancient times.
I hypothesize that regions and regionalizations tend to follow the dominant or
hegemonic modes of spatial production during a period. For the twentieth
century, the paradigm of large-scale production of social space was the territorial
nation-state under conditions of global capitalist production and exchange. Note
that this way of formulating the problem may also incorporate the socialist
nation-state, which sought to industrialize under conditions of global capital
accumulation.
In Henri Lefebvre’s classic study, he shows how powerful systems such as
capitalism produce the kinds of space they require.1 These spaces are constituted
H
OW HAS
Prasenjit Duara (
[email protected]) is Raffles Professor of Humanities and Director of Humanities and Social
Sciences Research at National University of Singapore.
1
Henri Lefebvre, The Production of Space, trans. Donald Nicholson-Smith (Oxford: Blackwell,
1992).
964
Prasenjit Duara
by relationships that can be abstracted, standardized, exchanged, and secured by
property rights. In capitalist space, physical factors of production such as land and
water become commodities. National spaces are often continuous with this kind
of space, which the nation-state authorizes not only by guaranteeing property
rights, but also by seeking to homogenize the population as citizens with overarching loyalty not to their substantive communities or life worlds, but to the
national community through the nation-state. This homogenizing tendency of
the nation-state may, of course, be reproduced within nested formations in
which horizontal identity is expressed in associations, provinces, language
groups, and so on, theoretically under the sovereign nation-state. In the national
model of space, there is an effort to make culture and political authority congruent. Of course, this also produces tensions between national and capitalist space.
Most significantly, the territorial sovereignty of the nation-state can limit the
deterritorializing imperative of capitalism.
IMPERIAL REGIONALISM
During the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, the relationship between
global capitalism, regional formations, and the nation-state was mediated by
imperialism. Much of nineteenth-century Asia was dominated by the “free
trade” imperialism of the British Empire, at a time when several historical networks of the Asian maritime trade were able to adapt and expand their operations. By the late nineteenth century and during the first half of the twentieth
century, imperialism came to be driven by nationalism to compete effectively
in a capitalist system, whether this was to secure resources, markets, or the military needs of the capitalist nation. This yielded a complex relationship between
imperialist nations and their colonial or dependent territories, which they
sought to develop as imperial regions.2
Turning first to the nineteenth century, colonial empires, most notably the
British Empire, created significant regional interdependencies in Asia. This
had the effect of intensifying some of the old relationships and generating new
linkages between the cities (and hinterlands) of Aden, Bombay, Calcutta, Singapore, Hong Kong, and Shanghai as entrepôts and financial centers for Asian
trade. For a long time, the study of Asian trade in the colonial period was conducted apart from the rich and high-quality scholarship of the precolonial maritime Asian or Indian Ocean trade, thus yielding a skewed picture of the former.
2
See Eric J. Hobsbawm, Nations and Nationalism since 1780: Programme, Myth, Reality
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 102; and Hannah Arendt, The Origins of Totalitarianism (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1973), 152–53. Arguably, even after World War
II, during the Cold War, the political mechanism that was developed to compete for global
resources was national imperialism, or the means whereby a national superpower exercised its
hegemony over subordinated nation-states.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
965
It was perhaps taken for granted that the financial, technological, and politicalmilitary superiority of the colonial powers in the nineteenth century had completely subordinated, if not eliminated, these networks. This seems to have been the
assumption behind the dual economy model of J. H. Boeke and others. More
recent work on the Indian Ocean—along the Gulf of Aden and Arabian Sea as
well as the South China Sea—has shown how faulty this picture was.
Since at least the thirteenth century, the maritime region from the Red Sea to
the South China Sea represented an interlinked system of trade routes. From the
1400s, the routes were held together, most importantly, by the cosmopolitan port
city of Malacca, to which the monsoon winds brought Indian, Persian, and Arab
traders. There, they waited for the reversal of the monsoon winds to carry in the
trade from the Chinese empire and eastern regions before returning. The networks of Chinese, Indian, Jewish, and Arab merchants, among others, with
their sophisticated credit transfer mechanisms and trading techniques enabled
the wholesale and forward carrying trade across the Indian Ocean littoral from
Zanzibar to China.3
According to Rajat K. Ray, while Asian networks from the nineteenth century
were doubtless subordinated to colonial trade and power, the older networks of
Chinese, Indian, and (Baghdadi) Jewish communities, which possessed longdistance credit networks and negotiable financial instruments operable in
several countries, adapted and expanded their operations within certain
spheres. Their business practices enabled them to occupy a realm between the
European world of banks and corporations and the small Asian peddler and
retail markets. Indeed, without the financial and marketing services provided
by these mobile merchant communities of Asia, European capital would not
have been able to penetrate the hinterlands. During the course of the twentieth
century, not only did these networks expand into the lower latitudes of Africa and
Southeast Asia, but also they emerged as the modern Asian business and industrial classes, which were able to integrate the three-tiered colonial economies into
national and postnational economies.4
On the East Asian side, the multiple connections and shifts between the precolonial maritime networks and modern Asian networks has been studied masterfully by Hamashita Takeshi. By the Qing period, the Chinese imperial tribute
3
Rajat K. Ray, “Asian Capital in the Age of European Expansion: The Rise of the Bazaar, 1800–
1914,” Modern Asian Studies 29, no 3 (1995): 449–554, 464, 472; Janet Lippman Abu-Lughod,
“The World System in the Thirteenth Century: Dead-End or Precursor?” in Essays on Global
and Comparative History, ed. Michael Adas (Washington, D.C.: American Historical Association,
1993), 9–11. For the precolonial Asian networks, see also the magisterial study of K. N. Chaudhuri,
Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilisation of the Indian Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
4
Ray, “Asian Capital in the Age of European Expansion,” 553; see also Sugata Bose, A Hundred
Horizons: The Indian Ocean in the Age of Global Empire (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 2006).
966
Prasenjit Duara
system had become the framework for commercial transactions based on the
price structure in China. The entire tribute trade zone became loosely integrated
by the use of silver as a medium of trade settlement. It became the axis around
which wider trading networks in the region were organized. Thus, for instance,
the private trade between Siam and South China was fueled by profits from
tribute mission, and when trade in this region declined, traders in South China
were able to switch to trading alongside other tribute missions, say, from
Ryukyu to Nagasaki. Tribute trade also linked the European trade with the
East Asian one. While it may have appeared to be an exclusively political relationship, in reality, the tribute system also expressed trading opportunities under a
loose regulatory system of several different states within an imperial Chinese
tribute zone.5 Not only has Hamashita shown how European-dominated patterns
rode on older networks of Asian trade, he also has recently revealed what he calls
the “crossed networks” (kōsa nettowaku) of Chinese and Indian overseas financial groups in East, South, and Southeast Asia.6 The Japanese conquests and
the partial overtaking of control of this trade opened new opportunities for
regional integration, but it turned out to be more destructive than enabling
during the short period it existed.
Moving on to imperial regional formation in the interwar years of the twentieth century, national imperialisms sought to develop a regional or (geographically dispersed) bloc formation promoting economic autarky as a means for the
imperial power to gain global supremacy or advantage. Here they sought to
establish common standards, measures, currency, and laws to facilitate
integration—if uneven development—across the bloc. After World War I, the
indebtedness of Great Britain to the United States and its weakening competitiveness vis-à-vis other imperialist powers caused the British to impose the
doctrine of imperial preference and the sterling zone in its colonies and dependencies. This was also, however, a time when the anti-imperialist movement in
the colonies began to make increasing demands for economic and political
parity. Thus, imperialists sought to create economic blocs in which colonies or
subordinate territories were promised self-governing status and other concessions, and sometimes were even constituted as nominally sovereign nation-states,
although they remained militarily in thrall to the metropole. The imperialism of
nation-states reflected a strategic reorientation of the periphery to be part of an
organic formation designed to attain global supremacy for the imperial power. As
Albert Lebrun declared after World War I, the goal was now to “unite France to
5
Hamashita Takeshi, “The Tribute Trade System and Modern Asia,” in Japanese Industrialization
and the Asian Economy, ed. A. J. H. Latham and Heita Kawasatsu (London: Routledge, 1994).
6
Hamashita Takeshi, “Kōsa suru Indokei nettowaku to Kajinkei nettowaku: Honkoku sōkin shisutemu no hikaku kentō” [Intersecting networks of Indians and Chinese: A comparative investigation
of the remittance system], in Gendai Minami Ajia 6: Sekai Sisutemu To Nettowâku [Contemporary
South Asia 6: World system and network], ed. Akita Shigeru and Mizushima (Tokyo: Tokyo University Press, 2003), 239–74.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
967
all those distant Frances in order to permit them to combine their efforts to draw
from one another reciprocal advantages.”7
But it was less the older imperialist powers than the new ones such as Japan,
the United States, and the Soviet Union that proved able to switch to this mode of
regional imperialism of nation-states. With the increased need for resource and
social mobilization within colonies or dependencies, it was more efficient for the
imperialists to foster modern and indirectly controlled institutions in them. The
goal was to control these areas by dominating their institutions of mobilization,
such as banks, transportation infrastructure, and political institutions, which
were created to resemble those of the metropole (such as legislative councils,
institutions of political tutelage, and political parties such as the communist
parties or the Concordia in Manchukuo). In short, unlike colonialism or British
free trade imperialism, the interwar imperialists attended to the modernization
of institutions and identities. They often espoused cultural or ideological
similarities—including sometimes anticolonial ideologies—even while racism
and nationalism accompanied the reality of military-political domination.
To compete with Britain and France, Germany had sought to develop a
regional bloc in Central and Eastern Europe since the end of the nineteenth
century.8 This trend accelerated during the interwar years, and German commercial influence before the war peaked in 1938, when Austria was incorporated into
the Reich and Adolf Hitler annexed the Sudeten region of Czechoslovakia.
Hannah Arendt regarded the German (and Russian pan-Slav) movement as an
expression of “continental imperialism” whereby latecomer nationalists sought
to develop their empires through the nationalistic pan-German movement.9
The German economic New Order in Europe, built on states that were essentially German puppets or had German military governors, was designed to
supply the German war effort. However, there were also plans to build an economic region around a prosperous Germany linked to new industrial complexes in
central Europe and captured areas of the western Soviet Union. This unitary
European market, however, remained a nationalistic German vision—and we
should be wary of seeing it as a predecessor of the European Union. The
German plan represented in several ways no more than an aborted version of
the new imperialism.10
7
As quoted in D. Bruce Marshall, The French Colonial Myth and Constitution-Making in the
Fourth Republic (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1973), 44.
8
Barry Eichengreen and Jeffrey A. Frankel, “Economic Regionalism: Evidence from Two
Twentieth-Century Episodes,” North American Journal of Economics and Finance 6, no. 2
(1995): 97.
9
Arendt, The Origins of Totalitarianism, 222–23. This racist ideology seemingly authorized the
Germans to annex or dominate territories belonging to other states. At the same time, Nazi
racism excluded such large numbers of people that even the rhetoric of anti-imperialism or solidarity of cultures was made impossible.
10
See Richard Overy, “World Trade and World Economy,” in The Oxford Companion to World War
II, ed. Ian C. B. Dear and M. R. D. Foot (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001).
968
Prasenjit Duara
Beginning with the formation of the puppet state of Manchukuo (1932–45),
the Japanese economic bloc idea grew by the mid-1930s into the East Asian
League (Tōa renmei) and the East Asian Community (Tōa kyōdōtai), and still
later into the idea of the Greater East Asian Co-Prosperity Sphere (Dai-Tōa
Kyōeiken). Manchukuo signaled fundamental changes in the nature of the Japanese empire. The truly intensive phase of industrialization and development in
Korea and Taiwan came after 1931 and emerged as part of the plan for strategic
autarky centered on Manchukuo. The rapid growth in industrialization, education, and other aspects of development in Korea and Taiwan began mostly in
the early 1930s, and accelerated with the invasion of China in 1937. The Japanese
wartime empire resembled the German New Order in that the entire occupied
zone became subordinated to Japanese war needs, and Japan’s defeat represented a failure of the new imperialism.
This form of imperial regionalism, then, was characterized by an unsustainable tension: a commitment to creating a common space akin to the nation that
would extend the benefits and pains of creating a globally competitive region, but
would extend them unevenly over the whole. By the same token, the imperialnational region was often ripped apart by enduring nationalist prejudices fostered
in earlier times and simultaneous processes of nation building, especially within
the imperial metropole. In other words, while it sought to create a region of interdependence and cooperation, the national interests of the imperial power made
this an unsustainable region.
What was the spatial composition of this imperialist region? While most of
the subordinate nations or colonies within the region were by no means fully integrated with capitalist urban centers, the infrastructure of capitalist market
relations—including standardization of weights and measures, currency unification, and the physical and educational infrastructure—were being laid across
many of these societies, both within each colony or country and across them.
The integration was a dual and interactive process undertaken by the colonial
states and metropolitan capitalists, as well as by Asian merchants, who, as
shown earlier, dominated the indigenous financial markets through bills of
exchange, promissory notes, and other negotiable instruments (such as the
Chinese gu or South Asian hundis). As Hamashita has shown, Singapore and
Hong Kong were colonial cities in which the Chinese and Indian money transfer
and remittance networks intersected, and their resources became part of a vast
regional financial market interfluent with the Western-dominated banking
sector.11 But if the material lives and economic practices of Asians were becoming interlinked on an everyday basis, how was this reflected in the representation
of the region?
11
Hamashita, “Kōsa suru Indokei nettowaku to Kajinkei nettowaku,” 261–67.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
THE ANTI-IMPERIALIST REGIONALIZATION PROJECT
IN
969
ASIA
While the British and Japanese empires were trying to create autarkic, interdependent regions to sustain their imperial power in Asia, anti-imperialist
thought linked to rising Asian nationalism was seeking to build an alternative conception of the region. These intellectual proponents of an “Other Asia” evoked
earlier linkages between their societies, but it should be noted that their conceptualization of Asia was itself premised and enabled by contemporary imperialist
technologies and modes of regional integration.
The idea of Asia among these Asians was expressed largely through a cultural
movement that is instructive for us to explore. I will review here the efforts of
three intellectuals—Okakura Tenshin, Rabindranath Tagore, and Zhang
Taiyan—as in this early period, Asianism was principally an intellectual and
cultural effort until it was overtaken by the Japanese military for imperialist
purposes. Okakura Tenshin or Kakuzo is perhaps most famous for his opening
line “Asia is one” in his book The Ideals of the East with Special Reference to
the Arts of Japan, written in 1901 (published 1903).12 Okakura, who was
deeply knowledgeable about Chinese art and culture and closely connected
with South Asian Asianists such as Tagore and Ananda Coomarswamy, as well
as with American art entrepreneurs such as Ernest Fenellosa, probably did
more than anyone to establish Asian art as a legitimate and viable domain of
high art, fit for museums and the art market.
It was through his conception of the great civilizational arts of China and
India, and not least the aesthetic values of Buddhism, that Okakura saw the
unity of the Asian ideals that reigned before what he regarded as the marauding
of the Mongols and their successors. But even as Okakura was articulating the
ideal of Asia, in the same moment, he was also carving out a place for Japan in
the civilized world of the West as the inheritor and leader of this present fallen
Asia. Okakura saw Japan as a survivor and a leader. “Thus Japan is a museum
of Asiatic civilization and yet more than a museum, because the singular
genius of the race leads it to dwell on all phases of the ideals of the past, in
that spirit of living Advaitism which welcomes the new without losing the
old.”13 The temples of Nara reveal that the great art of the Tang and the much
older influence of Shang workmanship can also be found in Japan.
Rabindranath Tagore and Okakura had a close friendship, and Okakura spent
considerable time in India, acquiring a deep respect for its arts and culture even
while introducing the utterly fascinated circle in the Tagore house, Jorasankho, to
Chinese and Japanese culture. Both men sought to live their lives according to
their ideals, even donning the clothing of their historical cultures while most
12
Okakura Tenshin, The Ideals of the East with Special Reference to the Arts of Japan (Tokyo: ICG
Muse, 2002).
13
Ibid, 7–8.
970
Prasenjit Duara
Western-educated gentlemen were opting for the prestige of the West. Thus,
Okakura dressed in a dhoti when he visited the Ajanta caves, and Tagore often
wore his Daoist hat, given to him during his first China visit. Yet, of course, let
it not be forgotten that they possessed the self-confidence to advocate Asian
culture because they were so knowledgeable and polished in the arts of the
West. Moreover, theirs was sometimes a troubled relationship, in part because
Okakura could not quite overcome the social Darwinist presuppositions and
imagery of Indian backwardness, and partly because he was an object of exotic
curiosity, if not ridicule, among many Indians who had never seen East Asians,
particularly in their historical dress.
Some have seen a form of Japanese Orientalism in Okakura’s paternalistic
attitude toward the older Asian societies. I believe this is an ahistorical
impulse. Japanese pan-Asianism at the turn of the century had several different
strains, including imperialistic ones, but also egalitarian and compassionate feelings toward fellow Asians who had been exploited and devastated by more
aggressive cultures. At the same time, pan-Asianism cultivated a deep claim of
Japanese leadership in Asia and a self-imputed responsibility to raise Asians
from their fallen state. Okakura saw Japan as the hall or museum—the
enabler—that would display all of the different civilizations of Asia. This enabling
role, of course, could easily be transformed into a superiority and instrumentalization of what it enabled. It was this tendency—or what we might call a “structure
of feeling”—that grew into the ideological foundations of Japanese imperialism,
endowing it with the mission to lead Asians. Indeed, as is well known, it is the
subservience of pan-Asianism to Japanese militarist imperialism that doomed
its future in the twentieth century.
Zhang Taiyan or Zhang Binglin is widely considered to be one of the most
powerful intellectuals of late Qing and early Republican China. The great
writer Lu Xun certainly regarded him as such and saw himself as a lifelong
student of Zhang. Many see Zhang as a maverick thinker who was both narrowly
racist in his violent anti-Manchu revolutionary views and deeply humanist and
learned—being not only the foremost scholar of ancient Chinese learning, but
also widely read in Buddhist philosophy, especially the Yogacārā or
Consciousness-Only (weishi or vijnapati matra) school of Buddhism, of which
he was a practitioner.
Zhang became committed to Buddhism during his years in jail (1903–6) as a
result of his revolutionary activities. He suffered greatly in jail and watched his
younger colleague Zou Rong die under terrible privation. He claimed that he
was saved only by his voracious readings of Buddhist philosophy. We do not
have the time here to discuss the allegation of the maverick’s inconsistency
except to indicate that alaya (storehouse) thinking permitted different levels of
consciousness and commitment depending on the needs of the time. This philosophy disposes one to think very differently from the principle of commitment
to ethical consistency.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
971
Zhang espoused the cause of freedom from imperialism in Asia while in Japan
after his release from prison. There, he attended the meetings of the Indian
freedom fighters commemorating the birth anniversary of the Maratha warrior
Shivaji, who had fought against the Moguls. He is said to have authored the manifesto of the Asian Solidarity Society created in Tokyo around 1907. It begins thus:
Among the various Asian countries, India has Buddhism and Hinduism;
China has the theories of Confucius, Mencius, Lao Zi, Zhuang Zi and
Yang Zi; then moving to Persia, they also have enlightened religions,
such as Zoroastrianism. The various races in this region had self-respect
and did not invade one another … They rarely invaded one another and
treated each other respectfully with the Confucian virtue of benevolence.
About one hundred years ago, the Europeans moved east and Asia’s
power diminished day by day. Not only was their political and military
power totally lacking, but people also felt inferior. Their scholarship deteriorated and people only strove after material interests.14
Zhang’s Asianism emerged from his commitment to the values of Buddhism, but
also from an anti-imperialist position. He saw the threat to peaceful, agrarian
societies from warlike cultures. But while committed to the ultimate values of
peace, like Okakura, he acknowledged the necessity of creating a modern nationstate along the Western model to combat the imperialist powers. Nationalism was
a necessary moment in the conception of pan-Asianism.
Only Tagore opposed this position. Tagore was deeply repulsed by nationalism. Writing about nationalism in Japan, he observed, “I have seen in Japan the
voluntary submission of the whole people to the trimming of their minds and clipping of their freedoms by their governments … The people accept this allpervading mental slavery with cheerfulness and pride because of their nervous
desire to turn themselves into a machine of power, called the Nation, and
emulate other machines in their collective worldliness.”15 Tagore’s pan-Asianism
was deeply affected by his personal friendships in China, but even here, during
his last visit to China in 1929, he was severely attacked by leftist intellectuals and
the Kuomintang because of his views.16 Most of all, he was bitterly disappointed
by the growing nationalism of his own homeland in India, where revolutionary
nationalists had overtaken the Swadeshi movement that he had once supported.
Their growing narrowness—revealed, for instance, in their goal to burn every
14
Viren Murthy, “Nationalism and Transnationalism in the Early Twentieth Century: Zhang Taiyan’s
View of Asia;” unpublished manuscript; see also idem, “The Myriad Things Stem from Confusion:
Nationalism, Ontology and Resistance in Zhang Taiyan’s Philosophy” (PhD diss., University of
Chicago, 2006).
15
Rabindranath Tagore, “Nationalism in the West,” Nationalism, ed. Ramachandra Guha (New
Delhi: Pengium Books, 2009), 49.
16
Stephen N. Hay, Asian Ideas of East and West: Tagore and His Critics in Japan, China, and India
(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), 323–24.
972
Prasenjit Duara
piece of foreign cloth—had also begun to affect relations between Hindus and
Muslims.
Tagore was committed to an alternative cosmopolitanism drawn from Asian traditions, which he sought to realize in Vishwa Bharati (India of the World) University
at Santiniketan. According to Saranindranath Tagore, Tagore’s philosophy of education rose above both abstract and lifeless rationalism as well as violent nationalism
and particularism. He was persuaded that reason would emerge only after a primary
identification with an inherited tradition. Education would have to nurture the attitude of seeking reason to bridge radical differences by recognizing the consciousness of humanity’s latent oneness.17 One of the great hopes of Santiniketan was
realized with the institution of Cheena Bhavan (China Hall) initiated by scholar
Tan Yunshan, whose children, notably Tan Chung, remain cultural ambassadors
between China and India. Among others, Tagore’s own relatives were pioneers in
introducing Chinese arts and scholarship to Indians.
Tagore’s cosmopolitanism, which he derived from the Advaita or monistic
philosophical tradition, has some unexpected parallels with contemporary thinkers from different traditions, such as Jürgen Habermas. Tagore’s commitment
to the universality of reason as made possible by working through difference
resembles Habermas’s idea of communicative rationality as emerging from the
negotiation of various value claims of different groups and communities. But
as with Habermas’s theory of communicative rationality, Tagore’s educational
philosophy could not withstand power—expressed in Tagore’s case in the historical force of nationalism and allied ideologies. The logic of communicative acts
and education is not the only or dominant logic of society—the logic of power
often frames this discussion through reified expressions of community (as in
nationalisms or communal religion). For most of the century, while Tagore was
celebrated, his cosmopolitan educational project in Santiniketan was ignored
and marginalized by the imperatives of a competitive nationalism.
Through this brief survey, we have seen how the three major Asian thinkers
were able to conceive of the unity of Asia founded on different principles. The
idea of a common historical and religious culture, conceived sometimes as a
utopian golden age of peaceful coexistence and dynamic exchange before the
arrival of foreign invaders, may have prompted Asianists to think of original
Asian value. Note also how in each case, their notion of Asia excluded societies
from the Middle East and Central Asia, which each regarded as foreign invaders
of their societies. Nonetheless, pan-Asianism, as several scholars have shown, was
an important trend in the Middle East as these thinkers reached out especially to
Japan as allies against Western imperialism. Indeed, Tagore’s four-week visit to
Iran in 1932, during which he and his hosts sought to highlight Indo-Iranian
17
Saranindranath Tagore, “Postmodernism and Education: A Tagorean Intervention,” paper presented at “Tagore’s Philosophy of Education,” conference dedicated to the memory of Amita
Sen, Kolkata, India, March 29–30, 2006.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
973
civilizational nexus, was perhaps one of his most successful Asian visits.18 By and
large, the three thinkers we have considered were looking for new beginnings in
the search for alternative values—alternative to the dominant civilizational narratives of the West. In this sense, they were the founders of a cultural antiimperialism and articulators of an Asian cosmopolitanism.
However, their thought was ahead of their time, in that it could not be sustained
by the political societies in which they lived. Ideas of race, culture, anti-imperialism,
and imperialism to be found in pan-Asianism all spelled a lethally close relationship
with the dominant trend of nationalism. In the case of Okakura, pan-Asianism
became easily absorbed by Japanese imperialism; in the case of Zhang, nationalism
took priority because of the circumstances. In the case of Tagore, the nationalism of
his time made his ideas and institutions irrelevant for a long period.
The spatial vision of Asia that these thinkers possessed was based not on the
actual interactions of people from the different countries—of which there was a
great deal—but on an abstract and essentialized notion of culture and civilization
formed in the mirror image of the Western concept of civilization. Just as that
celebration of the superior achievements of a race and religion—apart from
specific classes and areas—worked to further a program of domination of
Others, so, too, the idea of Asian civilization was hijacked by Japanese militarism.
ASIA
AFTER
WORLD WAR II
The Cold War division of the world into two camps controlled militarily by
nuclear superpowers seeking to dominate the rest of the developing and decolonizing nations may be seen as a kind of supraregionalism. While in fact, the two
camps or blocs represented transterritorial spaces including noncontiguous
nations, the contiguity of the core Eastern and Western Europeans nations
within each camp served as a stepping stone for subsequent regionalism to
develop within Europe. We see this tendency as well in Asia, where regional
interactions were promoted among the countries of the Central Treaty Organization, the Southeast Asia Treaty Organization, and the Association of Southeast
Asian Nations (ASEAN), which were basically security alliances. The Japanese
efforts to cultivate Asian markets during and after the Vietnam War also
created some economic and cultural grounds for later integration. After the
Cold War, ASEAN, which had been designed, unlike the European community,
to serve the nation, not only expanded to include the former communist nations
of Southeast Asia, but also became more oriented to serve the economic needs of
the region.19 Moreover, places such as Hong Kong, which played an
18
Sugata Bose, A Hundred Horizons, 260–65.
Muthiah Alagappa, Asian Security Practice: Material and Ideational Influences (Stanford, Calif.:
Stanford University Press, 1998).
19
974
Prasenjit Duara
indispensable role as a conduit for exchange between the two camps, were able to
reinforce and benefit handsomely from older regional links, especially between
Southeast Asia and China.
Another effort to create a regional entity during the early Cold War was the
movement of nonaligned nations, principally in Asia, although it also included the
African nations. The culmination of this movement was the Bandung Conference,
a meeting of the representatives of twenty-nine new nations of Asia and Africa, held
in Bandung, Indonesia, in 1955, fifty years after the Russo-Japanese war signaled
the beginnings of pan-Asianism. The conference aimed to express solidarity
against imperialism and racism and to promote economic and cultural cooperation
among these nations. China, India, and Indonesia were key players in the meeting.
The conference finally led to the nonaligned movement in 1961, a wider third-world
force in which participants avowed their distance from the two superpowers—aligning themselves neither with the United States or Soviet Union—during the Cold
War. However, conflicts developed among these nonaligned nations—for instance,
between India and China in 1962—that eroded the solidarity of the Bandung spirit.
At any rate, the nonaligned nations tended to be nationally autarkic in their economic strategies, moving further away from regional linkages.
Thus, all in all, although there were significant foundations for the post–Cold
War regionalism to be found in the Cold War itself, the economic energies of the
Asian countries in the two camps were directed more toward the nation and the
supraregion than the region itself. The congruence between political and cultural
realms also came to be directed toward the two loci.
The post–Cold War scene is usually characterized as one of globalization. At
the same time, the nation-state and nationalism have by no means disappeared;
they have developed a new relationship to globalization. In this reconfiguration,
regionalism has clearly strengthened, emerging as an intermediate zone between
the deterritorializing impulses of capitalism and the territorial limits of nationalism. Evidence of regionalism can be found in Europe, of course, but also in the
North American Free Trade Agreement, Mercosur in South America, AsiaPacific Economic Cooperation, ASEAN (+3 and +6, i.e., the East Asian
Summit), and many others. Unlike the Cold War, these are largely economic
rather than security-based regionalisms. Moreover, most of these regions are
not overwhelmingly dominated by one imperial power or hegemon.
Within East and Southeast Asia—and more recently, India—Asian economic
integration has increased significantly, principally since the end of the Asian
financial crisis of the late 1990s. The economic integration of East, South, and
Southeast Asia, which grew steadily under imperialist-dominated trade, declined
precipitously at the end of World War II.20 Intraregional trade began to pick up in
20
Peter A Petri, “Is East Asia Becoming More Interdependent?” Paper prepared for the session on
“European and Asian Integration: Trade and Money Issues,” American Economic Association,
Boston, January 8, 2005.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
975
the 1980s, but it was the Asian financial crisis—the shock of the common
crisis—that seems to have awakened states to the reality of regional networks
and focused their attention on cooperation. Today, what the Asian Development
Bank calls “integrating Asia,” including ASEAN, China, Japan, Korea, India,
Hong Kong, and Taiwan, conducts more than 50 percent of its trade among
itself, in comparison to trade with the outside world, and compared with only
33 percent in the 1980s. Six major indicators of interdependence tracked for
the sixteen Asian economies have increased markedly in the ten years since
the financial crisis.21
The most important factor behind the increased trade is the participation of
these economies in a regional supply chain production network. Production is
divided up into smaller steps, and each part is assigned to the most cost-efficient
producer. Thus, for instance, an electronic product may be produced or
assembled in China with hardware from Taiwan and software from India.
Indeed, much of this type of vertical integration has been enabled by new information and communication technologies and open markets. At the same time,
the bulk of these goods have been produced for consumption in Europe and
North America. The present crisis in consumption may well lead to deepening
markets for these goods within Asia. In recent years, ASEAN has developed
free trade agreements with each of the East Asian nations and with India. The
China-ASEAN free trade agreement due in 2010 will create the third-largest
common market by trade volume. The significantly lower-volume trade
between ASEAN and India has also, however, been growing at a compounded
annual rate of 27 percent, and it is likely to accelerate with the signing of the
ASEAN-Indian free trade agreement in August 2009.22
Financial integration has been relatively weaker within Asia than between
individual Asian countries and Western economies. This is particularly noticeable
because of the enormous savings generated within Asia that are not productively
invested in projects within the region. However, after the 1997–98 financial crisis,
the Chiangmai Initiative was undertaken to provide emergency liquidity in case
of a foreign exchange crisis in the ASEAN + 3 countries with $80 billion. In 2009,
the fund was increased to $120 billion, with Japan and China agreeing to contribute a third each, South Korea putting up 16 percent, and ASEAN making up the
balance of 20 percent.23 In the last year, several other countries have entered into
21
Asian Development Bank, Emerging Asian Regionalism: A Partnership for Shared Prosperity
(Manila: Asian Development Bank, 2008), 70, 97–98.
22
See “Cabinet Nod for ASEAN FTA,” Times of India, July 25, 2009, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/News/Economy/Foreign-Trade/Cabinet-nod-for-Asean-FTA/articleshow/4818081.cms
(accessed August 10, 2010). On the China-ASEAN free trade agreement, see Collin Spears, “SINO
+ ASEAN = East Asian Unification? Not Quite Part I,” Brooks Foreign Policy Review, May 20,
2009, http://brooksreview.wordpress.com/2009/05/20/sino-asean-east-asian-unification-not-quitepart-i/ (accessed August 10, 2010).
23
The Straits Times (Singapore), Review and Forum, May 5, 2009.
976
Prasenjit Duara
bilateral swap agreements. Such agreements have been reached, for instance,
between India and Japan, and in response to the precipitous decline of the
Korean won, Korea recently entered separately into bilateral swap agreements
with China and Japan.
Macroeconomic interdependence in the region is also indicated by the movement of macroeconomic variables. For instance, the correlation of gross domestic
product (GDP) among many of these states over three-year moving averages is
very strong. The GDP correlation coefficient has gone up from 0.07
before the crisis to 0.54 after the crisis. Price movements are similarly correlated,
and price shocks in one area are being transmitted to other areas with greater
intensity. With the growth of macroeconomic interdependence, a growing
need to manage it has appeared. For instance, exchange rates require
monitoring and coordination so that central banks do not shoot each the other
in the foot.24
Most of all, of course, the need to coordinate and manage interdependence
arises from a common and linked set of problems faced by the region in the realm
of climate change, environmental degradation, water scarcity, and public health,
among others. The provisioning of these items, which the Asian Development
Bank dubs “regional public goods,” is evidently urgent. Consider a colossal and
dire public goods problem that cannot be managed without a concerted regional
effort. The Himalayas and the Tibetan Plateau are the source and watershed of
ten major rivers that provide freshwater to many different countries in South and
Southeast Asia, in addition to China. Climate change and environmental degradation have depleted the water resources available in all these countries, a situation that is particularly severe in north and northwest China, which is suffering
the most severe drought in the last half century, with precipitation levels 70
percent to 90 percent below normal and water tables depleted from excessive
well drilling.25
What does this crisis in a remote area of China have to do with South and
Southeast Asia? A great deal, in fact. China not only has been building dams
on rivers such as the Yangtze, but has also built three more on the Mekong
River to produce hydropower for its southwest border regions. About twelve
more large dams are expected to be built on the Mekong (or Lancang) alone.
Vietnam, Laos, Thailand, and Cambodia have expressed grave concerns about
water diversions, shortages, and ecological imbalance in the region. Although
China and some authorities assert that the impact of Chinese dam building has
not affected downstream waters significantly, the Chinese government has not
been very forthcoming with the data on the dams, and it also has not permitted
independent scientific studies of the dams. Greater regional efforts must begin
24
Asian Development Bank, Emerging Asian Regionalism, 153–55.
Mark Selden, “China’s Way Forward? Historical and Contemporary Perspectives on Hegemony
and the World Economy in Crisis,” Asia-Pacific Journal, March 24, 2009.
25
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
977
with pooling all of the necessary data.26 Recently, there has been a proposal to
divert the waters of several Tibetan rivers, including the Yarlung Tsangpo
(Brahmaputra) in India and Bangladesh northward to irrigate the north China
plains. The proposal, known as the Great South-North Water Transfer Project,
appears to have the backing of President Hu Jintao. Needless to say, the
effects of this diversion on South Asia could well lead to unprecedented water
wars.27 In this context, it is heartening to learn that economic interdependence
within Asia is the major—perhaps the only—factor reducing conflict among
these Asian nation-states.28
THE CIRCULATION
OF
PEOPLE
I turn now to more direct people-to-people interactions. There is some indication of greater cultural interest of Asians in Asia. We see this in the increase in
the number of tourists circulating the region to more than pre-crisis levels. Not
only has the market demand for Asian art skyrocketed, but also there are plenty
of exhibitions and showings of Asian art in which artists and curators are experimenting with new ideas of Asia as well as art. These shows often deliberately distance themselves from the culturally unified notion of Asia or reified versions of
national civilizations prevalent among their predecessors, such as Okakura and
Nand Lal Bose. They often seek to showcase the contemporary, urban, multicultural experience of Asia, emphasizing heterogeneity and cultural encounters.29 At
a popular level, the circulation of East Asian cinema, manga, anime, television
shows, food, design, and allied areas in East and Southeast Asia has been the
most conspicuous cultural development in Asia since the 1990s.
Most revealing of the emergent space and complex nature of Asian integration is perhaps the subject of migration and sojourning within the region.
Through this optic, we can observe the extent of the move away from the national
production of space and explore the possibilities and dangers of a new type of
spatial production. As globalization has proceeded over the last two and a half
decades, nation-states have adopted, albeit to different degrees, strategies of neoliberal privatization and opening to world markets and circulations. The movement of people across the globe and region for purposes of work and
livelihood has expanded considerably. The People’s Republic of China has 35
26
Geoffrey Gunn and Brian McCartan, “Chinese Dams and the Great Mekong Floods of 2008,”
Japan Focus, March 21, 2009.
27
Brahma Chellaney, “China-India Clash over Chinese Claims to Tibetan Water,” Japan Focus, July
3, 2007.
28
See Benjamin E Goldsmith, “A Liberal Peace in Asia?,” Journal of Peace Research 44, no. 1
(2007): 5–27.
29
C. J. Wan-Ling Wee, “‘We Asians’? Modernity, Visual Art Exhibitions, and East Asia,” boundary 2
37, no. 1 (2010): 91–126.
978
Prasenjit Duara
million migrants across the world; India has 20 million, and the Philippines has
8 million. Remittances, cultural values and styles, and technical and professional
knowledge from their host societies have a major impact on domestic economies
and societies. As of 2001, more than 6 million migrants from Asia worked in the
more advanced economies of Japan, Singapore, Taiwan, Korea, Hong Kong, and
Malaysia.30
Elite migrants and transmigrants circulating within Asia are a novel phenomenon of these last few decades, and they have ushered in a new culture of professional Asians in the major cities. They are embedded in both knowledge
and business networks and have often been trained in Western academic establishments, where they develop their professional cultural ethos and connections.
These professionals are a significant element in the cultural profile of the new
global and metropolitan cities in Asia, whether in Shanghai, Bangalore, Dubai,
Singapore, or Hong Kong. As the workshop on “Inter-Referencing Asia,” held
in Dubai in 2008, points out, there is “an intensification of traffic in people,
urban models, and cultural forms between Asian cities, big and small.” In
many ways, these cities are increasingly linked by corridors of exchange with
other Asian cities, as they are with their own national or regional hinterlands.
The workshop identifies these Asian—indeed, intra-Asian—cities as “extraterritorial” metropolises that are produced not only by national resources but also
through a set of global and intra-Asian flows of labor, capital, and knowledge.31
The complex known as Biopolis and its sister establishment Fusionopolis in Singapore represent classic instances of such extraterritoriality. The scientists, technicians, and professionals who work here day and often night for Asian and global
biotech companies hail from every part of Asia (often with Western degrees).
These gigantic mall-like complexes feature every kind of Asian eatery and
omniplexes featuring anime festivals, while construction and maintenance are
performed by gangs of other Asian migrant laborers.
It is this new relationship between elite and working-class migration that
I wish to comment on. As is well known, many Asian nations are seeking and succeeding in wooing back their talented émigrés to invest their knowledge and
capital in their original homelands. Historically, this kind of migration and courtship has been exceptional. Migration over the last century and a half has largely
been labor migration, mostly in plantation, mining, and infrastructure construction, but of people who have ended up in different niches in the host societies.
The matrix in which this migration has taken place has been constituted by
networks and institutions of global capitalism and the modern nation-state,
30
Asian Development Bank, Emerging Asian Regionalism, 225; see also http://www.scalabrini.asn.
au/atlas (accessed August 10, 2010).
31
“Inter-Referencing Asia: Urban Experiments and the Art of Being Global,” workshop directed by
Aihwa Ong and Ananya Roy, International Conference on Inter-Asian Connections, Dubai, United
Arab Emirates, February 21–23, 2008.
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
979
whether in its imperialist manifestation or its nationalist one. While, as we have
seen, the relationship between the nation-state and capitalism has largely been a
collusive one, there has also been a tension in that relationship. To put it simply,
while global capitalism has encouraged the flow of labor, nationalist states have
sought to both regulate and curb this flow by responding to a set of other interests,
including affected domestic working classes and constituencies based on racial
and nationalist ideologies. Decolonizing nation-states have turned out to be as
limiting of immigrant populations as older imperialist nation-states.
The laboring population that has both benefited and suffered most greatly
from this tension between global capitalism and the nation-state is the Chinese
community, first in the Americas and then in Southeast Asia. The exclusion
laws against Asians in the United States until 1942 imposed strict quotas and controls on labor migrants from China. Indeed, the matrix made much immigrant
labor the exception in the sense of Agamben—the impossible subject—necessary
to labor on undesirable tasks for a pittance, but without rights, suspended
between capital and the state and often between nation-state jurisdictions. To
be sure, much of this labor was also able to creatively manipulate their suspension
between powers, as the so-called paper sons of Chinese migrants who entered
the United States in large numbers during the early twentieth century show.32
What has changed in the relationship between global capitalism and the
nation-state? How has the globalization of recent decades changed this institutional matrix affecting migrants? One new element, as I have tried to show,
is the substantially new flow of high-value workers, or professionals. Speaking
impressionistically, it would seem that this is informed by the growth of what is
called the knowledge economy, or knowledge-based service and production in
the global economy. The fact that so much of it is Asian and circulating in the
Asian region is a still more complex and interesting question. The return and
transmigration of a professional and managerial stratum does signify a shift in
the institutional matrix. Whereas the nation-state worked to regulate the deterritorialized flows of labor, capital, and culture of capitalism even when colluding
with it, now the nationalist opposition to these flows is significantly smaller,
especially from the institutions of the nation-state. As large states such as India
and the People’s Republic of China reach out to global professionals among overseas and global Chinese (huaren, haigui) and Indians (nonresident Indians) they
create a nonterritorial, ethnic identity—as children of the Yellow Emperor or
Hindutva or Bharat Pravasis—that fits with a neoliberal model of globalization
and competitiveness. Until recently, this has also coincided with state withdrawal
in many areas of provisioning public goods, such as education and health care.
32
“Paper sons” were Chinese immigrants who claimed to be the sons of American citizens using
false papers. See Prasenjit Duara, “Between Sovereignty and Capitalism: The Historical Experiences of Migrant Chinese,” in The Global and Regional in China’s Nation Formation (London:
Routledge, 2009), chap. 7.
980
Prasenjit Duara
On the other hand, labor migration, especially in seasonal and construction
work, has expanded to many more societies. These labor migrants are typically
sojourners who have short-term labor contracts and are prevented from assimilation into the host society. Many, such as the recent case of the Rohingas in
Thailand and elsewhere, are regularly abused and exploited by local authorities
and labor contractors. Moreover, unlike the previous round, there is increased
sojourning by women employed as domestic workers, nurses, entertainers, and
prostitutes, which, in turn, is also reshaping families across Asia. We need to
focus more on the continuing power and role of the nation-state to regulate
and expel immigrants. The nation-state continues to control the prerogative of
return for them. It controls their tenure and bodies,33 and can satisfy the constituent interests of domestic workers and nationalist interests. They can serve
as an important safety valve and whipping boy.
Thus, the new order in Asia must be seen in its totality. The figure of the professional global transmigrants, their flexible citizenship, self-improvement projects, and the state’s interest in utilizing them must be seen against the ground
of continuing power of the restructured nation-state to control and expel at
the lower levels of the social hierarchy. While these Asian nations must be able
to draw in and deploy migrants at the higher levels, they must be able to push
out migrants at the lower levels. Thus, the new Asia does not by any means
suggest the weakening of nationalism, but rather a refiguration or restructuring
of the nation-state to adapt to global capitalism.
WHAT KIND
OF
SPACE IS THIS NEW ASIA?
There are significant continuities and novelties in this space. While the
nation-state continues to exercise deeply rooted powers, regionally, there is no
congruence or sustained effort at producing congruence between politics and
culture by any state. The absence of a single dominant nation-state in the
region contributes significantly to this, but it is also the case that the individual
nation-state finds it difficult to make a coherent case for a nationalism congruent
with its territorial conception. In part, this has to do with state withdrawal and
growing identification with transterritorial ethnic groups such as the overseas
Chinese or Indians (often at the expense of peripheries and nondominant
ethnics or marginal co-nationals). Moreover, both capitalism and the nation-state
have transformed to the point where they celebrate heterogeneity and multiculturalism even as these sociocultural factors are themselves commoditized. As the
authors of the latest management fad book Globality suggest, for multinationals,
33
For instance, female domestic workers are required to undergo pregnancy and HIV tests every six
months in Singapore. Those who are pregnant often face dismissal and deportation. See Human
Rights Watch, “Maid to Order: Ending Abuses against Migrant Domestic Workers in Singapore,”
2005, http://www.hrw.org/en/reports/2005/12/06/maid-order (accessed August 10, 2010).
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
981
the very idea of domestic markets has been replaced by niche markets.34 Finally,
because the nation-state is much more invested in and aware of regional and
global interdependence, a split has appeared in the interests and rhetoric of
popular nationalism and the nation-state, most evident in the People’s Republic
of China, but also in India, Thailand, and elsewhere. All of these factors make the
political homogenization of culture or its essentialization an unnecessary and difficult process. The weakness and failure of the effort to create an ideology of
Asian values in the late 1990s is a case in point.
But, as I have argued, actual interdependence has increased dramatically,
and so has cultural contact. Interdependence, however, is being managed by
ad hoc arrangements and specialized transnational institutions with little possibility of large-scale state-like coordination or control. In this sense, region formation in Asia is a multipath, uneven, and pluralistic development that is
significantly different from European regionalism. Moreover, the region has no
external limits or territorial boundaries and does not seek to homogenize itself
within. Individual nations, economic, regulatory, cultural entities, and nongovernmental organizations have multiple links beyond the core, and when a
country beyond the core arrives at the threshold of a sufficiently dense set of
interactions and dependencies with it, it may brought within the region’s frameworks of governance. Conceivably, this could include even regions outside the
cartographic scope of Asia, say, for instance, South Africa. At least this has
been the pattern in recent years.
Culturally, this plurality indicates a move away from an essentialist identity
formation even when different Asians consume common cultural goods. Thus,
consuming Korean television serials with the voracious appetite that has been
revealed in East and Southeast Asia does not end up transforming an identity
from, say, Vietnamese or Taiwanese to Korean. Rather, as Chua Beng Huat has
pointed out, it requires the consumer to “transcend his or her grounded nationality to forge abstract identification with the foreign characters on screen, a foreignness that is, in turn, potentially reabsorbed into an idea of (East) ‘Asia.’”35
Indeed, I am not sure that this foreignness even need be reabsorbed. The reception of the Asian cultural product can remain a site of circulation and interaction,
one that implicitly questions pure identity in the recognition of multiple connections and interdependence. It can remain without the potential of absorption into
another political project of nationalism or another grand Othering process.
In a more literary language, Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak has described a
similar ideal: “To combat the desire for an origin in a name, I propose to deal
with ‘Asia’ as the instrument of altered citation: an iteration. Indeed, the
34
Harold Sirkin, James Hemerling, and Arindam Bhattacharya, Globality: Competing with Everyone from Everywhere for Everything (New York: Business Plus, 2008).
35
Beng-huat Chua, “Conceptualizing an East Asian Popular Culture,” Inter-Asia Cultural Studies 5,
no. 2 (August 2004): 200–221.
982
Prasenjit Duara
possibility of the desire for a singular origin is in its iterability.” She points to
different “histories, languages, and idioms ‘that come forth’ each time we try
to add an ‘s’ to the wish for a unified originary name.”36 Tagore would probably
agree with Spivak. But identities are designed to emphasize exclusivity; presumably, that is their nature. Efforts to bridge differences have historically been the
loser in the era of identitarian politics heralded by the nation-state and nationalism. In addition to founding the call for heterogeneity and plurality of homelands
on textual, imaginative, and psychological grounds, I wish to emphasize our interdependence as necessary for our survival and even for individual flourishing. We
need to recognize our interdependence and foster transnational consciousness in
our education and cultural institutions, not at the cost but for the cost of our
national attachments.
In an earlier work, I argued that in pre-nationalist societies, political forces
such as imperial or feudal states did not seek to dominate every aspect of a
person’s identity. These societies were characterized by soft boundaries, where
individual community difference (say, in diet or belief in deities) would not
prevent large-scale and un-self-conscious borrowing in other respects. Modern
nationalisms sought precisely to create hard boundaries between communities
by privileging a defining characteristic of community (say language) as constitutive of the self in a self-conscious way that often developed intolerance for the
non-national Other.37 The Asian maritime networks of the precolonial era exemplified such a framework. This long-distance trade involved a wide variety of merchant communities at different points who did not speak the same languages or
trade in the same currencies. Yet as Janet Abu-Lughod says, goods were transferred, prices set, exchange rates agreed upon, contracts contracted, credit
extended, partnerships formed, records kept, and agreements honored. Trade
was contained “within the interstices of a larger collaboration in which goods
and merchants from many places were intermingled on each others’ ships and
where unwritten rules of reciprocity assured general compliance. This system
was not decisively challenged until the sixteenth century, when the Portuguese
men-of-war violated all the rules of the game.”38
I am by no means arguing that we return—or can return—to the pre-national
mode of identities; rather, I want to see whether the nationalist congruence
between state and culture exemplified by the hard boundary may have
represented a long twentieth-century moment. Certainly, the present regional
nexus resembles the earlier Asian maritime networks in terms of this noncongruence. Although the actual products flowing through the Asian maritime
networks were miniscule compared to today’s figures, the cultural flows they
36
Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak, Other Asias (Oxford: Blackwell, 2008), 217, 220.
Prasenjit Duara, Rescuing History from the Nation: Questioning Narratives of Modern China
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995), chap. 2.
38
Abu-Lughod, “The World System in the Thirteenth Century,” 11.
37
Asia Redux: Conceptualizing a Region for Our Times
983
enabled—packaged in Hinduism, Buddhism, Confucianism, Daoism, and
Islam—were nothing short of world transforming. They created interlinked cultural universes, however, that were rarely accompanied by the kind of political
domination that became hegemonic from the nineteenth century. To be sure,
today’s cultural identities are shaped by circulations of culture, knowledge, technology, goods, services, and finance that are dizzying in their velocity, while also
becoming deeply commodified or consumerist. Nonetheless, the older Asian
models of cultural circulation without state domination of identity present us
with a historical resource to explore new possibilities.
But the two dimensions of migration remind us that regional formation is
taking place under capitalist liberalization and state restructuring. While this
favors the emergence of a professional and capitalist Asian community with its
cultural openness and ability to forge multiple linkages and new cultures from
their encounter, the power of the nation-state remains entrenched in relation
to the movement—especially the transnational movement—of labor. The neoliberal circumstances under which regional formation is taking place can easily
develop the concept of Asia for the rich and their representatives who attend
to financial flows, knowledge economies, and corporatization, while containing
or displacing the poor and privatizing public goods. It is well established that
while globalization produces wealth, it also creates stratification and a deeper
gulf between the rich and the poor. Does regionalism under these circumstances
do the same? The verdict is not fully out on this, but it is clear that regionalism
possesses a greater ability to bring states and other political actors together to
address common problems and achieve common goals, if only because of the
more limited scale and recognizable commonality of problems. Of course, a
time such as the economic crisis of the present will represent a test for these
nation-states. Will they withdraw to domestic protectionism and expel foreign
elements or will they seek common solutions? In what degree will they engage
in each? Has the expansion of regional interests and interdependence only
yielded state-led and corporate modes of connecting and coordinating? If so, it
will not be easy to prevent the entrenchment of the Asian elite versus the
poor. We need to draw attention and encourage civil society organizations—
the NGOs that have mushroomed in most Asian societies over the last
few decades—to develop their linkages and guard the interests of the region
as a whole.