Regional Spillovers in
Sub-Saharan Africa
Exploring Different Channels
Francisco Arizala, Matthieu Bellon, Margaux MacDonald,
Montfort Mlachila, and Mustafa Yenice
I N T E R N A T I O N A L M O N E T A R Y F U N D
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Copyright ©2018 International Monetary Fund
Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Arizala, Francisco. | Bellon, Matthieu. | MacDonald, Margaux. | Mlachila, Montfort. | Yenice, Mustafa.
| International Monetary Fund.
Title: Regional spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa : exploring different channels / Francisco Arizala, Matthieu
Bellon, Margaux MacDonald, Montfort Miachila, and Mustafa Yenice.
Other titles: Spillover notes (International Monetary Fund) ; 12.
Description: Washington, DC : International Monetary Fund, 2018. | Spillover notes / International Monetary
Fund ; 12 | August 2018. | Includes bibliographical references.
Identifiers: ISBN 9781484367148
Subjects: LCSH: Africa, Sub-Saharan—Economic integration. | Fiscal policy—Africa, Sub-Saharan. | Financial
institutions—Africa, Sub-Saharan. | Africa, Sub-Saharan—Economic conditions.
Classification: LCC HJ1445 .R433 2018
Publication orders may be placed online, by fax, or through the mail:
International Monetary Fund, Publication Services
P.O. Box 92780, Washington, DC 20090, U.S.A.
Tel. (202) 623-7430 Fax: (202) 623-7201
E-mail:
[email protected]
www.imfbookstore.org
www.elibrary.imf.org
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
CONTENTS
Abstract 1
Introduction and Summary 1
Regional Trade Links Gaining Strength 4
Intraregional Trade Links are Growing 4
Global Comparisons 5
Banking Interdependence Becoming More Subregional 16
Presence of Foreign Banks Headquartered in Sub-Saharan Africa 16
African Bank Behavior and Trends in Correspondent Banking Relationships 20
The Dominant Role of South Africa Sovereign Spread Spillovers 21
Cross-Country Co-movement and Its Drivers 21
Estimating the Impact of South Africa 22
The Changing Pattern of Remittance Flows 22
The Foreign Direct Investment Channel—South Africa Rules the Roost 29
The Fiscal Channel—The Role of Unintended Consequences 34
Importance of Customs Unions 34
Unintended Spillovers from Nigeria’s Fuel Pricing Policies to Its Neighbors 36
The Rising Socioeconomic Impact of Forced Migration 38
Concluding Remarks 40
Appendix 41
References 43
Boxes
Box 1. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–16 Trade Flows 10
Box 2. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners 13
Box 3. Sovereign Yield Spread Spillovers 23
Box 4. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–15 Remittance Flows 27
Box 5. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances 31
Box 6. South African Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa 33
Box 7. SACU Revenue-Sharing Formula 35
Figures
Figure 1. Sub-Saharan Africa: Trade, Banking, and Remittance Channels 2
Figure 2. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Trade, 1980–2016 4
Figure 3. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Trade, Percent of GDP, 1980–2016 4
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 iii
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 4. Intraregional Exports by Region, 2016 5
Figure 5. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Exports, 2016 6
Figure 6. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Imports, 2016 6
Figure 7. Sub-Saharan Africa: Share of Intraregional Imports, 2016 7
Figure 8. Major Intraregional Trade Links 7
Figure 9. Countries with Substantial Trading Relationships from the Perspective of the Exporter 8
Figure 10. Major Intraregional Trade Relationships 8
Figure 11. Sub-Saharan Africa: Subregional Trade, 2016 9
Figure 12. Sub-Saharan Africa:Intraregional Trade by Subregions, 2016 9
Figure 13. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Exports, by Country Groups 12
Figure 14. Sub-Saharan Africa: Exports to the Rest of the World, by Country Groups 12
Figure 15. PAB and Subregional Bank Presence in SSA,2007–16 16
Figure 16. Sub-Saharan African PABs and Subregional Banks: Home and Host Countries 17
Figure 17. Systemic Foreign Owned PAB andSubregional Banks, 2007–16 18
Figure 18. Sub-Saharan Africa: Real, Financial, and Cross-Border Links 19
Figure 19. Bank Deposits in PABs and Subregional Banks,2007–16 19
Figure 20. Sub-Saharan Africa: Sovereign Spread Correlations, 2012–16 21
Figure 21. Sub-Saharan Africa: External Flows and Remittances 25
Figure 22. Remittance Inflows in Emerging and DevelopingCountries 2010–15 25
Figure 23. Sub-Saharan Africa: Remittance Outflows and Inflows, 2010–15 26
Figure 24. Sub-Saharan Africa: Major Remittance Corridors, 2010–15 27
Figure 25. Percentage Cost of Sending US$200 across Region and over Time 29
Figure 26. Total Average Cost by Remittance Sending Provider 30
Figure 27. Selected Sub-Saharan African Countries:Intraregional Foreign Direct
Investment Stock Positions 30
Figure 28. SACU Revenues and Selected Macroeconomic Indicators 36
Figure 29. Differentials between Nigerian Gasoline Prices and Those of Benin and Togo 37
Figure 30. Sub-Saharan Africa: Within Migration, Refugees 38
Figure 31. Sub-Saharan Africa and Selected Countries:Internally Displaced Persons 38
Figure 32. Selected Sub-Saharan African Countries: Civil Unrest and Terroris 39
Box Figure 3.1. South African News and Sovereign Spreads 24
Box Figure 6.1. South Africa: Outward FDIin Sub-Saharan Africa 34
Tables
Table 1. Loan-to-Deposit Ratios, Largest Sub-Saharan African Countries, 2015 20
Table 2. Fuel Prices Correlation in Togo, Benin and Nigeria, 2008–17 37
Table 1.1. Determinants of Trade Flows 11
Table 2.1. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners 14
Table 2.2. Sub-Saharan Africa and Other Developing Countries: GDP Growth Elasticities to the
Growth of Trading Partners 15
Table 3.1. Impact of Global, Regional, and Domestic Factors on Sovereign Spreads, 2012–16 24
Table 4.1. Determinants of Average Remittances Flows 28
Table 5.1. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances 32
Table 6.1. South Africa: Major Multinationals 34
Appendix Table 1. Sub-Saharan Africa: List of Country Abbreviations 41
Appendix Table 2. Sub-Saharan Africa: Member Countries of Groupings 41
Appendix Table 3. Sub-Saharan Africa: Member Countries of Regional Groupings 42
iv International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
REGIONAL SPILLOVERS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA: EXPLORING
DIFFERENT CHANNELS
Abstract
After close to two decades of strong economic activity, overall growth in sub-Saharan Africa decelerated mark-
edly in 2015–16 as the largest economies experienced negative or flat growth. Regional growth started recovering
in 2017, but the question remains of how trends in the economies stuck in low gear will spill over to the countries
that have maintained robust growth. This note illuminates the discussion by identifying growth spillover channels.
The focus is on trade, banking, financial, remittance, investment, fiscal, and security channels, which are the most
prominent and most likely to transmit growth trends across borders. In addition to bringing together findings from
a broad array of existing research, the note identifies countries that are the most likely sources of regional spillovers
and those that are most likely to be impacted, and provides estimates for the size of these channels. It finds that
intraregional trade and remittance flows are an important channel for growth spillovers, while banking channels are
less important but will remain a risk going forward. Finally, the note documents other important spillover channels
through financial markets contagion, revenue-sharing arrangements in fiscal unions, commodity-pricing poli-
cies, corporate investment, and forced migration. The main takeaway is that the level of interdependence among
sub-Saharan countries is higher than is generally assumed. Consequently, there is a need for additional emphasis on
regional surveillance and spillover analysis, along with traditional bilateral surveillance.
Introduction and Summary failed to show large spillovers across the region. It also
After close to two decades of strong economic activ- assesses a variety of spillover channels, whose impor-
ity, overall growth in sub-Saharan Africa decelerated tance varies across countries, reflecting the heterogene-
markedly in 2015–16, to its lowest level in more than ity of economic structures in sub-Saharan Africa.
20 years at 1.4 percent. However, this average masked The note covers well-known channels as well as
substantial heterogeneity across the region. While the those that have received less attention in the literature.
largest economies (Nigeria and South Africa) experi- It does this by using several methodologies and draw-
enced negative or flat growth, a third of the countries ing on studies that have identified transmission chan-
in the region continued to grow at 5 percent or more nels and mechanisms, and by breaking new ground
during the period. As growth has begun to recover empirically in areas in which the existing literature is
since 2017 on the back of a more favorable external silent. In all cases, the note systematically updates pre-
environment, the question remains: to what extent do viously known stylized facts and empirical estimates.
growth trends in the largest economies spill over to the It identifies countries that are likely to be the origin of
rest of sub-Saharan Africa? In particular, will trends in economic spillovers and countries more likely to be at
the economies stuck in low gear spill over to countries the receiving end, provides new empirical estimates of
that have maintained robust growth? the size of various spillover channels, and documents
This note focuses on identifying the channels and new channels of transmission not previously identified
impacts of intraregional spillovers in sub-Saharan in the literature (Figure 1).
Africa. The note goes beyond existing studies that Regional trade links are steadily gaining strength.
rely on aggregate growth data and that have typically Countries that absorb most intraregional exports and
hence have the highest potential to generate regional
spillovers are identified, as well as countries that are
The authors would like to thank Anne-Marie Gulde-Wolf for her
overall guidance of the project, as well as the Spillover Task Force, more exposed to spillovers from other countries in the
Céline Allard, Jesus Gonzalez-Garcia, Miguel Pereira Mendes, and region. The note also discusses the following findings:
several IMF colleagues for very helpful comments and suggestions. •• Intraregional trade has steadily increased in intensity
Natasha Minges provided excellent editorial assistance, Joe
Procopio edited the manuscript, and Heidi Grauel provided layout.
over time. It represented 6 percent of total exports
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 1
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 1. Sub-Saharan Africa: Trade, Banking, and Remittance •• Some countries are highly exposed to intraregional
Channels
demand. Exports to the top 10 destinations
More likely to generate spillovers
More likely to suffer from spillovers represent between 5 percent and 10 percent of
More likely to generate spillovers and suffer from spillovers source-country GDP.
1. Trade Channel •• Subregional trade accounts for most of sub-Saharan
African regional trade. Southern Africa Customs
Union (SACU) subregional trade alone represents
half of total sub-Saharan Africa intraregional trade.
Moreover, in the cases of the Southern Africa
Development Community (SADC) and the SACU,
subregional trade represents more than 80 percent of
their member countries’ intraregional trade.
•• Econometric analysis shows that bilateral trade is
more likely to be hindered by distance and socio-
cultural differences in sub-Saharan Africa than in
2. Banking Channel the rest of the world, which explains why most
regional trade occurs within subregions. Moreover,
econometric estimates suggest that about half of
the growth in regional trade over 1980–2016 stems
from subregional trade integration, in particu-
lar within the East African Community (EAC)
and the SADC.
•• The growth of regional trading partners has a
significant effect on individual countries’ growth,
even after controlling for variables capturing
co-movement at the global and regional levels.
3. Remittances Channel Econometric estimates suggest that a 5 percentage
point increase in the export-weighted growth rate
of intraregional partners is associated with about
a 0.5 percent increase in the average sub-Saharan
African country’s growth.
Beyond pan-African banks, subregional banks are
emerging, and South Africa plays a significant role
in determining sovereign debt spreads in sub-Saha-
ran Africa frontier markets. The rising importance of
subregional banks is highlighted, and countries with
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database;
the highest exposure to pan-African banks (PABs) and
and IMF staff calculations. subregional banks are identified. The note also finds:
•• Strong intraregional banking links represent a
growing channel of potential spillovers. In terms
(1 percent of GDP) in 1980 before taking off in of market participation, the share of PABs and
the early 1990s and eventually reaching 20 percent subregional banking groups in sub-Saharan African
(4 percent of GDP) in 2016. financial system is increasing, following a global
•• The key players in the total demand for intra- trend of banking regionalization.
regional exports (that is, the countries with the •• A few sub-Saharan African countries are identified
potential to generate the largest regional spillovers) as being the primary countries of origin of banking
are highly concentrated. Ten countries account for spillovers. While there is considerable overlap among
65 percent of total regional demand. the countries that are home to PABs and subregional
2 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
banks, the spillover recipient countries are more •• Firms from South Africa that are searching for diver-
widely dispersed. sification opportunities in relatively faster growing
•• Growth in countries that are home to PABs and regional African markets dominate the landscape.
subregional banks is associated with private sector •• The lion’s share of investment is in services, trade,
credit growth in the countries in which they oper- and the financial sector.
ate, which itself has reinforcing effects on growth in
those countries. Significant unintended spillovers exist from fiscal
•• There are links from changes in the spread on South policies in the largest countries. The note covers how
African sovereign debt to other sub-Saharan African these fiscal channels develop via large fluctuations of
frontier markets. The global and emerging market tax receipts in customs unions and via negative exter-
financial cycles have a major impact on all issuing nalities arising from different fuel pricing policies in
sub-Saharan countries, including South Africa, but neighboring countries.
there is also evidence of specific spillovers from •• The SACU revenue-sharing formula ties member
South Africa. countries’ fiscal revenues to economic developments
in South Africa. While providing certainty for
Remittances from within sub-Saharan Africa are current revenue, the formula leads to high levels of
becoming relatively more important. The key players volatility over the medium term. As a result, it com-
in terms of regional remittance outflows (with the plicates fiscal management in the smallest countries
potential to generate the largest regional spillovers) (Lesotho and Swaziland).
are identified, as well as the countries most exposed •• Subsidized fuel in Nigeria leads to widespread
to remittance spillovers. In further analysis, the smuggling and to the erosion of the tax base in
note also finds: Benin and Togo. For instance, for Benin, only about
•• Growth in regional remittances has outpaced the 15 percent of the fuel consumed is purchased on the
growth of other external sources of financing such as formal (taxed) market.
aid, foreign direct investment (FDI), and remit-
tances from the rest of the world. The socioeconomic costs of forced migration are
•• Remittance flows are rather concentrated in a few rising. The note analyzes the socioeconomic impact
corridors, and in some countries regional remittance of forced migration owing to conflict and secu-
inflows represent a substantial share of income. In rity concerns.
particular, Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana are important •• The share of forced migration across countries in
sources for West Africa, and South Africa is an sub-Saharan Africa declined significantly through
important source for Southern and East Africa. most of the 1990s and 2000s, but the pace of
•• Recent reductions in the cost to send money across decline has slowed or partially reversed.
borders are associated with the development of •• Terrorism and civil conflict in the Sahel, the Lake
mobile money and explain part of the observed Chad area, the eastern Democratic Republic of the
increase in regional remittances. The cost of sending Congo, Somalia, and South Sudan have been the
remittances in sub-Saharan Africa are the highest in main drivers of involuntary migration.
the world, implying that there is room for further •• The main negative spillovers of forced migration
cost reductions and increases in regional remittances. studied here are reduced economic activity, human-
•• Growth in countries that send remittances is found itarian damage, and the fiscal costs of hosting
to be significantly associated with growth in receiv- displaced persons and fighting terrorism.
ing countries. A 5 percent increase in the growth of
remittance partners is estimated to raise growth by The key takeaways from this note are that regional
0.5 percent, although this is partially outweighed by integration in its various forms is more extensive than
trading partners’ growth spillovers. generally assumed and that subregional integration is
moving faster than overall integration. Spillover chan-
South Africa is the dominant source of regional nels for the largest economies are diverse. For South
FDI. This note analyzes the corporate sector and dis- Africa, spillovers are via trade, banking, and remittance
cusses the following: channels, while Nigerian spillovers are mainly through
banking, fuel pricing policy, and trade (in the case of
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 3
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 2. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Trade, 1980–2016
25
Regional exports to total exports
Regional imports to total imports
20 Total regional trade to total trade
15
Percent
10
5
0
1980 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Calculation based on weighted averages.
its neighboring countries). Overall, the potential for Intraregional Trade Links Are Growing
spillovers—both positive and negative—is higher than The increase in intraregional trade integration in
previously found in the literature. sub-Saharan Africa over the past 35 years has amplified
the potential for intraregional spillovers. Sub-Saharan
African economies have become more open to and
Regional Trade Links Gaining Strength
integrated with global and intraregional trade, a
Sub-Saharan African economies have become more trend that is marked by the increase in regional trade
open to and integrated with global and intraregional as a share of total trade. Regional trade represented
trade. This trend has been marked by an increase in 6 percent of total exports in 1980 before taking off in
regional trade as a share of total trade, which has ampli- the early 1990s and eventually reaching 20 percent in
fied the potential for regional spillovers. Fluctuations in 2016 (Figure 2). These increases in regional trade have
the economic activity of intraregional trading partners been significant relative to the size of sub-Saharan Afri-
affect the growth of individual countries in the region. can economies; they have been faster for small coun-
tries in the region, as reflected by the faster growth in
the simple average level of trade integration (Figure 3).
Figure 3. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Trade, Percent of GDP, 1980–2016
8
Regional exports to GDP, weighted average
7 Regional exports to GDP, simple average
6
Percent of GDP
5
4
3
2
1
0
1980 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
4 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 4. Intraregional Exports by Region, 2016
1. Intraregional exports 2. Intraregional exports
(Percent of total exports) (Percent of GDP)
40 Exports to total exports (weighted) 10 Percent of GDP (weighted)
Exports to total exports (simple) 9 Percent of GDP (simple)
35
8
30
Percent of total exports
Percent of total exports
7
25 6
20 5
15 4
3
10
2
5 1
0 0
SSA MENA Emedev Asia CIS Latin America MENA CIS SSA Emedev Asia Latin America
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: CIS = Commonwealth of Independent States; EMEDEV = Emerging and Developing economies; MENA = Middle East and North Africa. SSA = sub-Saharan Africa.
The increase in global and regional trade integra- regional spillovers—is broadly in line with levels in
tion is the result of global developments but also of other regions (Figure 4.1 and 4.2). Measured as a share
a strengthening of institutional and macroeconomic of total exports, sub-Saharan Africa exhibits the highest
conditions in the region. Part of the increase in global share of intraregional trade integration among emerg-
trade can be explained by the twofold increase in the ing and developing regions, followed by the Middle
relative price of commodity exports over the period East and North Africa and emerging and developing
1995–2013. Another part is explained by volumes of Asia. Relative to the size of the economy, sub-Saharan
exported commodities, which increased by two and Africa is in the middle of the pack.
a half times over the same period (Allard and others
2016). In addition to these supporting conditions, the Countries Most Exposed to Regional Trade Spillovers
sub-Saharan Africa region has experienced a substantial Although significant heterogeneity exists among
strengthening of macroeconomic policies and political sub-Saharan African countries in terms of intraregional
and economic institutions over the past 20 years, along trade integration, many of them are highly connected
with an abatement of internal and external conflicts to other countries in the region (Figures 5 and 6). This
and, in some cases, countries exiting fragility. These is particularly the case within subregions. For example,
elements all contributed to improving the business in several countries in the SACU (such as Swaziland
environment and supported the deepening of regional and Lesotho) and in other small and very open econ-
trade (IMF 2015a). Furthermore, the establishment omies (such as Togo and The Gambia) intraregional
of regional trade agreements in various subregions has exports represent more than 65 percent of total exports
contributed to regional and bilateral reductions in (IMF 2012).1 Also, export shares can be large relative
tariffs, which have further supported trade integration to the size of the economy. This is the case for Zimba-
(ODI 2010). Compared with advanced economies, bwe and certain SACU members (Botswana, Lesotho,
intraregional trade remains low and the business Namibia), where intraregional exports represent about
environment remains challenging, but the direction has 20 percent of GDP, and some Western Africa Eco-
been favorable over time. nomic and Monetary Union (WAEMU) countries
(Côte d’Ivoire, Guinea, Senegal), where they constitute
close to 10 percent of GDP.
Global Comparisons
The average level of regional trade integration
in sub-Saharan Africa—and thus the potential for 1The SACU comprises Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, South Africa,
and Swaziland.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 5
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 5. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Exports, 2016
100 25
Exports to total exports
90 Exports to GDP (right axis)
80 20
Percent of total exports
70
Percent of GDP
60 15
50
40 10
30
20 5
10
0 0
SWZ
ZWE
GMB
TGO
LSO
BDI
SEN
MWI
NAM
SLE
KEN
ZAF
CAF
BEN
ZMB
COD
MOZ
GIN
MUS
GNB
MLI
COG
NER
CMR
LBR
MDG
ETH
AGO
STP
GNQ
COM
GAB
SYC
ERI
TCD
CIV
CPV
RWA
UGA
TZA
BWA
BFA
NGA
GHA
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Swaziland’s exports-to-GDP ratio is not shown; it was equal to 62 percent in 2016. See page 41 for country abbreviations tables.
Countries More Likely to Generate Regional chains and re-exports. In most of the top 10 importing
Trade Spillovers countries, intraregional imports primarily consist of
Regional demand for intraregional exports is con- manufactures, fuels, and food. An economic decelera-
centrated in a very few countries. Ten sub-Saharan tion in any of these countries thus has the potential to
countries represent 65 percent of total regional weaken demand for intraregional exports and may be a
demand for intraregional exports, with South Africa, source of wider negative spillovers.
Botswana, and Namibia accounting for the largest Imports absorbed by the top 10 regional importers
shares of total regional demand, and South Africa of sub-Saharan African intraregional trade represent
alone importing 15 percent of total intraregional significant shares of the economies of the exporting
exports (Figure 7). These SACU member countries countries, setting the stage for potentially large spill-
trade significantly among themselves, with exports con- overs. The strength of this channel is commensurate
centrated mainly in manufactures, food, and machin- with the importance of the importer’s demand relative
ery, often in the context of regional or global value to the size of the exporting country’s economy. For
Figure 6. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Imports, 2016
90 60
Imports to total imports
80 Imports to GDP (right axis)
50
70
Percent of total imports
60 40
Percent of GDP
50
30
40
30 20
20
10
10
0 0
LSO
ZWE
SWZ
NAM
ZMB
COD
MLI
MOZ
MWI
STP
BDI
TCD
CMR
GNB
GMB
SYC
BEN
COM
NER
SEN
MUS
SLE
TGO
ZAF
COG
MDG
GIN
KEN
GNQ
CAF
AGO
GAB
ERI
ETH
SSD
CIV
CPV
BWA
RWA
BFA
UGA
TZA
GHA
NGA
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Swaziland’s imports-to-GDP ratio is not shown; it was equal to 81 percent in 2016. See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
6 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 7. Sub-Saharan Africa: Share of Intraregional Imports, 2016
16
Other resource-intensive countries
14 Non-resource-intensive countries
Oil exporters
Percent of total regional imports
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
ZAF BWA NAM ZMB ZWE SWZ CIV COD MOZ COG
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
Figure 8. Major Intraregional Trade Links (Major importers perspective)
CPV COG COD
GAB CMR
GHA CIV
GIN BWA
GMB BFA
GNB BEN
GNQ BDI
KEN AGO
LBR ZWE
LSO ZMB
MDG ZAF
MOZ UGA
MUS TZA
MWI TGO
NAM SYC
NGA
RWA SEN SLE SWZ
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and
IMF staff calculations.
Note: The thickness of the arrows refers to the size of bilateral exports in percent of GDP of the
exporting country. The top 10 destinations are in red; the other countries in blue. See page 41
for country abbreviations table.
instance, South African imports from Swaziland, Leso- sub-Saharan African intraregional exports, import more
tho, Zimbabwe, and Mozambique represent between than 1 percent of GDP of their subregional trading
4 percent and 11 percent of these economies’ GDP. partners.2 Indeed, for four countries in the region,
Similarly, Zimbabwe’s total demand for goods from their exports to Nigeria and Mali represent more
Zambia, Malawi, and Botswana constitutes between than 1 percent of their economy, making them also
1 percent and 4 percent of these countries’ GDP potential sources of intraregional spillovers (Figures 9
(Figure 8). and 10).3
Other countries import non-negligible shares of
their neighbors’ GDP and can be a substantial source 2Informal trade (not captured by official statistics) between Nige-
of spillovers at the subregional level. This is the case for ria and its neighbors may be economically important for the smaller
Nigeria, Mali, Ghana, and Burkina Faso, which, even countries (Balami, Ogboru, and Talba 2011).
3Similarly, for 10 countries in the region, their exports to South
though they do not import substantial shares of total
Africa represent more than 1 percent of their GDP.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 7
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 9. Countries with Substantial Trading Relationships from the Perspective of the Exporter
10
9
8
7
Number of countries
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
ZAF NGA MLI ZWE BWA GHA BFA COG ZMB SWZ
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: In the above chart, number of countries for which the country is a destination market representing more than 1 percent of
GDP of the sender’s economy.
See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
Figure 10. Major Intraregional Trade Relationships (Exporter’s perspective)
GHA GAB CPV COG
GIN COD
GMB CMR
GNB CIV
GNQ BWA
KEN BFA
LBR BEN
LSO AGO
MDG ZWE
MLI ZMB
MOZ ZAF
MUS UGA
MWI TZA
NAM TGO
NER SYC
NGA SWZ
RWA SEN SLE STP
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff
calculations.
Note: Blue and red dots indicate exporting and importing countries, respectively. The size of the red
dots is proportional to the number of countries for which the country is a destination market
representing more than 1 percent of GDP of the exporter’s economy. The thickness of the arrows
refers to the size of bilateral exports in percent of GDP of the exporting country. See page 41 for
country abbreviations table.
The Role of Subregional Trade Concentration rest of the region (Figure 11).4 In the Central African
Trade spillovers are more likely to take place within Economic and Monetary Community (CEMAC) and
subregions, as most regional trade is concentrated at the WAEMU regions, the concentration is less pro-
the subregional level. In the SADC, the SACU, and
the EAC, subregional trade accounts for more than 4The SADC comprises Angola, Botswana, Democratic Republic of
70 percent of their total trade with sub-Saharan Africa, the Congo, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique,
Namibia, Seychelles, South Africa, Swaziland, Tanzania, Zambia, and
reflecting the fact that member countries are mostly Zimbabwe. All SACU member countries are also part of the SADC.
integrated within themselves rather than with the The EAC includes Burundi, Kenya, Uganda, Rwanda, South Sudan,
and Tanzania.
8 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 11. Sub-Saharan Africa: Subregional Trade, 2016 Figure 12. Sub-Saharan Africa:
(Percent of the subregional exports to sub-Saharan Africa) Intraregional Trade by Subregions, 2016
(Percent of total sub-Saharan Africa trade)
100
Export
80
90 Import Export
70 Import
80
70 60
60
50
Percent
50
Percent
40
40
30 30
20 20
10
10
0
SADC SACU EAC CEMAC WAEMU 0
SADC SACU WAEMU EAC CEMAC
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: CEMAC = Central African Economic and Monetary Community; EAC = East Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database; and IMF staff calculations.
African Community; SACU = Southern African Customs Union; SADC = Southern Note: CEMAC = Central African Economic and Monetary Community; EAC = East
African Development Community; WAEMU = West African Economic and African Community; SACU = Southern African Customs Union; SADC = Southern
Monetary Union. African Development Community; WAEMU = West African Economic and
Monetary Union.
nounced, but subregional trade nonetheless represents
half of their intraregional trade. These significant shares 2016). The results also suggest that subregional trade
of subregional trade point to the importance of con- agreements played a major role in strengthening bilat-
sidering subregions explicitly when assessing potential eral trade in the region, in particular for countries in
spillovers. the SADC and the EAC (see Box 1).
In absolute terms, a few subregions account for most The Role of the Economic Structure
of total sub-Saharan Africa intraregional trade. The
SADC and the SACU account for more than 70 per- Regional trade integration in sub-Saharan Africa
cent and 50 percent of total sub-Saharan Africa trade, and its potential to generate intraregional spillovers
respectively (Figure 12). Other subregions represent a varies substantially depending on the natural resource
smaller share of total sub-Saharan African intraregional endowment of a country. Non-resource-intensive coun-
trade, with the WAEMU, EAC, and CEMAC account- tries are the most exposed to regional demand, with
ing for less than 10 percent each. The overall pattern of intraregional exports accounting for 7 percent of GDP
high subregional integration reflects not only geo- and 30 percent of total exports, on average (Figure 13).
graphic proximity but also infrastructure constraints They are followed closely by non-oil-resource-intensive
and the impact of regional trade agreements and lower countries (“other”). In terms of demand concentration,
nontariff trade barriers within subregions. these other resource-intensive countries have the largest
Empirical estimates suggest that trade in the region share of imports from the region, constituting 30 per-
is larger between countries that are culturally and cent of total imports. Oil-producing countries have
geographically closer and that regional trade growth distinct trading relationships compared with the other
over the past four decades is mostly explained by groups and are notably more oriented toward the rest
subregional integration. A trade gravity equation of the world. Exports from oil-producing countries to
estimation shows that bilateral trade in the region is the rest of the world amount to 25 percent of GDP,
greater among countries that are separated by a smaller while intraregional exports represent only 1.5 percent
distance and that share a common currency, language, of GDP (Figures 13 and 14); thus, the latter group is
ethnicity, and colonial heritage. Cross-region compar- relatively less likely to suffer from intraregional spill-
isons show that distance is a great barrier to trade in overs through the trade channel.
sub-Saharan Africa, possibly because of the well-known
infrastructure gaps in the region (Allard and others
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 9
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 1. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–16 Trade Flows
A gravity model of bilateral trade flows over the logF ijt = β X ij + θ o I i∈SSA . X ij + θ d I j∈SSA . X ij + γ it +
period 1980–2016 is estimated to study the determi- δ jt + ε ijt . ( 3)
nants of regional trade integration. In all specifications,
This specification allows us to investigate whether
the sample includes annual data from the Direction of
distance plays a specific role for export flows within
Trade Statistics (DOTS) database with all the country
sub-Saharan Africa. Coefficient estimates θ o and θ d
pairs in the world that exchanged goods at least once.
of these interaction variables, respectively, reflect the
The first specification is as follows:
differential effects of distance for sub-Saharan Africa
logF ijt = α i + ϕ j + θ t + β X ijt + β xr xr ijt + γ Y it + δ origin and destination countries. Table 1.1, column
Z jt + ε ijt , (1) 3, is composed of three subcolumns; the coefficient
estimates θ oare reported in the second subcolumn
where F ijtis the logarithm of export values in dol-
while estimates θ dare reported in the third. The
lars from country i to country j; X ijt corresponds
results indicate that distance is a greater hindrance
to corridor-specific variables, including geographic
when exporting to sub-Saharan destinations and
distance and dummy variables indicating whether the
that having belonged to the same colony is a greater
countries share a common official language, share the
benefit in sub-Saharan Africa. Also, compared with
same ethnic group, share the same colonial origin,
other regions, sub-Saharan African exports are even
share a common official religion, or share a currency;
larger between countries that share a language and a
xr ijt corresponds to bilateral exchange rates; and Yit
colonial background. Finally, the distance between two
and Zjt , respectively, refer to the logarithms of GDP
sub-Saharan countries deters trade significantly more
per capita and population in the origin and destina-
than between other countries, as shown by a Wald test
tion countries. The specification includes country fixed
(p-value of 0.02).
effects, α i and ϕ
j, to control for country time-invariant
Table 1.1, column 4, explores whether trade integra-
characteristics, as well as time effects, θ t, to control for
tion occurred faster as of 2016 between countries that
all annual shocks common to all countries.
belonged to the same economic union: the WAEMU,
The specification in Table 1.1, column 2 includes
CEMAC, EAC, SADC and SACU (see main text
country-time fixed effects, γ itand δ jt, to control for all
for region definitions). The following specification is
country variable characteristics. The corridor variables
estimated:
X ijin equation (1) are kept but the country-level char-
acteristics (population and GDP) are dropped, as these logF ijt = α ij + γ it + δ jt + β (X ij . t) + ϕ 1 I waemu . t +
characteristics are absorbed by the country-time fixed
ϕ 2 I cemac . t + ϕ 3 I eac . t+ ϕ5 Ieac. t + ϕ 4 I sacu . t + ε ijt , (4)
effects. Hence, the results presented in column 2 refer
to the specification: where country-time, δ jtand γ it, and country-pair, α ij,
fixed effects are included; corridor fixed characteristics
logF ijt = β X ij + γ it + δ jt + ε ijt. ( 2)
are interacted with a time trend, ( X ij . t); and member-
Estimation results in the first two columns of ships to a common subregion are respectively inter-
Table 1.1 show that distance significantly hampers acted with a time trend.
trade flows across countries. The first column addition- As shown in column 4, there is statistically signif-
ally shows that exports increase significantly with both icant evidence that integration among members of
population and GDP per capita of both the origin the EAC and the SADC was particularly successful
and destination countries, and are also higher between in fostering trade. This relationship holds even after
partners that share a common language, ethnicity, and controlling for developments in individual countries
colonial heritage. Bilateral exchange rates do not have when country-time effects are introduced. Quantita-
a significant effect on bilateral trade flows. tively, trade among members of the EAC increased
In Table 1.1, column 3, all countries in the world by an additional 4 percent per year on average while
(including those not in sub-Saharan Africa) are trade among members of the SADC increased by an
included. The specification is also richer, as interaction additional 2 percent per year. Using these estimates
variables between measures of distance and a dummy to compute what trade would have been without
variable for either sub-Saharan Africa origin countries subregional integration, we finds that average annual
(Ii∈SSA
. X ij) or sub-Saharan Africa destination countries growth in regional trade would have been about
(Ij∈SSA
. Xij ) are introduced: 9 percent instead of 11 percent, thereby translating
10 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 1. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–16 Trade Flows (continued)
into trade levels that would be half as low as those barrier, meaning that the infrastructure facilitating
observed in 2015. In addition, the coefficient on the trade among economic unions has lagged relative to
interaction between distance and time suggests that in the development of infrastructure within unions.
sub-Saharan Africa, distance has increasingly become a
Table 1.1. Determinants of Trade Flows
Dependent variable: logarithm of bilateral trade flows
(3)
(1) (2) Coefficient estimates for (4)
Country controls Country FE All countries SSA origin SSA destination Time trends
Contiguous countries 1.57*** 1.53*** 0.48*** 20.00
(0.21) (0.21) (0.11) (0.01)
Distance (in log) 21.60*** 21.60*** 21.60*** 0.18 20.40*** 20.02***
(0.09) (0.09) (0.04) (0.11) (0.11) (0.00)
Common language 0.46*** 0.45*** 0.54*** 0.17 20.11 0.01
(0.15) (0.14) (0.10) (0.14) (0.15) (0.01)
Common ethnicity 0.24* 0.30** 0.21** 20.27** 0.21* 0.01
(0.14) (0.13) (0.09) (0.14) (0.12) (0.01)
Belonged to common 1.44*** 1.37*** 0.81*** 1.16*** 0.74*** 20.00
colony (0.13) (0.12) (0.11) (0.20) (0.19) (0.01)
Common religion 0.14 0.14 0.25*** 20.01 20.04 0.00
(0.14) (0.13) (0.06) (0.16) (0.13) (0.01)
Common currency 1.22*** 1.28*** 0.40 0.99**
(0.31) (0.31) (0.29) (0.39)
Origin GDP p.c. 0.49***
(0.06)
Destination GDP p.c. 0.48***
(0.13)
Origin population 0.70**
(0.30)
Destination population 2.41***
(0.24)
Origin/destination 0.00
FX rate (0.01)
WAEMU trend 0.00
(0.01)
CEMAC trend 0.00
(0.01)
EAC trend 0.04*
(0.02)
SADC trend 0.02**
(0.01)
SACU trend 0.09
(0.07)
Observations 92,132 95,711 556,476 95,108
R-squared 0.52 0.57 0.73 0.77
Year FE YES NO NO NO
Country FE YES NO NO NO
Country-time FE NO YES YES YES
Country-pair FE NO NO NO YES
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: In all specifications, the standard errors are clustered at the destination country level to control for possible unobserved correlation within
importing countries. CEMAC 5 Central African Economic and Monetary Community; EAC 5 East African Community; SACU 5 Southern African
Customs Union; SADC 5 Southern African Development Community; WAEMU 5 West African Economic and Monetary Union. Clustered standard
errors in parentheses (Destination country) ***p 0.01, ** p 0.05, *p 0.1.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 11
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 13. Sub-Saharan Africa: Intraregional Exports, by Country Groups
(Simple average)
35 Percent of total exports in 2016
Percent of GDP in 2016
30 Percent of total exports in 2000–15
Percent in GDP 2000–15
25
20
Percent
15
10
5
0
Non-resource intensive Other resource-intensive Oil exporters
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: See page 41 for country groupings table.
Intraregional Trade and Growth China, whose increased market for sub-Saharan Afri-
Sub-Saharan African countries’ growth depends can exports has been shown to be an important driver
on fluctuations in the economic activity of regional of growth in the region (Chen and Nord 2017).
trading partners and global developments. A panel Consistent with having comparable shares of intra-
regression model for all sub-Saharan African countries regional trade, the trade channel spillovers seem to be
for the period 1980–2016 suggests that a 1 percent- similar in sub-Saharan Africa and in other emerging
age point increase in the export-weighted growth and developing economies. Panel regression estimates
rate of intraregional partners is associated with about for countries in the Middle East and North Africa,
a 0.11 percent increase in the average sub-Saharan Latin America, and emerging and developing Asia sug-
African country’s growth (Box 2). These results were gest that sub-Saharan African countries have a slightly
obtained after accounting for extraregional factors such lower intraregional elasticity of growth compared with
as terms of trade movements and demand from trading peers in Latin America and emerging and developing
partners outside the region, including countries such as Asia, but a higher one than those estimated for coun-
tries in the Middle East and North Africa (Box 2).
Figure 14. Sub-Saharan Africa: Exports to the Rest of the World, by Country Groups
(Simple average)
45
2016 2000–15
40
35
30
Percent of GDP
25
20
15
10
5
0
Oil exporters Other resource-intensive Non-resource intensive
Sources: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics database, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: See page 41 for country groupings table.
12 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 2. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners
A panel fixed effect model is estimated to study the column 8), as is customary in the growth literature.
elasticity of GDP growth in sub-Saharan African coun- The latter allows the model to minimize serial cor-
tries to the growth of the trading partners inside and relation, which is likely to be present in annual data.
outside the region. The model is specified as follows: This specification includes the initial level of GDP per
capita to capture growth convergence. Country fixed
RealGDPgrowth it = α + γ i + β 1
effects, γ i, are included to control for time-invariant
RealGDPgrowth t−1,i + β 2 RealGDPgrowth t−2,i
country-specific heterogeneity, and standard errors are
+ β 3 SSAtradingpartnergrowth t,i + β 4 Non −
clustered at the country level to control for possible
SSAtradingpartnergrowth t,i + β 5 X it + e it (1)
unobserved correlation across countries.
where the left-hand variable is the annual rate of The estimation includes all sub-Saharan African
growth of real GDP, sub-Saharan African trading countries over the period 1980–2016. The lagged
partner growth refers to the weighted average rate time-varying weights reflect the annual share of
of growth of the trading partners from sub-Saharan exports going to each specific partner as reported in
Africa for each country at time t. Non-sub-Saharan the IMF Direction of Trade Statistics. The baseline
Africa trading partner growth corresponds to the specification suggests that a 1 percentage point increase
weighted average rate of growth of the trading partners in the export-weighted growth rate of intraregional
from outside the region for each country at time t partners is associated with about a 0.11 percent
(Arora and Vamvakidis 2005; Chen and Nord 2017). increase in the average sub-Saharan African country
The weights used in averaging refer to export shares growth rate (Table 2.1, column 1). This estimate
in the previous year. The vector X of controls includes is robust across multiple specifications (Table 2.1,
variables capturing regional and global growth dynam- column 5). The baseline specification also finds that a
ics, as measured by the average rate of growth of the 1 percentage point increase in the growth rate of the
region and the world. trading partners outside the region is associated with
The model includes country-specific controls in X: an increase of 0.34 percent in the growth rate of the
lags of the dependent variable, the rate of investment average sub-Saharan African country. This coefficient
to GDP, the inflation rate, and the level of trade seems to capture other external environment factors,
openness. This allows the coefficient of interest to such as the changes in the terms of trade and the
more clearly identify the effect of the regional trading degree of openness of the economy, as evidenced by
partners’ growth on individual countries, once the the results in column 2.
average growth co-movements in the continent and in These results are robust to the inclusion of other
the world are isolated. In addition, the model controls controls that capture structural factors such as
for the occurrence of conflict and war, as captured investment-to-GDP and population growth, and
by the Uppsala Conflict Data Program. As part of other monetary controls such as global liquidity,
the control vector X, variables capturing the external inflation, and exchange rate movements. The regres-
environment are also included: fluctuations in the sions results are also robust to implementing a panel
terms of trade, and the degree of trade openness of generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation
the economy and the share of regional exports in total to account for the endogeneity in a dynamic-panel
exports. Other controls include a measure of interna- context (Table 2.1, column 5). Results are robust to
tional liquidity as captured by the change in the Fed the exclusion of large economies (Table 2.1, column
funds rate, a measure of the monetary policy stance in 6). Introducing interaction variables fails to capture
the United States, the country inflation rate, and the heterogeneous effects, as the new variables are insig-
change in the bilateral exchange rate with respect to nificant (Table 2.1, column 7). This means that more
the US dollar. open economies are not significantly more exposed
As a robustness check, the 10 percent largest econo- to spillovers, suggesting that the nature of trade in
mies are excluded from the estimation sample: Angola, more open economies prevents them from being
Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria, and South Africa (Table 2.1, more exposed to variation in partners’ demand. Using
column 6); an interaction term between countries’ five-year averages to analyze the medium-term deter-
openness and their partners’ average growth is added minants of economic growth finds that the growth
(Table 2.1, column 7); and a specification using of the regional trading partners continues to play an
five-year averages of the data is estimated (Table 2.1, important role in individual countries’ rate of growth,
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 13
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 2. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners (continued)
Table 2.1. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners
Dependent variable: real GDP growth
(2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
(1) Openness Structural Monetary GMM Excluding Exposure GMM, 5–year
Baseline controls controls controls estimation 10% largest heterogeneity averages
Real GDP growth (t–1) 0.318*** 0.299*** 0.292*** 0.284*** 0.264*** 0.255*** 0.264*** 0.410***
(0.0821) (0.0734) (0.0771) (0.0789) (0.0678) (0.0749) (0.0681) (0.0632)
Real GDP growth (t–2) 20.0180 20.0374 20.0452* 20.0551** 20.0770* 20.0736* 20.0863*
(0.0202) (0.0247) (0.0244) (0.0260) (0.0405) (0.0413) (0.0454)
SSA trading partners’ growth 0.113* 0.114* 0.111* 0.120* 0.133** 0.110* 0.184*** 0.0761**
(0.0636) (0.0597) (0.0573) (0.0605) (0.0610) (0.0622) (0.0658) (0.0354)
Non2SSA trading partners’ 0.348* 0.265 0.251 0.252 0.334 0.306 20.0842 0.0118
growth (0.184) (0.161) (0.161) (0.164) (0.238) (0.238) (0.249) (0.0437)
SSA average growth 0.288** 0.0870 0.124 0.0739 0.0526 0.0124 0.0265 20.117
(0.115) (0.202) (0.192) (0.214) (0.280) (0.260) (0.278) (0.268)
World average growth 20.0391 0.210 0.198 0.221 0.108 0.107 0.0794 4.943***
(0.139) (0.201) (0.224) (0.233) (0.255) (0.269) (0.235) (1.761)
Conflict year, Uppsala 24.548*** 23.722*** 23.527*** 23.810*** 23.913*** 23.119** 23.717*** 24.267
database (0.900) (1.047) (1.029) (1.081) (1.287) (1.377) (1.392) (2.871)
Terms of trade, percent 0.138*** 0.153*** 0.0936* 0.0881* 0.0928 0.110* 20.0361
change (0.0457) (0.0529) (0.0470) (0.0485) (0.0594) (0.0662) (0.374)
Trade openness (t–1) 0.0524* 0.0466* 0.0522* 0.0844 0.0908 0.0710 0.0915
(0.0305) (0.0270) (0.0296) (0.0585) (0.0624) (0.0500) (0.0557)
Share of regional exports in 3.108* 3.153* 3.426* 1.561 2.267 0.448 20.311
total exports (t–1) (1.604) (1.750) (1.961) (2.888) (2.801) (1.876) (2.103)
Investment, percent of GDP 0.0460 0.0483 0.0608 0.0587 0.0638 0.0877**
(t–1) (0.0378) (0.0393) (0.0579) (0.0576) (0.0573) (0.0383)
Percent change in 0.376 0.394 0.489 0.478 0.448 0.440***
population (0.391) (0.443) (0.341) (0.355) (0.349) (0.159)
Change in US Federal Funds 20.000131 20.000256 20.000285 20.000405
rates (%) (0.000555) (0.000497) (0.000539) (0.000485)
Inflation 20.00362*** 20.00311*** 20.00198 20.00265**
(0.00118) (0.00102) (0.00306) (0.00113)
Inflation (t–1) 20.00103 20.000293 20.00268 20.000313
(0.000748) (0.00154) (0.00239) (0.00154)
Foreign exchange rate, % 0.180*** 0.155*** 0.101 0.133**
change (0.0584) (0.0484) (0.145) (0.0530)
Foreign exchange rate, % 0.0619 0.0226 0.137 0.0251
change (t–1) (0.0373) (0.0783) (0.119) (0.0772)
SSA trading partners’ 21.808
growth interaction with the (2.277)
lag share of regional exports
Non–SSA trading partners’ 2.839
growth interaction with the (1.919)
lag share of extraregional
exports
Share of regional exports in 17.61
GDP (t–1) (11.56)
Share of extraregional 27.143
exports in GDP (t–1) (7.592)
GDP per capita at the 24.95e206***
beginning of the 5y periods (5.07e207)
Constant 0.758 22.943 24.541* 24.781* 26.869 219.31** 219.31** 219.31**
(0.689) (2.660) (2.486) (2.513) (5.382) (8.033) (8.033) (8.033)
Observations 1,345 1,344 1,344 1,301 1,252 1,118 1,252 159
R2squared 0.159 0.180 0.188 0.187
Number of countries 45 45 45 45 45 40 45 43
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***p , 0.01, **p , 0.05, *p , 0.1.
14 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 2. GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of Trading Partners (continued)
although the estimated coefficient is smaller. Similarly, of growth compared with peers in Latin America and
a statistically significant impact of the global economic emerging and developing Asia but a higher elasticity
environment continues, as captured by world average than the one estimated for countries in the Middle
growth (Table 2.1, column 8). East and North Africa and in emerging and developing
Estimating the specification in equation (1) for Europe, which is not statistically different from zero
countries in the Middle East and North Africa, Latin (Table 2.2). The results for the Middle East and North
America, emerging and developing Asia, and emerging Africa countries can be explained by the importance of
and developing Europe, shows that sub-Saharan developments in oil markets.
African countries have a lower intraregional elasticity
Table 2.2. Sub-Saharan Africa and Other Developing Countries: GDP Growth Elasticities to the Growth of
Trading Partners
Dependent variable: real GDP growth
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
SSA Latin America MENA Asia Europe and CIS
Real GDP growth (t–1) 0.264*** 0.197*** 20.000418 0.170** 0.325***
(0.0678) (0.0407) (0.0351) (0.0843) (0.103)
Real GDP growth (t–2) 20.0770* 20.00800 20.196** 20.0487 20.0406
(0.0405) (0.0367) (0.0805) (0.0329) (0.0890)
SSA trading partners’ growth 0.133** 0.157** 20.00140 0.157* 0.204
(0.0610) (0.0693) (0.0629) (0.0921) (0.163)
Non–SSA trading partners’ growth 0.334 20.0482 20.107 0.492*** 0.335**
SSA average growth 0.0526 0.254*** 0.476** 0.322*** 0.429**
(0.280) (0.0928) (0.219) (0.117) (0.184)
World average growth 0.108 0.394** 0.192 20.148 20.0342
(0.255) (0.163) (0.348) (0.173) (0.201)
Conflict year, Uppsala database 23.913*** 22.588 24.737 20.913* 20.674
(1.287) (1.734) (3.427) (0.477) (1.253)
Terms of trade, percent change 0.0881* 0.281*** 0.0319 0.121 0.0694
(0.0485) (0.0537) (0.0420) (0.0858) (0.0963)
Trade openness (t–1) 0.0844 0.0188*** 0.0347* 0.00545 0.0229
(0.0585) (0.00690) (0.0206) (0.0112) (0.0147)
Share of regional exports in total 1.561 22.190 2.662 20.988 2.864
exports (t–1) (2.888) (1.360) (2.870) (1.881) (3.652)
Investment share of GDP (t–1) 0.0608 20.161*** 0.239** 0.0442 20.0103
(0.0579) (0.0312) (0.109) (0.0287) (0.0861)
Percent change in population 0.489 0.223 20.530 0.108 0.162
(0.341) (0.272) (0.372) (0.534) (0.566)
Percent change in US Federal 20.000256 0.00117* 0.000884 0.000218 20.00111
Funds rates (0.000497) (0.000672) (0.000958) (0.000631) (0.000715)
Inflation 20.00311*** 20.00326* 20.0669*** 20.00808 20.00327
(0.00102) (0.00182) (0.0218) (0.0130) (0.00203)
Inflation (t–1) 20.000293 27.14e205 0.0836** 20.00229 26.71e205
(0.00154) (0.000366) (0.0390) (0.0140) (0.00135)
Foreign exchange rate, percent 0.155*** 0.314 20.829 21.672 20.140
change (0.0484) (0.200) (0.508) (1.052) (0.107)
Foreign exchange rate, percent 0.0226 20.00983 0.757 0.661 20.00828
change (t–1) (0.0783) (0.00869) (0.770) (0.477) (0.121)
Constant 26.869 2.959*** 23.668* 21.05 22.297
(5.382) (0.937) (2.032) (2.777) (2.913)
Observations 1,252 941 560 494 420
Number of countries 45 30 20 18 18
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: CIS 5 Commonwealth of Independent States; MENA 5 Middle East and North Africa. SSA 5 sub-Saharan Africa. Robust standard errors in
parentheses. ***p , 0.01, **p , 0.05, *p , 0.1.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 15
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Banking Interdependencies Becoming Figure 15. PAB and Subregional Bank Presence in SSA,
More Subregional 2007–16
Banks headquartered in sub-Saharan Africa account 1. Assets in host countries as a percent of host country assets
for an increasingly large share of the regional financial sys- PAB: Total assets in hosts (Percent of total host assets)
12 Subregional banks: Total assets in hosts 1200
tem.5 Their headquarters are based in a small number of (Percent of total host assets)
countries, and their subsidiaries and branches are hosted 10 Total SSA Assets 1000
across a wide range of countries—a situation that creates (Billions USD, RHS)
important spillover channels. Additionally, as regional 8 800
USD billion
banks’ activities have increased over time, so has financial
Percent
sector depth, which itself has been associated with higher 6 600
GDP growth in the region.
4 400
2 200
Presence of Foreign Banks Headquartered in
Sub-Saharan Africa 0 0
2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
The expansion of banks headquartered in
sub-Saharan Africa has contributed to the deepening 2. Deposits in host countries as a percent of host country deposits
of financial systems across the region and represents an PAB: Total deposits in hosts (Percent of total host deposits)
14 Subregional banks: Total deposits in hosts 740
important vector for economic and financial spillovers.
(Percent of total host assets)
Banks headquartered in sub-Saharan Africa are gen- 12 640
Total SSA Deposits
erally well capitalized and have expanded throughout (Billions USD, RHS) 540
10
the region mainly via subsidiaries. The subsidiaries are 440
USD billion
funded primarily using local sources, which limits the 8
Percent
340
risk of spillovers in the short term (IMF 2012, 2015c;
6
Mecagni, Marchettini, and Maino 2015). However, 240
as the financial sector continues to expand on the 4
140
continent, sub-Saharan Africa–based banks constitute 2 40
an increasingly important transmission channel for real
economic activity in the medium term. This channel 0 –60
2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
is particularly relevant today as vulnerabilities among
sub-Saharan Africa–based banks have increased owing Sources: Fitch Connect; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff
calculations.
to their high exposure to sovereign debt and to the Note: PAB = pan-African banks; SSA = sub-Saharan Africa, RHS = right hand side.
commodity export sector, more nonperforming loan
levels in some cases, and the often limited capacity
for governments to support or resolve troubled banks
(Kinda, Mlachila, and Ouedraogo 2016; IMF 2017b). Africa–based banking groups that own subsidiaries or
Banks headquartered in sub-Saharan Africa branches in three to nine sub-Saharan African coun-
expanded rapidly throughout sub-Saharan Africa fol- tries (referred to as subregional banks) grew through
lowing the global financial crisis. Pan-African Banks— the postcrisis period before growth slowed down
defined here as sub-Saharan Africa–based banking more recently.
groups that own subsidiaries or branches in 10 or more This growth coincided with the retrenchment of
sub-Saharan African countries—expanded rapidly European and American banks on the continent.
from 2007 through 2013 before expansion decelerated In terms of both asset and deposit shares, PABs and
in recent years (Figure 15). Similarly, sub-Saharan subregional banks control a roughly equal share of
the foreign markets in which they are present (Fig-
5This section focuses on banks that are both headquartered in ure 15).6 In terms of market participation, the share
sub-Saharan Africa (and thus subject to sub-Saharan African banking
regulations) and majority owned by sub-Saharan African groups, 6In the literature (notably IMF 2015c), subregional banks are
because of the implications for the home countries in terms of defined as having a presence in five or more countries. The definition
regional spillovers. has been expanded in this note to capture important subregional
16 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 16. Sub-Saharan African PABs and Subregional Banks: Home and Host Countries
(PAB or subregional banking group foreign assets and deposits, measured as indicated)
1. PAB Home Countries 2. PAB Host Countries
(Percent of total PAB assets or deposits outside parent bank country) (Percent of total domestic assets or deposits)
50 70
Assets Assets
60
40 Deposits Deposits
50
Percent
30 40
Percent
20 30
20
10
10
0 0
South Africa Togo Nigeria LSO CAF BFA GNB BEN MLI SWZ SEN UGA NAM
3. Sub-Regional Banking Groups Home Countries 4. Sub-Regional Banking Groups Host Countries
(Percent of total SRB assets or deposits outside parent bank country) (Percent of total domestic assets or deposits)
35 45
Assets 40 Assets
30 Deposits Deposits
35
25
30
20
Percent
25
Percent
15 20
15
10
10
5
5
0 0
ZAF TGO KEN NGA BWA MUS GAB CMR SWZ LSO BWA CAF COG TCD SLE TZA ZMB UGA NER
Sources: Fitch Connect, IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: PAB = pan-African banks; SRB = sub-regional banks. See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
of PABs and subregional banking groups in the total concentrated in three countries, with South Africa
sub-Saharan African financial system is increasing, fol- and Togo each home to about 40 percent of all PABs,
lowing a global trend of banking regionalization (IMF leveraging their roles as subregional hubs for finan-
2015b). Nevertheless, assets and deposits have recently cial services (Figure 16.1).7 In contrast, subregional
declined, consistent with the decline in regionwide parent banks are only about half as concentrated. PAB
assets that coincided with the economic deceleration and subregional banking group parents are based in
in the region. a similar set of countries (Figure 16.3), but they are
hosted in different sets of countries. While the foreign
Country Exposure to Sub-Saharan African Banks subsidiaries of PABs are spread across the region
Both PABs and subregional banks are highly (Figure 16.2), countries that host subregional banks are
concentrated in terms of their home countries but notably more concentrated (Figure 16.4). While the
have foreign entities that are widely dispersed across majority of South African subregional bank subsidiar-
sub-Saharan Africa, thus representing a potentially
7Ecobank in Togo is a special case. Only the holding company,
important spillover channel. PAB parent banks are
Ecobank Transnational Incorporated, is headquartered in Togo, and
it has the status and privileges of a nonresident supranational finan-
banks that have a presence in fewer countries, particularly those in cial institution. The de facto economic headquarters of Ecobank is in
East Africa. Nigeria, where its largest subsidiary is located (IMF 2015c).
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 17
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
ies are located in SADC countries, Kenyan subregional Figure 17. Systemic Foreign Owned PAB and
banks are mostly situated in EAC countries, Nigerian Subregional Banks, 2007–16
subregional banks are mainly in West African coun- 1. Average Bank Deposits, by Country, 2007–16
tries, and Gabonese and Cameroonian subregional (Percent of total deposits in country)
70
banks are mostly in neighboring CEMAC countries. Average deposit ratio, PAB
This means that developments in a few countries home 60 Average deposit ratio, SRB
to most PABs and subregional banks can have substan-
50
tial economic spillovers in a variety of countries.
Spillover channels are potentially numerous and run 40
Percent
in both directions between the parent bank and its
30
subsidiaries, as well as across subsidiaries and branches
of the same banking group (IMF 2015c). As described 20
in IMF (2015c), subsidiaries and branches could be
affected if they are connected to their parent through 10
the placement of deposits and credit or via deficien- 0
LSO CAF SWZ GNB BEN TCD NAM BFA MLI SLE SEN COG UGA TZA
cies in governance, perceptions of mismanagement,
or other reputational concerns at the group level. 2. Cross-Country Average Bank Deposits, By Bank Type, 2007–16
On the other hand, parent banks themselves may be (Percent of total deposits in country)
exposed to risks in any of the countries hosting their 20
Average deposit ratio, PAB
foreign subsidiaries and branches, depending on the 18 Average deposit ratio, SRB
systemic importance of these entities to the local 16
economy, the liquidity-sharing arrangements across the 14
banking group, and the size of the foreign subsidiary 12
Percent
or branch operation relative to the group. While the 10
subsidiary model minimizes contagion risk, it does not 8
eliminate it completely, as subsidiaries may still have 6
exposure to their parent or other entities in the bank 4
group (Mecagni, Marchettini, and Maino 2015). For 2
example, there may be important risks stemming from 0
2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
syndicated loans between subsidiaries or branches.
Finally, host countries of systemic PABs and subre- Sources: Fitch Connect; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff
gional bank subsidiaries and branches may face risks calculations.
Note: PAB = pan-African banks; SRB = sub-regional banks. See page 41 for
arising from unilateral or uncoordinated actions taken country abbreviations table.
by the banks’ home authorities or parent banks, which
can have implications for financial stability in the host
jurisdiction (Mecagni, Marchettini, and Maino 2015).
Nigeria and South Africa) or because the foreign enti-
In many countries, banks headquartered in
ties were not systemic (IMF 2012, 2015c). In either
sub-Saharan Africa are systemically important, increas-
case, a banking crisis in the headquarters country did
ing the potential for cross-border spillovers. The ratio
not typically affect ratios at the macro level in host
of total deposits in foreign African subsidiaries or
countries. However, this does not rule out the possi-
branches of PABs or subregional banks to total depos-
bility that a PAB or subregional banking group parent
its by country—a measure of systemic importance—is
bank could be hit by a shock that is transmitted across
highest in small countries (Figure 17). Also, the degree
borders. If its foreign subsidiary or branch is systemi-
of systemic importance is larger for PAB subsidiaries
cally important, such a shock could have real effects on
and branches than for subregional banks. In the past,
the host economy. This situation would be difficult for
spillovers from banking crises in African countries
host country policymakers to foresee.
were limited, either because the subsidiaries in host
countries were mainly funded by local deposits and
therefore did not significantly depend on funding from
their parent (for example, banks headquartered in
18 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 18. Sub-Saharan Africa: Real, Financial, and Cross-Border Links
1. Cross-Country Average Total Private Credit, 1960–2016 2. Private Credit Growth and GDP Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa, 2008–15
(Percent of GDP) (Average)
80 8
Average, SSA
70 PAB home countries 7
SRB home countries
60 Major PAB host countries 6
Major SRB host countries
50 5
GDP Growth
Percent
40 4
30 3
20 2
10 1
0 0
–4 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40
1960
63
66
69
72
75
78
81
84
87
90
93
96
99
2002
05
08
11
14
Private Credit Growth
Sources: Fitch Connect; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.
Cross-border Banking and Growth Figure 19. Bank Deposits in PABs and Subregional Banks,
Financial markets have deepened in countries home 2007–16
to pan-African and subregional banks, and this deepen- 700 Total deposits, oil exporters
ing has been associated with higher real GDP growth. Total deposits, non-oil exporters
600
Over the long term, financial markets in sub-Saharan
Africa have gradually deepened, as measured by credit 500
to the private sector (Figure 18.1). This is especially
Billions of USD
400
true in countries that are home to PABs and subre-
gional banks compared with those that are primarily 300
hosts to these banking groups. At the same time, 200
evidence has shown that financial development and
deepening have supported growth and reduced growth 100
volatility in sub-Saharan Africa (IMF 2016a), as can be 0
seen from the strong positive association between GDP 2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
growth and private credit growth (Figure 18.2).
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.
PABs and subregional banks could spur cross-border Note: See page 41 for country groupings table.
growth spillovers. Depending on the funding arrange-
ments within these banking groups, lower growth in
the parent banks’ home countries could lower credit
excess liquidity to their parent, which may limit credit
and deposit growth in their foreign African subsid-
growth in the parent country.
iaries and branches, as it does at home (IMF 2012).
The source of economic deceleration is important
This would be the case if the parent supplies a signif-
for the financial sector. Countries in the region that
icant portion of liquidity to the subsidiary or branch,
were hard hit by the commodity price decline have
although evidence suggests that bank funding is mostly
experienced credit growth deceleration and a decline
local in the largest countries (IMF 2012, 2015c). On
in deposits (Figure 19) (Agrawal, Duttagupta, and
the other hand, lower growth in host countries also
Presbitero 2017). This is partly a result of the tendency
limits the prospects for new cross-border expansion
of African banks to be highly exposed to the commod-
opportunities for the parent bank and constrains
ity sector (IMF 2017c). Reinforcing factors such as a
the ability of subsidiaries and branches to repatriate
slowdown in economic activity and a buildup in gov-
ernment arrears to contractors can further exacerbate
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 19
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Table 1. Loan-to-Deposit Ratios, Largest Sub-Saharan African Countries, 2015
(Percent)
Foreign-owned Foreign-owned
Countries pan-African banks subregional banks All banks*
Kenya 61.3 77.1 88.9
Tanzania 57.4 79.1 73.6
Ghana 51.5 63.8 71.6
Côte d’Ivoire 58.2 63.3 80.9
Cameroon 57.3 79.6 90.6
Uganda 50.2 83.4 79.7
Zambia 48.8 59.7 69.9
Mali 41.1 57.3 95.0
Botswana 61.7 73.7 79.6
Mozambique 53.9 68.3 69.8
Burkina Faso 56.5 64.3 93.9
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations
Note: *Aggregate loan-to-deposit ratio measured using IFS bank credit-to-deposit ratio.
any rise in nonperforming loans, lower bank profits, and the shadow banking sector is about 40 percent
or increased solvency risk (IMF 2017b). Depending of the entire financial sector (IMF 2016b). In South
on the structure of cross-border banking groups, these Africa, NBFIs hold about two-thirds of all financial
credit supply and solvency issues can have cross-border assets, with pension funds holding assets equal to
implications. 110 percent of GDP (versus banking assets equal to
112 percent), and long-term insurers holding assets
equal to 64 percent of GDP (IMF 2014). PABs gener-
African Bank Behavior and Trends in Correspondent ally have large shares of ownership in NBFIs, thereby
Banking Relationships increasing the risk of spillovers from developments
Both PABs and subregional banks are relatively in the real economies to the banking sectors. These
less active lenders in the countries where they oper- risks are compounded by a lack of regulation in the
ate. In almost all countries that host PABs, the PAB nonbank financial sector and low levels of compliance
subsidiaries and branches seem to be less aggressive in the banking sector.
in their lending practices on average compared with The withdrawal of correspondent banking rela-
other banks. Across hosting countries, the average tionships (CBRs) in sub-Saharan Africa presents
loan-to-deposit ratio for PABs is about 34 percent less another potentially important channel for spillovers.
than the country-level average (Table 1). Subregional After increasing between 2011 and 2014, CBRs have
banks are also more restricted in their lending, with been under pressure in recent years. Since 2011,
average loan-to-deposit ratios about 22 percent less sub-Saharan Africa has seen a 4 percent decline in the
than country-level averages. These patterns reflect a number of active correspondent banks and a 9 per-
combination of supervisory limits, preference to act as cent decline in the number of counterparty countries
deposit-taking institutions with limited lending to the (FSB 2017). The decline has been driven by a range
private sector, and greater exposure to sovereigns, as of factors, including weaknesses in controls at respon-
has been documented in East Africa (Cihak and Pod- dent banks, inadequate supervision and regulation,
piera 2005) and across the continent (IMF 2015c). country risk, and profitability. While much of the
PABs and subregional banks have become increas- decline appears to be concentrated in small banks,
ingly complex by integrating nonbank activities, some subregional banks have also lost their CBRs, and
increasing the potential for spillovers. This is partic- in some cases respondent banks have terminated CBRs
ularly the case in the southern part of the continent, with their own subsidiaries. The termination of a CBR
where these activities tend to have a regional scope, affects a bank’s ability to extend credit and transfer
such as insurance and securities dealing (IMF 2015c). international payments, which has direct effects on
For instance, in Namibia, nonbank financial institu- growth, trade, and internal and external stability. If a
tions (NBFIs) have gross assets four times those of CBR is terminated with a PAB or regional banking
traditional banks (equivalent to 330 percent of GDP),
20 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 20. Sub-Saharan Africa: Sovereign Spread Correlations, 2012–16
AGO 1
CIV 0.85 1
CMR 0.93 0.96 1
ETH 0.92 0.89 0.92 1
GAB 0.93 0.92 0.98 0.92 1
GHA 0.90 0.95 0.98 0.88 0.96 1
KEN 0.88 0.91 0.95 0.91 0.96 0.93 1
MOZ –0.02 –0.17 –0.21 0.03 –0.22 –0.28 –0.24 1
NAM 0.88 0.96 0.98 0.88 0.95 0.95 0.92 –0.22 1
NGA 0.89 0.88 0.93 0.85 0.95 0.93 0.90 –0.23 0.93 1
SEN 0.87 0.95 0.98 0.90 0.97 0.96 0.96 –0.27 0.96 0.92 1
TZA 0.70 0.80 0.82 0.65 0.79 0.80 0.73 –0.25 0.85 0.80 0.78 1
ZAF 0.81 0.92 0.94 0.79 0.92 0.93 0.87 –0.29 0.95 0.93 0.93 0.90 1
ZMB 0.91 0.96 0.99 0.91 0.98 0.99 0.96 –0.23 0.97 0.95 0.98 0.81 0.95 1
AGO CIV CMR ETH GAB GHA KEN MOZ NAM NGA SEN TZA ZAF ZMB
Sources: JP Morgan; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
group parent, the impact can be felt across the entire markets and the country most highly integrated with
group and multiple countries. global financial markets, may be driving movement in
sovereign spreads of the region’s frontier markets (IMF
2012, 2017b).
The Dominant Role of South Africa Sovereign The substantial co-movement in sovereign spreads
Spread Spillovers across sub-Saharan African frontier markets may be
Though highly vulnerable to global trends, frontier driven in part by conditions in South Africa. A simple
markets in sub-Saharan Africa are driven in part by correlation analysis of sovereign spreads indicates
trends in South Africa. This is consistent with other a high degree of co-movement across sub-Saharan
emerging markets and low-income regions dominated by a African frontier markets (Figure 20).8 A principal
single large and financially integrated economy. component analysis on these spreads further shows
that 85 percent of this co-movement is explained by
their first common factor. This first common factor is
Cross-Country Co-movement and Its Drivers then itself strongly correlated with economic indica-
Evidence suggests that financial market tors of a single country, South Africa, with a correla-
co-movement in emerging and developing econo- tion coefficient of 0.93 against the implied volatility
mies is driven by both global and regional factors. It index of the Johannesburg stock exchange (SAVI) and
is well established that open economies are exposed of 0.94 against the South African sovereign spread.
to a global financial cycle, and certainly sub-Saharan However, correlations alone cannot determine whether
African countries are no exception (Rey 2015). the South Africa factor is driving the co-movement or
However, national policies and fiscal fundamentals a confounding global factor is driving both the South
can also have an impact on regional treasury bill and African spread and co-movement with sub-Saharan
bond markets. In sub-Saharan Africa, there is evidence African frontier markets.
of cross-country fiscal spillovers to sovereign spreads
within regional economic areas (Hitaj and Onder
2013). Evidence also shows that if there is a single Estimating the Impact of South Africa
dominant economy in an emerging market region, The estimated impact of cross-border spillovers of
it tends to influence asset prices in smaller coun- movements in the South African spread to frontier
tries within the region (see, for example, Mwase and markets of sub-Saharan Africa is considerable. The
others 2016). For sub-Saharan Africa, it is natural to
ask whether South Africa, the largest sovereign debt 8Mozambique is an outlier owing to public debt misreporting and
emitter with the deepest and most liquid financial subsequent default, which increased its spread significantly in recent
years, making it substantially out of line with regional spreads.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 21
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
South African spread explains about 6 percent more of The composition of remittances in sub-Saharan
the variation in frontier market spreads than domestic Africa is shifting toward intraregional flows. While
and global factors (as measured by the CBOE Volatil- total remittance inflows to sub-Saharan African coun-
ity Index (VIX)) alone, while a 100 basis point change tries have remained constant at slightly over 2 per-
in the South African sovereign spread is estimated cent of GDP over the past 10 years, the composition
to be associated with a 20 basis point increase in the has shifted: remittances among sub-Saharan African
average frontier market spread (Box 3 and Table 3.1, countries have grown faster than those from the rest
columns 1 and 2). The fact that developments specific of the world in the past five years.9 Meanwhile, total
to South Africa act as drivers of regional spreads sug- remittances are becoming relatively more important as
gests that investors may have incomplete information other sources of external funding, such as aid and FDI,
on other regional developments (for instance, owing decline (Figure 21.1). Regional remittances accounted
to data availability constraints) and may proxy their for about 35 percent of the region’s total remittance
portfolio allocation for the region on the basis of per- inflows in 2015 (Figure 21.2).10
ceptions of the South African economy. This has been Measured as a share of GDP, total remittance
shown to be the case in other regions in which a single inflows in sub-Saharan Africa are larger than those in
country is the dominant economy (Furceri, Jalles, and other emerging and developing regions (Figure 22).
Zdzienicka 2016). The relative importance of intraregional inflows in
Sub-Saharan African frontier market spreads are sub-Saharan Africa is the third highest, after the
also influenced by emerging market trends. It is likely Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), and the
that the impact of the South African spread on other Middle East and North Africa.
sub-Saharan frontier market spreads is driven by a For some countries in sub-Saharan Africa, regional
confounding factor; namely, trends in emerging mar- remittance inflows account for a large share of national
kets globally. However, in controlling for an index of income, setting the stage for a potentially high expo-
emerging market bond spreads, the estimated impact sure to regional spillovers. In 27 of the 45 sub-Saharan
of changes in South Africa’s spread remains positive African countries, regional remittance inflows exceed
and significant (although, depending on the index, the interregional remittances. At the high end, Lesotho,
impact may decrease in absolute value and be quan- Liberia, and Togo receive more than 5 percent of
titatively less important than the emerging market GDP in remittances from other sub-Saharan Afri-
trends), suggesting that movement in South African can countries. Given that remittances have been
spreads explains a significant share of movement in shown to reduce macroeconomic fluctuations and
sub-Saharan African frontier spreads. poverty and foster financial development, regional
remittance flows can help redistribute resources from
fast-growing countries to slower-growing ones. This
The Changing Pattern of Remittance Flows factor was particularly helpful, for instance, in the case
Regional remittances among sub-Saharan African of resource-intensive countries hit by the commodity
countries are relatively large. They account for a third of price shock: Liberia, Mali, and Nigeria, with remit-
total remittance inflows, and their share is growing in tance inflows of 8, 4, and 2 percent of GDP, respec-
parallel with declining costs. Because of a high concen- tively (IMF 2016c; Gonzalez-Garcia and others 2016;
tration of outflows from a few countries and the large Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh 2009).
exposure of some recipient countries, these remittances Most remittance outflows from sub-Saharan African
constitute an important spillover channel. In particu- countries are sent to other countries in the region.
lar, Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana are important sources for Specifically, 31 out of 45 sub-Saharan countries send
West Africa, while South Africa is the main source for more remittances to the region than to the rest of the
Southern and East Africa. Econometric estimates suggest world, and three-quarters of total remittances from
that growth spillovers between remittance partners are
important but may be outweighed by growth spillovers
9The estimates used in this section are from official sources, which
from trading partners, although trading and remittance
are known to underestimate remittances.
partners often coincide. 10Remittance inflows from other sub-Saharan Africa countries
increased from 0.6 percent of regional GDP in 2010 to 0.8 per-
cent in 2015.
22 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 3. Sovereign Yield Spread Spillovers
An examination of the movement in sovereign included in the original EMBIG index sample. X
spreads of sub-Saharan frontier markets around major is country-specific controls, including inflation, the
news events in South Africa shows noticeable responses exchange rate relative to the US dollar, and an index
to such events. This is first studied via an ad hoc event of financial stress.
analysis during the month of December 2015, a time The model is estimated in first differences follow-
of high volatility in South African markets. Three ing standard tests that indicate the presence of a unit
major events occurred: root in all the time series variables. Country fixed
December 4 Ratings downgrade by Standard effects, γ i, are included to control for time-invariant
& Poor’s country-specific heterogeneity. Standard errors are clus-
December 9 Finance minister fired tered at the country level. The sample uses monthly
December 1311 New finance minister appointed data from January 2012 to August 2017, and includes
These three major events are plotted in Figure 3.1, all sub-Saharan African countries that have issued
along with the sovereign spread of South African foreign-denominated debts on international finan-
and sub-Saharan African frontier markets. All rates cial markets since 2012 (frontier markets). These are
are normalized to zero on the date of the first event. Angola, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Ethiopia, Gabon,
The chart shows 10 days before and 15 days after the Ghana, Kenya, Mozambique, Namibia, Nigeria, Sene-
first event (and thus includes the December 9 and gal, South Africa, Tanzania, and Zambia.
14 events). It shows that there is a marked jump in The analysis augments IMF (2016) by taking advan-
South Africa’s sovereign spread within 24 hours of tage of the panel dimension of the data. The estima-
each announcement, which continues for up to 72 tion results for equation (1) are reported in Table 3.1,
hours. Movement in other countries’ sovereign spreads and show that movements in the sovereign spreads of
tend to be heterogeneous in the days leading up to sub-Saharan African frontier markets are associated
the announcements, but they move in concert with with changes in the South African spread. This result is
the South African spread immediately following the robust after controlling for additional global emerging
announcements. This suggests that South Africa has a market factors. Across columns 2–5, the South African
degree of influence over its regional peers via sovereign spread coefficient is positive and highly significant,
financial markets. though its value halves and its level of significance
A panel fixed effects model is estimated to study falls when emerging market factors are controlled
the drivers of sovereign yield spreads. The model is for via the synthetic EMBIG index, suggesting that
specified as follows: both global and South African factors are import-
ant in explaining spreads across sub-Saharan Africa.
sprea d it = α + γ i + β 1 sprea d t−1,i + β 2 ZAF t +
Additionally, based on the adjusted R2, the South
β 3 Globa l t + β 4 X it + e it ( 1)
African factors combined explain 5 percent more of
where spread refers to the difference between a coun- the variation in spreads (versus without them), while
try’s foreign denominated bond yields with respect global emerging market factors explain only up to an
to US Treasury bond yields and ZAF corresponds to additional 2 percent of the variation. The results are
South African factors, including either the SAVI or consistent with the correlation analysis and indicate
the sovereign spread. Global is global factors, includ- the importance of both regional and global emerging
ing the VIX, oil prices, and—in columns 4 and 5 market-specific factors in driving sub-Saharan African
of Table 3.1—either the Morgan Stanley Capital frontier market yields.
International (MSCI) Emerging Markets index or a
synthetic version of the Emerging Market Bond Index
Global (EMBIG). The synthetic EMBIG spread is
constructed with the same sample and weights as the
actual EMBIG spread, excluding South Africa and
those sub-Saharan African frontier markets that are
11The announcement was made on Sunday, December
13, 2017. Since markets are closed on Sunday, the observed
movement in spreads occurred on Monday December 14, 2017,
which is when the indicator is identified in Figure 3.1.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 23
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 3. Sovereign Yield Spread Spillovers (continued)
Box Figure 3.1. South African News and Sovereign Spreads
Angola Ethiopia Gabon Ghana Côte d’Ivoire
Kenya Mozambique Namibia Nigeria Senegal
Tanzania South Africa Zambia
200
150
100
Level change
50
0
–50
–100
–150
–10 –9 –8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Days
Source: Bloomberg LP.
Table 3.1. Impact of Global, Regional, and Domestic Factors on Sovereign Spreads, 2012–16
Dependent Variable: Country spread (t)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Country spread (t–1) 20.20* 20.24** 20.21* 20.24** 20.23**
(0.10) (0.09) (0.10) (0.09) (0.09)
FSI 0.02 20.03 0.00 20.03 20.03*
(0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02)
Oil Price 20.25*** 20.16* 20.19** 20.15* 20.03
(0.07) (0.08) (0.07) (0.08) (0.07)
VIX 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.10*** 0.10**
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Inflation 20.07 20.07 20.06 20.07 20.04
(0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07)
Exchange Rate 0.51** 0.45*** 0.48** 0.47*** 0.17
(0.18) (0.14) (0.20) (0.14) (0.16)
South Africa Spread 0.20*** 0.20*** 0.10*
(0.04) (0.04) (0.05)
SAVI 0.06***
(0.01)
MSCI 0.03
(0.03)
Synthetic EMBIG 0.16***
(0.03)
Constant 20.00 20.00 0.00 20.00 0.01*
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 641 641 641 641 626
R2 (adj) 0.25 0.31 0.26 0.30 0.32
Source: Bloomberg LP; Chicago Board Options Exchange; IMF, International Financial Statistics; and staff estimates, and calculations.
Note: All variables are standardized and estimated in first differences. Clustered standard errors in parentheses.
*p 0.1, **p 0.05, ***p 0.01.
24 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 21. Sub-Saharan Africa: External Flows and Remittances
1. Selected External Flows 2. Remittance Inflows
5 40 12
Remittances inflows Share in total SSA inflows (LHS)
Aid (net official development 35 Amount of SSA regional
assistance and official aid) remittances (RHS)
4
Foreign direct investment 30
Billions of US dollars
10
Percent of GDP
25
Percent share
3
20
2 15
8
10
1
5
0 0 6
2005 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 2010 11 12 13 14 15
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and World Bank, World Development Indicators, Migration and Remittances database.
Note: Remittances in the World Bank databases are measured as the sum of three items in the IMF’s Balance of Payments Statistics Year Book: (1) personal transfers,
(2) compensation of employees, and (3) migrants’ transfers (that is, capital transfers between resident and nonresident households). LHS = left hand side; RHS = right
hand side.
sub-Saharan African countries are sent to other coun- Figure 22. Remittance Inflows in Emerging and Developing
tries in the region.12 Countries 2010–15
Remittance outflows originate in a few countries.
1.5
The four largest senders in 2015 accounted for 50 per- From the region
From rest of the world
cent of total regional remittances. Remittances from
Chad, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, and Ghana to Nigeria
alone account for 50 percent of received remittances 1.0
Percent of GDP
in the region. Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana are also a
large source of remittance flows to other West African
countries (Figures 23 and 24). Their ongoing growth
0.5
spell has translated into steady remittance flows to the
region and has contributed to economic growth in the
subregion. Remittance outflows from South Africa, the
other large sender, are spread across the region, making 0.0
SSA Asia Europe America MENA CIS
the country of regionwide importance.
In general, remittances in sub-Saharan Africa are Sources: World Bank, Migration and Remittances database, World Development
Indicators; and IMF staff calculations.
exchanged among the largest, wealthiest, and closest Note: CIS = Commonwealth of Independent States; MENA = Middle East and
economies, but on a net basis, they flow toward poorer North Africa. SSA = sub-Saharan Africa.
and more connected countries, making them more
exposed to spillovers. A standard gravity equation
on the 2010–15 average remittance flows shows that sending costs, especially relative to migrants’ incomes.
remittances are larger for geographically and cultur- Regression results also show that higher sending costs
ally close countries (Box 4 and Table 4.1, columns 1 are associated with lower remittance flows (Table 4.1,
and 2). Compared with other regions in the world, column 4), even after controlling for distance and by
geographical distance seems to be a greater barrier origin and destination fixed effects.
in sub-Saharan Africa because of higher travel and
12Exceptions include East African countries whose remittance
outflows are generally to India and China and certain francophone
countries whose remittance outflows go to France.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 25
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 23. Sub-Saharan Africa: Remittance Outflows and Inflows, 2010–15
1. Share of Total Intraregional Remittance Outflows
18
Percent of total regional outflows
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
CMR CIV TCD GHA ZAF BEN GAB NGA NER KEN BFA TGO GMB SSD TZA
2. Average Remittances Outflows
30
Intraregional Interregional
25
20
Percent of GDP
15
10
5
0
GMB BEN TGO TCD CMR NER LBR CIV GAB SSD BFA GIN CAF GNB RWA
3. Average Remittances Inflows
25
Intraregional Interregional
20
Percent of GDP
15
10
5
0
LSO LBR TGO MLI SEN UGA STP BEN GMB GNB CPV NGA COM KEN MUS
Source: World Bank, Migration and Remittances database.
Note: The Gambia stands out as a country with large inflows and outflows of remittances. Large
inflows from non-sub-Saharan African countries can be explained by the large diaspora (about 5
percent of the population lives abroad, and two out of three Gambians who graduate from foreign
universities stay abroad). Large outflows are essentially directed to Senegal, which surrounds the
country. Anecdotal evidence suggests that these outflows originate from the many Gambians who
have family members in Senegal and those who seek better health care and transportation
means in Senegal, given the superior quality of Senegalese infrastructure. See page 41 for
country abbreviations table.
26 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 24. Sub-Saharan Africa: Major Remittance Corridors, 2010–15
SEN
KEN TCD MLI
BWA
LBR
BEN
NGA
CIV
SWZ ZAF BFA
GHA
LSO GIN
TGO
MOZ CMR
NER
Sources: World Bank, Migration and Remittances database, World Development Indicators.
Note: Averages for top five remittance senders, 2010–15 (in red) (Chad, Cameroon, Ghana,
Cote d’Ivoire, and South Africa). Thickness of the arrow represents the size of remittance flow
in US dollars. Flows of less than US$10 million were censored. Nigeria receives substantial
remittances through the compensation of Nigerians working in neighboring countries. Only
officially recorded remittances sent through formal channels are recorded, which explains
why some countries known for receiving large remittance inflows—such as Zimbabwe and
Chad—are not included in the graph. See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
Box 4. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–15 Remittance Flows
A gravity model of bilateral remittance flows over are dropped, as these characteristics are absorbed by
the period 2010–15 is estimated to study the determi- the country fixed effects. The new specification is as
nants of remittances. In all specifications, the sample follows:
includes annual data over 2010–15 from the World
Bank Migration and Remittances database with all the logF¯ i,j = α i + γ j + β Xij + ε ij . ( 2)
country pairs in the world that exchanged remittances Estimation results in the first two columns of
at least once. All variables are simple averages over the Table 4.1 demonstrate that all distance measures
six-year period. The standard errors are clustered at the significantly hamper remittance flows across countries.
destination country level to control for possible unob- The first column additionally shows that remittance
served correlation within receiving countries. flows increase significantly with both population and
The first specification is as follows: the GDP per capita of both the origin and destina-
tion country. It does, however, increase more with the
logF¯ ij = α 0 + β Xij + γ Y¯ i + δ ¯
Zj + ε ij (1)
GDP per capita of the origin country, implying that
where F¯ ijrefers to the logarithm of the average remit- net flows toward a poorer country are increasing with
tance flow from country i to country j; Xij corresponds the difference in GDP per capita.
to corridor-specific independent variables, including The specification in column 3 adds interaction
geographic distance, the exchange rate between the variables between measures of distance and dummy
currency of the origin and destination countries, and variables. These variables are introduced for either
dummy variables indicating whether the countries sub-Saharan Africa origin countries (I i∈SSA Xij ) or
share a common official language, share the same sub-Saharan Africa destination countries (I j∈SSA Xij ):
ethnic group, had the same colonial origin, or share a
logF¯ ij = α i + γ j + β X ij + θ o I i∈SSA X ij + θ d I j∈SSA X ij +
common official religion; and Y ¯ i and ¯
Z
j which, respec-
ε ij . ( 3)
tively, refer to the logarithms of the average GDP per
capita and the average population of the origin and This specification is appropriate to investigate
destination countries. whether distance plays a specific role for remittance
The specification in column 2 includes country fixed flows within sub-Saharan Africa. Coefficient estimates
effects, α i and γ j, to control for origin country i and θ o and θ dof these interaction variables, respec-
destination country j time-invariant characteristics. tively, reflect the differential effects of distance for
The corridor variables X ijin equation (1) are kept but sub-Saharan Africa origin and destination countries.
the country-level characteristics (population and GDP)
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 27
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 4. Gravity Equation Estimation for 2010–15 Remittance Flows (continued)
Column 3 is composed of three subcolumns; the number of days it took for the money to be trans-
coefficient estimates θ oare reported in the second sub- ferred. Only a small subset of remittance corridors
column, while estimates θ dare reported in the third. is covered by the Remittance Price database, which
The results indicate that distance is a greater hindrance explains the smaller sample size, the higher R2, and the
for both origin and destination sub-Saharan countries, weaker significance of the results. Despite these issues,
except for those that belonged to the same colony. the results indicate that costs significantly reduce
In column 4, the specification reverts to equation bilateral flow.
(2) but includes two supply-side variables to the set
of independent variables: the median cost of sending
US$200 in percent of the US$200 and the median
Table 4.1. Determinants of Average Remittances Flows
Dependent variable: the logarithm of the average bilateral remittance flow
(3)
(1) (2) Coefficient estimates for (4)
Country controls Country FE All countries SSA origin SSA destination Costs
Contiguous countries 2.61*** 2.40*** 2.09*** 0.56 0.94
(0.14) (0.16) (0.19) (0.36) (0.80)
Distance (1000 km) 20.25*** 20.24*** 20.22*** 20.19*** 20.11*** 20.01
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.03) (0.02) (0.05)
Common language 1.52*** 1.07*** 0.93*** 20.11 0.54** 20.05
(0.14) (0.17) (0.21) (0.33) (0.24) (0.41)
Common ethnicity 0.64*** 0.48*** 0.65*** 0.09 20.45* 0.53
(0.14) (0.16) (0.19) (0.34) (0.23) (0.51)
Belonged to common 1.58*** 1.50*** 1.59*** 20.94*** 0.57* 1.22***
colony (0.14) (0.22) (0.22) (0.31) (0.31) (0.39)
Common religion 0.11* 0.61*** 0.70*** 20.14 20.11 20.20
(0.07) (0.10) (0.11) (0.34) (0.26) (0.48)
Origin GDP p.c. 1.04***
(0.02)
Destination GDP p.c. 0.63***
(0.02)
Origin population 0.67***
(0.01)
Destination population 0.82***
(0.01)
Origin/destination FX rate 20.02**
(0.01)
Median costs (% of 20.10*
amount sent) (0.06)
Median completion time 20.15
(days) (0.12)
Observations 10,704 10,814 10,814 220
R-squared 0.54 0.81 0.81 0.93
Country FE NO YES YES YES
Sources: French Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales (CEPII) database; IMF, World Economic Outlook database; World
Bank, World Development Indicators; and remittances and migration database.
Note: Clustered standard errors in parentheses (Destination country). ***p 0.01, **p 0.05, *p 0.1.
28 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 25. Percentage Cost of Sending US$200 across Region and over Time
(Percentage of the amount sent)
Global East Asia & Pacific Europe & Central Asia
Latin America & Caribbean Middle East & North Africa South Asia
13 Sub-Saharan Africa
12
11
10
Percent
9
8
7
6
5
2011:Q1
11:Q3
12:Q1
12:Q3
13:Q1
13:Q2
13:Q3
13:Q4
14:Q1
14:Q2
14:Q3
14:Q4
15:Q1
15:Q2
15:Q3
15:Q4
16:Q1
16:Q2
16:Q3
16:Q4
17:Q1
17:Q2
Source: World Bank, Remittance Prices Worldwide, Issue 22, June 2017.
Growth in countries sending remittances spills Developments in financial technologies (fintech)
over to receiving countries. Regression results show have the potential to increase the magnitude of remit-
that a 1 percent increase in GDP growth in origin tance flows within the region, strengthening them as
countries is associated with a 0.1 percent increase in a channel for regional spillovers. Sub-Saharan Africa
growth in a receiving country (Box 5). Interestingly, is the most expensive destination to send money to
the result only holds for origin countries that belong (Remittance Price Database Report 2017) (Figures
to the same region, perhaps reflecting that interre- 25 and 26). Remittance costs in 2017 were about
gional remittances are dominated by those sent from 25 percent higher there than in the rest of world.
advanced economies and that their variations are too However, these costs have been decreasing for the past
small to have an impact on the receiving countries 10 years, partly because of the rise of mobile money
through the remittance channel. For many countries, technology. Mobile money transfers are two times less
remittance and trade partners tend to be the same, and expensive than those at money transfer operators and
data limitations do not allow us to accurately distin- post offices and almost three times less expensive than
guish spillovers occurring through one channel rather transfers through commercial banks. As mobile money
than the other.13 However, estimates suggest that both technology continues to expand, and its coverage and
spillovers have a similar magnitude, each accounting usage continue to increase across sub-Saharan Africa, it
for half of the total effect identified in the baseline is expected to contribute to an increase in remittance
estimation. Overall, regression estimates suggest that flows. On the basis of estimates presented in Box 4,
growth performance of large origin countries such as and assuming there is no substitution across corridors,
Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana, and South Africa can generate a decline in remittance costs to the world average
growth spillovers to the rest of the region. (from 9.4 percent to 7.4 percent) could result in
increases in bilateral flows of up to 20 percent.
13The correlation between the share of imports and the share of
remittance flows across partner countries varies substantially. The
median correlation is about 50 percent, but for some countries with
correlations close to 1, like Swaziland and Lesotho, trade and remit-
tance partners are almost the same (South Africa, in this case).
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 29
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 26. Total Average Cost by Remittance Sending Provider
(Percentage of the amount sent)
12
10
8
Percent
6
4
2
0
Bank Money transfer operator Post office Mobile operator
Source: World Bank, Remittance Prices Worldwide, Issue 22, June 2017.
The Foreign Direct Investment Channel—South Figure 27. Selected Sub-Saharan African Countries:
Africa Rules the Roost Intraregional Foreign Direct Investment Stock Positions
Foreign direct investment constitutes an important 70
Percent of total Inward
40
channel of regional integration in sub-Saharan Africa.
Percent of total inward direct investment
direct investment (LHS) 35
60 Percent of GDP (RHS)
For some countries, inward FDI from sub-Saharan
30
Africa constitutes the largest share of total inward FDI. 50
This is the case in Togo, Rwanda, Guinea-Bissau, and
Percent of GDP
25
40
Botswana, where the share of regional inward FDI 20
positions is more than 40 percent of their total stock 30
15
of FDI (Figure 27).
20
Firms from South Africa, Kenya, and Nigeria have 10
the largest presence in other sub-Saharan markets. 10 5
South African firms are the most visible, with more 0 0
than 2,400 subsidiaries in other African countries
TGO
GNB
SYC
MOZ
BEN
ZMB
MLI
MUS
NER
ZAF
CPV
RWA
BWA
UGA
BFA
NGA
(Box 6), but other hubs are growing fast, such as
Kenya (with an important presence in East Africa) Source: IMF, Coordinated Direct Investment Survey database.
and Nigeria (in West Africa). Other subregions, such Note: See page 41 for country abbreviations table.
as central Africa, have limited cross-border corporate
ownership (IMF 2017c).
Multinational firms on the continent can be import- Kenya, Tanzania, and Rwanda) compensated for the
ant sources and transmitters of positive international weaker performance of the headquarters (IMF 2017b).
spillovers. Firms’ potential to affect both their host and The risks of negative cross-border spillovers are
headquarters economies increases with their size and equally important. Multinational firms can increase
interconnectedness. Regional integration at the corpo- national exposure to negative shocks across borders.
rate level allows firms to leverage knowledge transfer The risks are many and varied and include the follow-
and country-level comparative advantages and achieve ing four examples: (1) If a firm is systemically import-
diversification, all while tapping into economies of ant for an economy, performance of its headquarters
scale. For instance, during the recent economic slow- or foreign subsidiaries could have macroeconomic
down in Nigeria, the strong performance of foreign implications for the host country; (2) A firm’s ability
subsidiaries in high-growth countries (for example, to borrow can be affected by its exposure to sovereign
risk, as surges in sovereign spreads often lead to
30 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 5. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances
A panel fixed effects model is estimated to study the variables are then included to test whether sub-Saharan
elasticity of GDP growth rates to the average growth countries behave differently than other countries in the
among remittance partners inside and outside a region. world.
The model is specified as follows: Regressions results are reported in Table 5.1. Start-
ing from column 2, the specifications include controls
RealGDPgrowth it = α + γ i + β 1 RealGDPgrowth t−1,i +
for both the average growth of the sub-Saharan Africa
β 2 regionalremitpartners’growth+
region and for world growth, to ensure that coeffi-
β 3 extraregionalremitpartners’growth +
cients are not capturing average co-movements in
β 4 Xit + β 5 Ii∈SSA
* regionalremitpartners’growth+
continent or world developments. In columns 3 and
β 6 Ii∈SSA
* extraregionalremitpartners’growth + e it (6)
4, the lag of the dependent variable is introduced to
where the dependent variable is the annual growth
address serial correlation issues, and an Arellano-Bond
rate of real GDP in country i; regional remittance
estimation procedure is adopted to address the possible
partners’ growth is the average growth rate of the remit-
endogeneity of that variable. Results are robust to
tance partners that are in the same region as country
the exclusion of the 10 percent largest economies (in
i; extraregional remit partners’ growth corresponds to
column 4) and to the introduction of interaction vari-
the average growth rate of the remittance partners that
ables capturing heterogeneous effects (in column 5).
are outside the region; and I i∈SSAis a dummy variable
In the latter specification, the share of remittances in
for sub-Saharan African countries that is interacted
GDP is interacted with the remittance partners’ aver-
with the last two variables. The growth averages are
age growth to test whether more-exposed economies
weighted using the share of lag remittance inflows. The
are more affected. These new variables are not signifi-
sample includes 2010–15 annual data from the World
cant. In column 6, the specification also includes the
Bank Migration and Remittances database for all
growth averages of the trade partners that are inside
countries in the world, as well as all the data included
and outside the region of the country considered. The
in Box 1.
purpose of these controls is to distinguish between
All specifications include the same standard
spillover effects that are channeled through trade and
country-specific controls that are included in
those channeled through remittance inflows.
Table 1.1, column 5 when studying spillovers from
The estimation results indicate that growth spillovers
the trade channel. Country fixed effects γ i, are also
through the remittance channel are significant for all
included to control for time-invariant country-specific
countries in the world and that these spillovers are
heterogeneity. Coefficient estimates have the expected
not different in sub-Saharan Africa (columns 1–3).
signs, but results are omitted from Table 5.1 for pre-
The results are robust to controlling for the average
sentational purposes. The share of regional remittances
regional growth and serial correlation (columns 2–3).
in total remittance inflows and the share of remittance
Column 4 results suggest that some of the spillovers
inflows in GDP are added as controls. Standard errors
associated with the remittance channels may capture
are robust, clustered at the country level to control for
trade spillovers. The joint significance of the average
possible unobserved correlation within countries.
growth of trade and remittance partners is confirmed
In contrast with the regression using trade data,
by a Wald test with a p-value below 0.02. Despite
remittance flow series are much shorter, spanning
the weaker significance of each estimate separately,
2010 to 2015, which reduces efficiency in the estima-
estimated values suggest that both channels have equal
tion. Given the limited degrees of freedom, a lagged
importance and that half of the observed spillovers can
dependent variable is not included as a control. In
be attributed to each channel. The lack of significance
addition, as opposed to the baseline specification in
of the remittance channel in that last specification
Box 1, all countries of the world are included in the
may be due to the small sample size and the imperfect
regression to increase statistical power. Interaction
measurement of remittance flows.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 31
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 5. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances (continued)
Table 5.1. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances
Dependent variable: Real GDP growth
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Baseline World/regional GMM Excluding Exposure Trade channel
shock controls estimation 10% largest heterogeneity controls
Real GDP growth (t-1) 0.166 0.170 0.168 0.174
(0.123) (0.134) (0.123) (0.122)
Regional remittance partners’ growth 0.0917** 0.0587 0.0999** 0.0971* 0.109** 0.0588
(0.0365) (0.0431) (0.0503) (0.0516) (0.0450) (0.0692)
Extraregional remittance partners’ 20.129 0.101 20.0114 20.0907 20.0378 20.0976
growth (0.179) (0.240) (0.234) (0.261) (0.341) (0.234)
Regional remittance partners’ growth, 20.0849 20.0700 20.00218 0.0222 20.0804 0.0239
SSA differential (0.129) (0.127) (0.144) (0.146) (0.194) (0.142)
Extraregional remittance partners’ 20.366 20.651 20.514 20.430 20.528 20.366
growth, SSA differential (0.376) (0.393) (0.414) (0.417) (0.542) (0.459)
Conflict year, Uppsala database 24.980** 24.878** 25.081*** 25.327*** 25.276*** 25.032***
(1.941) (1.899) (1.283) (1.104) (1.323) (1.250)
Share of regional remittances in total 20.0356 20.0347 20.0523** 20.0587** 20.0536** 20.0515**
inflows (t-1) (0.0257) (0.0254) (0.0256) (0.0276) (0.0270) (0.0251)
Share of remittances inflows in 20.0626 20.0250 0.127 0.136 0.0728 0.128
GDP (t-1) (0.0900) (0.0958) (0.118) (0.123) (0.178) (0.119)
Region average growth 0.424*** 0.485*** 0.501*** 0.500*** 0.474***
(0.138) (0.164) (0.165) (0.172) (0.162)
World average growth 20.601 20.490 20.972 20.510 21.056
(0.971) (0.949) (1.061) (0.953) (1.006)
Share of regional imports in total 20.633 20.245 0.561 0.206 0.547 0.265
inflows (t-1) (3.060) (3.140) (3.203) (3.110) (3.127) (2.994)
Trade openness (t-1) 0.0291 0.0183 0.0156 0.0101 0.0136 0.00987
(0.0238) (0.0261) (0.0334) (0.0342) (0.0333) (0.0331)
Percent change in the terms of trade 0.0918 0.0948 0.196 0.237 0.208 0.205*
(0.0949) (0.0974) (0.121) (0.152) (0.128) (0.121)
Investment share of GDP (t-1) 0.0601 0.0698 0.0672 0.0737 0.0631 0.0742
(0.0948) (0.0966) (0.0955) (0.0984) (0.0939) (0.0951)
Percent change in population 0.524* 0.615** 0.751** 0.726** 0.708** 0.687**
(0.286) (0.297) (0.323) (0.350) (0.324) (0.306)
Percent change in US Federal Funds 0.0100** 0.00718 0.00588 0.00741 0.00588 0.00624
rates (0.00482) (0.00471) (0.00405) (0.00470) (0.00410) (0.00403)
Inflation 20.152 20.180 20.225* 20.223* 20.224* 20.223*
(0.127) (0.125) (0.121) (0.135) (0.124) (0.121)
Inflation (t-1) 0.0507 0.0290 20.0131 20.0299 20.0143 20.00990
(0.0757) (0.0732) (0.0681) (0.0763) (0.0679) (0.0680)
Percent change in the foreign exchange 1.141 2.383 2.371 4.949 2.144 2.233
rate (3.504) (3.620) (3.278) (4.181) (3.321) (3.270)
Percent change in the foreign exchange 20.886 0.817 3.334 4.065 3.409 3.128
rate (t-1) (2.628) (2.442) (2.450) (2.765) (2.472) (2.454)
Regional remittance partners’ growth 21.222
interaction with the lag share of (0.943)
remittance inflows
Extraregional remittance partners’ 0.523
growth interaction with the lag share of (4.190)
remittance inflows
Regional remittance partners’ growth 6.046
interaction with the lag share of (6.585)
remittance inflows, SSA differential
Extraregional remittance partners’ 0.308
growth interaction with the lag share of (9.081)
remittance inflows, SSA differential
Regional trading partners’ growth 0.0497*
(0.0302)
Extraregional trading partners’ growth 0.480*
(0.255)
32 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 5. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances (continued)
Table 5.1. Spillover Effects from Countries Sending Remittances (continued)
Dependent variable: Real GDP growth
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Baseline World/regional GMM Excluding Exposure Trade channel
shock controls estimation 10% largest heterogeneity controls
Regional trading partners’ growth, SSA 20.0152
differential (0.329)
Extraregional trading partners’ growth, 20.470
SSA differential (0.427)
Constant 1.582 1.888 0.659 2.520 1.374 1.861
(2.872) (3.682) (3.687) (3.810) (3.833) (3.790)
Observations 565 565 448 393 448 448
R-squared 0.161 0.181
Number of countries 117 117 117 103 117 117
Sources: French Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales (CEPII) database; IMF, World Economic Outlook database; World Bank,
World Development Indicators; and remittances and migration database.
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***p 0.01, **p0.05, *p 0.1.
Box 6. South African Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa
South African companies have become an increas- South African investment is highly regarded and an
ingly important source of investment in sub-Saharan important driver of growth. Survey evidence suggests
Africa since the mid-1990s, having expanded through that about 80 percent of sub-Saharan Africans who
joint ventures, greenfield investments, and mergers and interact with South African firms find them to have a
acquisitions (Table 6.1) (IMF 2012; Games 2017). better reputation than local firms in the same industry
About 75 percent of investment from South Africa to (DNA Economics 2013). Further empirical evidence
the continent is in the services, trade, and financial shows that outward foreign investment from South
sectors (IMF 2016c). Africa has significant impacts on local growth rates in
Outward foreign direct investment (FDI) from the southern continent, in particular the rates of con-
South Africa is increasing. The total stock of FDI from vergence to South African GDP per capita. Countries
South Africa to sub-Saharan African countries was with a high stock of South African FDI converge more
equivalent to 6.8 percent of South African GDP in rapidly to South African per capita income levels,
2015, up from 4.9 percent of GDP in 2010 (Fig- while countries with low bilateral FDI stocks vis-à-vis
ure 6.1). In receiving countries, South Africa’s invest- South Africa show no evidence of convergence (Dunne
ments represented as much as 3.2 percent of GDP (in and Masiyandiam 2015). Thus the deceleration of the
Mauritius), with an average of 0.4 percent across all South African economy in recent years could spill over
sub-Saharan African countries in which it invested in to other countries that have large stocks and flows of
2015. South African FDI and could manifest as both lower
FDI and lower GDP growth in these countries.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 33
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Box 6. South African Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa (continued)
Box Figure 6.1. South Africa: Outward FDI
in Sub-Saharan Africa
(Percent of GDP)
8.00
7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
2010 11 12 13 14 15
Source: IMF, Coordinated Direct Investment Survey
database.
Table 6.1. South Africa: Major Multinationals
Sub-Saharan Africa Reach: Global Reach
(Number of countries with (Total number of countries
Name Sector operations, excluding South Africa) with operations)
Bidcorp Food services 16 41
First Rand Financial services 8 16*
MTN Mobile phone operator 16 21
Naspers Internet and media 37 130
Sanlam Financial services 12 18
Sasol Chemical 7 33
Shoprite Groceries, furniture, restaurants, pharmaceutical, 15 15
logistics, property, hospitality, ticketing, liquor,
money markets
Standard Bank Financial services 16 30
Group
Note: *FirstRand has eight full service banking locations in Africa. It has one investment banking licence (Nigeria) and two representative offices
(Angola and Kenya) on the continent, plus five branches and representative offices globally.
increases in corporate spreads; (3) Financial channel could reduce the attractiveness of such countries as an
spillovers can manifest as counterparty spillovers, where FDI destination.
the default of a firm causes financial distress for its
foreign creditors, shareholders, or parent (Jorion and
Zhang 2009); and (4) The imposition of restrictions, The Fiscal Channel—The Role of Unintended
such as those on foreign exchange, can hurt local and Consequences
foreign-owned firms by disrupting their production Spillovers can arise from large fluctuations in fiscal
processes and revenue remittances. The subsequent revenues in the context of customs unions and from
negative performance of the local subsidiary could commodity pricing policies in neighboring countries. These
pose risks for the parent company (IMF 2017c), which
34 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Box 7. SACU Revenue-Sharing Formula
All customs and excise revenues collected in the imports to the country from all other SACU members,
Southern African Customs Union (SACU) coun- less re-exports, divided by the value of imports less
tries are pooled and managed by the South African re-exports for all SACU countries; y iis the share of
Revenue Fund, then distributed to member countries GDP of the country in the SACU GDP; and h i the
according to a revenue-sharing formula. The 2002 level of GDP per capita in the country divided by the
agreement describes how revenues are distributed: average across SACU members.
•• One hundred percent of customs revenue is distrib- Given the structure of the formula, fluctuations
uted on the basis of intra-SACU imports. in customs revenues have a larger impact on smaller
•• Eighty-five percent of excise revenue is distributed countries but are partially compensated by transfers
on the basis of members’ GDP. associated with the development component (Bas-
•• Fifteen percent of excise revenue is distributed devant 2012).
equally through a development component, with an Another source of volatility in the revenues stems
adjustment inversely proportional to the member’s from the forecasting and adjustment mechanism
GDP per capita. (Honda and others 2017). Transfers in any given year
As described in Basdevant (2012), the revenue (R) correspond to the forecasted value a year earlier, and
sharing formula is any discrepancies between forecast and actuals are
compensated the following year. Cuevas and others
( )
h − 1
Ri = a i C + 0.85 y i E + 0.15 _1 E 1– _
i
10
(2012) argue that this approach increases the predict-
5
ability of the revenues in the short term but over the
where C refers to custom duties and E to excises. medium term increases the variance of SACU transfers
For each country i, a iis the value at the border of beyond the variance of the underlying revenue pool.
developments have an impact on economic activity and with the procyclical structure of the sharing formula,
fiscal sustainability. creates strong economic links between SACU member
countries and can complicate the conduct of fiscal pol-
icy and macroeconomic management (Basdevant 2012;
Importance of Customs Unions Honda and others 2017).
For countries that share a customs union, fluc- Given the relative importance of the South Afri-
tuations in trade revenues constitute an important can economy in the union, the state of its economic
spillover channel. In the case of the SACU, member cycle is the main driver of the total amount of union
countries pool their trade-related revenues and excises receipts to be shared. Fluctuations in South Africa’s
and distribute them following a proportionality rule consumption and imports have a large impact on
(Box 7). Fluctuations in SACU revenues have a larger total SACU trade-related and excise revenues. Indeed,
impact on the fiscal revenues of smaller member coun- South African imports alone generate more than
tries because they represent a relatively larger portion 90 percent of the SACU revenue pool (Basdevant
of their total public revenues. For example, in Swa- 2012; IMF 2012). During periods of economic
ziland and Lesotho, SACU revenues constitute more expansion in South Africa, when both total demand
than 40 percent and 50 percent of total public reve- and import demand increase, there is an increase
nues, respectively (Figure 28, panel 1) (IMF 2016c). in total union-wide SACU revenues. On the other
The volatility of customs duties and excises can hand, SACU revenues experience large declines when
have substantial economic and fiscal impacts. SACU economic conditions deteriorate in South Africa, as
receipts as a share of government revenues or GDP was the case during the global financial crisis and more
can be highly volatile in the case of the smallest SACU recently as growth slowed in South Africa (Figure 28,
members. For instance, in Lesotho and Swaziland, panel 3). Declines in SACU revenues have led to sharp
the standard deviation of receipts as a share of GDP deteriorations in the fiscal position of SACU member
was between 5 percent and 7 percent for the period countries, with Lesotho and Swaziland most affected
2000–16 (Figure 28, panel 2). This volatility, together (Figure 28, panel 4). The deterioration was particularly
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 35
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 28. SACU Revenues and Selected Macroeconomic Indicators
1. SACU Revenues, 2000–16 2. Volatility of SACU Revenues, 2000–16
60 8
Percent of total government revenue
Percent of GDP, standard deviation
7
50
6
40
5
30 4
3
20
2
10
1
0 0
Swaziland Lesotho Namibia Botswana South Africa Lesotho Swaziland Botswana Namibia South Africa
3. SACU Revenues and South Africa Growth, 2000–16 4. Overall Fiscal Balance in SACU, 2006–16
SACU revenues, maximum and minimum South Africa Botswana
60 Median 6 16 Lesotho Namibia 8
South Africa growth (RHS) 5 12 Swaziland South Africa
50 growth (RHS)
Change, percent of GDP
4 8 4
40
Percent of GDP
3 4
30 2 0 0
1 –4
20
0 –8 –4
10
–1 –12
0 –2 –16 –8
2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 2006 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
5. Fiscal Balance, 2016 6. Current Account Balance, 2016
0 30
Current account excluding SACU transfers
–5 20 Current account balance
–10
10
Percent of GDP
Percent of GDP
–15
0
–20
–10
–25
Fiscal balance –20
–30 Fiscal balance excluding
–35 SACU transfers –30
–40 –40
Lesotho Swaziland Namibia Botswana South Africa Lesotho Namibia Swaziland South Africa Botswana
Sources: IMF, country team databases, World Economic Outlook.
pronounced in 2016, when the overall fiscal balance in revenues constitute an important source of foreign
Lesotho and Swaziland worsened by 9.5 percent and exchange inflows and contribute to the stock of
6 percent of GDP, respectively. international reserves (Honda and others 2017). For
Given the contribution of SACU revenues to fiscal example, in Namibia, these transfers are an important
and external deficits, spillovers originating from rev- source of foreign income, with the current account
enue fluctuations can have considerable implications (excluding SACU transfers) at 31 percent of GDP
for fiscal and external sustainability. For instance, (Figure 28, panel 6). In the context of the Common
in Lesotho, SACU revenues are critical to fiscal Monetary Area—in which Lesotho, Namibia, and
sustainability—in 2016 the fiscal deficit excluding Swaziland have pegged their currency to the South
regional revenues was 34 percent of GDP (Figure 28, African rand—fiscal sustainability has direct implica-
panel 5). In addition to the fiscal implications, SACU tions for external stability and the sustainability of the
36 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 29. Differentials between Nigerian Gasoline Prices and Those of Benin and Togo
1. Benin versus Nigeria Gasoline Prices 2. Togo versus Nigeria Gasoline Prices
700 700
600 600
500 500
400 400
300 300
200 200
Benin Formal Togo Formal
100 Nigeria 100 Nigeria
0 0
Jan. 2008
Jul. 08
Jan. 09
Jul. 09
Jan. 10
Jul. 10
Jan. 11
Jul. 11
Jan. 12
Jul. 12
Jan. 13
Jul. 13
Jan. 14
Jul. 14
Jan. 15
Jul. 15
Jan. 16
Jul. 16
Jan. 17
Jul. 17
Jan. 2008
Jul. 08
Jan. 09
Jul. 09
Jan. 10
Jul. 10
Jan. 11
Jul. 11
Jan. 12
Jul. 12
Jan. 13
Jul. 13
Jan. 14
Jul. 14
Jan. 15
Jul. 15
Jan. 16
Jul. 16
Jan. 17
Jul. 17
Sources: Country authorities; and IMF staff calculations.
Table 2. Fuel Prices Correlation in Togo, Benin and Nigeria, 2008–17
International oil Nigeria’s domestic Price differential
prices prices with Nigeria
Benin
Official prices 0.72 0.34
Informal market prices 0.3 0.63
Togo
Formal prices 0.49 0.31
Informal market prices 0.2 0.72
Domestic consumption 20.03 0.43 20.85
Nigeria
Official prices 0.01
Sources: Country authorities; and IMF staff calculations.
monetary arrangement (Basdevant 2012; Honda and average 2 percent of GDP per year), policies that do
others 2017). not reduce them are problematic.
Nigeria’s fuel subsidies are a quintessential example
of negative fuel pricing spillovers, which had serious
Unintended Spillovers from Nigeria’s Fuel Pricing fiscal impacts on Benin and Togo.14 Benin and Togo
Policies to Its Neighbors set about reforming their fuel pricing policies from
Fuel subsidies in sub-Saharan African countries have 2008 through 2012, while Nigeria continued to pro-
large fiscal costs and may have considerable negative vide subsidies. Inevitably, a significant price differential
spillovers to neighboring countries. Subsidies that arose between official fuel prices in these countries
lower fuel consumption costs in one country below and those in Nigeria, leading to increased operating
those in border countries tend to have the unintended margins for smugglers and more fuel smuggling (Fig-
consequence of cross-border fuel smuggling (IMF ure 29). The level of fuel sold on the formal (taxed)
2012). The negative externalities of smuggling are market declined precipitously in Benin to only 15 per-
particularly acute if the receiving country has an auto- cent of total consumption and was much less than it
matic fuel price adjustment mechanism that prevents should have been in Togo. This led to a smaller fuel tax
authorities from lowering fuel prices in line with smug-
gled prices. Given that fuel subsidies are expensive (on
14Inflation correlations between Nigeria and its neighboring coun-
tries are also strong, especially in food prices (IMF 2012).
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 37
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Figure 30. Sub-Saharan Africa: Within Migration, Refugees Figure 31. Sub-Saharan Africa and Selected Countries:
14
Internally Displaced Persons
Refugees Rest of migrants
13
1.3 1. SSA IDPs, 2010–16
12 1.1
11 8
10
7
Millions of persons
9
8 2.2 6
7
Millions of persons
6 11.8 5
3.1 11.2
5
4 4
3 6.7
3
2 4.1
1 2
0
1990 2000 10 13 1
Sources: United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees database; and World 0
2010 11 12 13 14 15 16
Bank, Migration and Remittances database.
2. IDPs by country, 2016
2.5 16
Number of IDPs (LHS)
base for legally consumed fuel in these two countries IDPs percent of 14
total population (RHS)
(Mlachila, Ruggiero, and Corvino 2015). 2.0
12
Nigeria’s price level had a large positive and sta-
Percent of population
tistically significant impact on foreign formal fuel 1.5 10
Millions of persons
consumption. In Togo, the correlation between formal 8
market consumption and the price differential vis-à-vis 1.0 6
Nigeria is –0.85 (Table 2). In 2011 this implied an
4
implicit subsidy of about 3 percent GDP to Togo, 0.5
three-quarters of which was captured by smugglers 2
and one-quarter by Togolese consumers, as their 0.0 0
welfare increased with the purchase of fuel at lower COD NGA SSD CAF CMR BDI TCD NER MLI COG MOZ
informal prices. Sources: United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees database; and World
In countries that provide subsidies, such as Nige- Bank, Migration and Remittances database.
ria, the first best approach is to follow international Note: See page 42 for country abbreviations table. LHS = left hand side;
RHS = right hand side.
fuel prices more closely by instituting an automatic
fuel pricing mechanism (see IMF 2013). In addition
to reducing fiscal costs, this would reduce negative
spillovers to the country’s neighbors. A second-best The Rising Socioeconomic Impact of
approach is more cooperation among countries to Forced Migration
control borders to reduce smuggling and further har- The number of internally displaced persons has risen
monization of tax policies to avoid generating negative significantly as a result of conflicts and violence, primarily
regional spillovers. the rise of religious extremism affecting the Sahel region
However, if there is large-scale smuggling, the first and northeastern Nigeria. These developments hurt eco-
best solution may not work effectively. In the pres- nomic activity and weigh on public expenditures.
ence of a porous border and large price differentials, While available statistics show evidence of a
automatic price adjustment—if it increases the price significant decline in the share of forced migration
differential—can lead to tax base erosion. In this case, across countries in sub-Saharan Africa through most
the best strategy may be to lower the tax rate, which is of the 1990s and 2000s, there are some indications
tantamount to lowering the domestic price (Mlachila, that the pace of the decline has slowed or partially
Ruggiero, and Corvino 2015). However, this approach reversed. The latest available migration data show that
may have substantial fiscal costs compared with a situa- the ratio of refugees to the total migrant population
tion of no smuggling. declined from over 40 percent in 1990 to 10 percent
38 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Figure 32. Selected Sub-Saharan African Countries: Civil Unrest and Terrorism
1. Civil Unrest, 2011–2017 2. Terrorism, 2011–2017
300 G5 Sahel 500 G5 Sahel
Cameroon Cameroon
Nigeria Nigeria
400
Number of incidents
Number of incidents
200
300
200
100
100
0 0
2011 12 13 14 15 16 17* 2011 12 13 14 15 16 17*
Sources: IMF, Corporate Services and Facilities Security Services database; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: * = August 2017.
in 2013 (Figure 30). This was a result of the decline in arms and the resultant elevated frequency of terrorist
large-scale conflicts in Southern and West Africa and attacks in the Sahel, especially in Burkina Faso and
the end of the Rwandan genocide (Gonzalez-Garcia Mali. Boko Haram attacks have been the leading
and others 2016). Since then, while the number cause of displacement of people in Niger, northeastern
of intraregional sub-Saharan African refugees has Nigeria, Chad, and northern Cameroon. In the other
declined, the number of internally displaced persons countries, domestic and neighboring political turmoil
has risen significantly (Figure 31, panel 1). The Sahel has been the driving factor of forced migration. For
countries, Nigeria, Democratic Republic of the Congo, instance, Uganda currently hosts more than 1.2 mil-
South Sudan, and Central African Republic, are lion refugees and asylum seekers, the highest number
among the countries most affected by internal displace- in sub-Saharan Africa and the third largest in the
ment triggered by conflicts and violence (Figure 31, world; they are mainly from South Sudan and Demo-
panel 2).15 Furthermore, while the number of refugees cratic Republic of the Congo (UNDP 2017).
has been falling, the absolute number of migrants has Forced migration reduces economic activity and has
risen considerably and is currently at record levels. The considerable humanitarian and fiscal costs stemming
increase in the number of migrants within sub-Saharan from both fighting terrorism and hosting displaced
Africa is likely driven by individuals seeking greater persons (IMF 2016b). This is the case in the Lake
economic opportunity and reflects reduced barriers to Chad area, where tourism has completely shut down.
the movement of people.16 While some economic activities may not be currently
There are many reasons for the increased number of affected (for example, mining in remote regions),
displaced persons. Across the Sahel countries, Nigeria, domestic and foreign investment is likely to be held
and Cameroon, terrorism-related events and civil con- back by the insecurity and the higher cost of doing
flicts have more than doubled since 2011 (Figure 32). business. The United Nations Office for the Coordina-
The collapse of the government in Libya, combined tion of Humanitarian Affairs estimates that the security
with the rise of religious extremism, has undoubtedly situation will result in nearly 30 million people suffer-
been the leading cause for civil conflict in the Sahel. ing food insecurity, with almost 12 million of these at
The direct impact has been increased availability of crisis or emergency levels. The office reports that the
Sahel region contended with approximately 4.9 million
15See the Internal Displacement Monitoring Centre website at refugees and internally displaced persons in 2017; it
http://www.internal-displacement.org/sub-saharan-africa/summary/. estimates the region’s humanitarian and financial needs
16For a detailed discussion of the economic determinants
at US$2.7 billion for that year. The fiscal costs of
of migration in sub-Saharan Africa, see Gonzalez-Garcia and
hosting displaced populations vary; they are estimated
others (2016).
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 39
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
to range between 1 percent and 5 percent of GDP, can have positive effects for medium-term growth in
depending on the number of displaced persons.17 sub-Saharan Africa.
Indeed, Sub-Saharan Africa hosts some of the biggest The analysis presented here suggests that the level of
refugee camps in the world (Gonzalez-Garcia and integration in sub-Saharan Africa is higher than com-
others 2016). monly assumed, and it has the potential to deepen on
many levels, supported by appropriate policies:
•• Trade integration is now at comparable levels with
Concluding Remarks that in other developing regions. Regional inte-
Over the past few decades, sub-Saharan Africa has gration policies—such as reduction of tariff and
been undergoing a process of regional integration that nontariff barriers—and improvements in transport
has materialized through many dimensions, including infrastructure can facilitate intraregional trade.
trade, banking, financial markets, financial innovation, Structural transformation strategies that promote
and customs and monetary unions—these changes diversification could minimize spillover risks
have likely increased the potential for regional spill- associated with overreliance on too few products
overs. What does this imply for the economic recovery and partners.
of the region now that the largest economies are expe- •• While greater integration and sophistication in the
riencing a tepid pick-up in growth after an extended regional financial systems are welcome, they pose
period of slow growth? As this note shows, the answer new risks, as they increase the interdependence of
depends on the dynamism of growth in countries with financial markets and the potential for contagion.
the highest potential to generate regional spillovers. Policies should address these risks by enforcing
In the context of the trade links, countries that have existing banking regulatory frameworks, strengthen-
been identified as the main destination for regional ing cooperation among supervisors, and developing
imports play a significant role in the growth of their cross-border bank resolution frameworks, which are
trading partners. Some of these countries, like South currently lacking.
Africa, are facing persistently sluggish economic activ- •• Ongoing financial and technological developments
ity, but others, such as Côte d’Ivoire, have maintained have translated into lower costs for sending remit-
fast growth for a decade. In terms of banking chan- tances throughout the region and have contributed
nels, PABs and subregional banks have contributed to rising regional remittance flows. It is essential
to the deepening of banking systems in the region, to provide a regulatory environment for these new
a development that has been associated with higher technologies that is both enabling and risk mitigat-
medium-term growth. In the context of remittance ing (IMF 2017a).
channels, the increase of intraregional remittance flows •• As economic integration deepens, public policies
in origin countries has an impact on the economic need to be mindful of fiscal spillovers to mitigate
activity of countries that receive remittances from the associated fiscal risks. This calls for greater harmoni-
region. The largest countries in the region have import- zation of fiscal policies.
ant fiscal policy spillovers, which can either boost or •• A recent resurgence in population displacement
derail growth in neighboring countries, depending on highlights the need for policies to address the
the state of their economies. main causes of forced migration, such as increased
As the sub-Saharan African economy has grown, economic and physical insecurity, and put in place
regional demand for intraregional exports has become a system that accommodates and integrates forced
an important market for goods produced in the region, migrants in host countries in a sustainable way.
regional banks have created new business opportuni- Increased international aid would greatly facilitate
ties and activity in the region, and remittance flows the process.
have contributed to economic activity in recipient
countries. Further enhancing regional integration This note stresses the growing need for policymakers
to factor in spillovers from within the region when
planning for the medium term and to design policies
17For instance, the United Nations Development Programme
that address increasing transmission risks.
estimates the cost of hosting refugees and asylum seekers in Uganda
at about US$320 million, or about 1.3 percent of GDP.
40 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
Appendix
Appendix Table 1. Sub-Saharan Africa: List of Country Abbreviations
AGO Angola ERI Eritrea MLI Mali SWZ Swaziland
BDI Burundi ETH Ethiopia MOZ Mozambique SYC Seychelles
BEN Benin GAB Gabon MUS Mauritius TCD Chad
BFA Burkina Faso GHA Ghana MWI Malawi TGO Togo
BWA Botswana GIN Guinea NAM Namibia TZA Tanzania
CAF Central African Republic GMB Gambia, The NER Niger UGA Uganda
CIV Côte d’Ivoire GNB Guinea-Bissau NGA Nigeria ZAF South Africa
CMR Cameroon GNQ Equitorial Guinea RWA Rwanda ZMB Zambia
COD Congo, Dem. Rep. of KEN Kenya SEN Senegal ZWE Zimbabwe
COG Congo, Rep. of LBR Liberia SLE Sierra Leone
COM Comoros LSO Lesotho SSD South Sudan
CPV Cabo Verde MGD Madagascar STP São Tomé & Príncipe
Appendix Table 2. Sub-Saharan Africa: Member Countries of Groupings
Other resource-intensive Non-resource-intensive
Oil exporters countries countries
Angola Botswana Benin
Cameroon Burkina Faso Burundi
Chad Central African Republic Cabo Verde
Congo, Rep. of Congo, Dem. Rep. of Comoros
Equatorial Guinea Ghana Côte d’Ivoire
Gabon Guinea Eritrea
Nigeria Liberia Ethiopia
South Sudan Mali Gambia, The
Namibia Guinea-Bissau
Niger Kenya
Sierra Leone Lesotho
South Africa Madagascar
Tanzania Malawi
Zambia Mauritius
Zimbabwe Mozambique
Rwanda
São Tomé and Príncipe
Senegal
Seychelles
Swaziland
Togo
Uganda
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 41
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Appendix Table 3. Sub-Saharan Africa: Member Countries of Regional Groupings
Southern
The West African Economic and Common Market African Economic
Economic and Monetary Community for Eastern and East Africa Development Southern Community of
Monetary Union of Central African Southern Africa Community Community Africa Customs West African
(WAEMU) States (CEMAC) (COMESA) (EAC-5) (SADC) Union (SACU) States (ECOWAS)
Benin Cameroon Burundi Burundi Angola Botswana Benin
Burkina Faso Central African Comoros Kenya Botswana Lesotho Burkina Faso
Republic
Côte d’Ivoire Chad Congo, Dem. Rep.of Rwanda Congo, Dem. Namibia Cabo Verde
Rep. of
Guinea-Bissau Congo, Rep. of Eritrea Tanzania Lesotho South Africa Côte d’Ivoire
Mali Equatorial Guinea Ethiopia Uganda Madagascar Swaziland Gambia, The
Niger Gabon Kenya Malawi Ghana
Senegal Madagascar Mauritius Guinea
Togo Malawi Mozambique Guinea-Bissau
Mauritius Namibia Liberia
Rwanda Seychelles Mali
Seychelles South Africa Niger
Swaziland Swaziland Nigeria
Uganda Tanzania Senegal
Zambia Zambia Sierra Leone
Zimbabwe Zimbabwe Togo
42 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Regional Spillovers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Exploring Different Channels
References Gupta, S., C. Patillo, and S. Wagh. 2009. “Effect of Remittances
on Poverty and Financial Development in Sub-Saharan
Allard C., J. Canales-Kriljenko, J. Gonzalez-Garcia, E. Kitsios,
Africa.” World Development 37 (1): 104–15.
J. Trevino, and W. Chen. 2016. “Trade Integration and
Hitaj, E., and Y. Onder. 2013. “Fiscal Discipline in the
Global Value Chains in Sub-Saharan Africa: In Pursuit of
WAEMU: Rules, Institutions and Markets.” IMF
the Missing Link.” African Department Departmental Paper,
Working Paper 13/216, International Monetary Fund,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Washington, DC.
Agrawal, I., Duttagupta, R., and Presbitero, A., 2017. “Inter-
Honda, J., F. Im, N. Koliadina, M. Morgan, M. Nose, C.
national Commodity Prices and Domestic Bank Lending in
Padilla, and J. Torres. 2017. “Fiscal Rules: Coping with Reve-
Developing Countries”. IMF Working Paper WP/17/279.
nue Volatility in Lesotho and Swaziland.” African Department
Arora, V., and A. Vamvakidis. 2005. “How Much Do Trading
Paper International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Partners Matter for Economic Growth?” IMF Staff Papers
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2012. “Nigeria and
52 (1): 24–40.
South Africa: Spillovers to the Rest of Sub-Saharan Africa,
Balami, D., I. Ogboru, and D. Talba. 2011. “The Cereal Econ-
Chapter 2 in SSA Regional Economic Outlook. Washington,
omy in Nigeria and the Sub-Regional Dimension.” Book,
DC, October.
Social Study Science Group, Vol. 1, No. 29.
———. 2013. “Energy Subsidy Reform—Lessons and Implica-
Basdevant, O. 2012. “Fiscal Policies and Rules in the Face of
tions.” Washington, DC.
Revenue Volatility within Southern Africa Customs Union
———. 2014. “South Africa—Financial Stability Assessment.”
Countries (SACU).” IMF Working Paper 12/93, Interna-
IMF Country Report 14/340, Washington, DC.
tional Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
———. 2015a.” Global Value Chains: Where Are You? The
Chen, W., and R. Nord. 2017. “A Rebalancing Act for China
Missing Link in Sub-Saharan Africa’s Trade Integration.”
and Africa: The Effect of China’s Rebalancing on Sub-Saharan
Chapter 3 in Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa.
Africa’s Trade and Growth.” African Department Paper. Inter-
Washington, DC, April.
national Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
———. 2015b. “International Banking after the Crisis: Increas-
Cihak, M., and R. Podpiera. 2005. “Bank Behavior in
ingly Local and Safer?” Chapter 2 in Global Financial Stability
Developing Countries: Evidence from East Africa.” IMF
Report. Washington, DC, April.
Working Paper 05/129, International Monetary Fund,
———. 2015c. “Pan-African Banks: Opportunities and Chal-
Washington, DC.
lenges for Cross-Border Oversight.” Washington, DC.
Cuevas, A., L. Engstrom, V. Kramarenko, and G. Verdier.
———. 2016a.” Financial Development and Sustain-
2012. “SACU Revenue Volatility: Roots and Options for
able Growth,” Chapter 3 in Regional Economic Outlook:
Mitigation.” In The Economics of Regional Integration: Current
Sub-Saharan Africa, Washington, DC, April.
and Future Challenges for Southern Africa. Washington, DC:
———. 2016b. “Macro-Financial Risks from Linkages between
International Monetary Fund.
Banks and Non-Bank Financial Institutions.” IMF Country
DNA Economics. 2013. “South African Investment in Africa.”
Report 16/374. Washington, DC.
Pretoria, South Africa.
———. 2016c.” Time for a Policy Reset.” Chapter 1 in
Dunne, P. J., and N. Masiyandima. 2017. “Bilateral Foreign
Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa Washing-
Direct Investment from South Africa and Income Conver-
ton, DC, April.
gence in the SADC Region.” African Development Review 20
———. 2017a. “Fintech and Financial Services: Initial
(3): 403–15.
Considerations.” IMF Staff Discussion Note,/17/05
Financial Stability Board (FSB). 2017. “FSB Correspondent
Washington, DC.
Banking Data Report.” Basel, Switzerland.
———. 2017b.” The Quest for Recovery.” Chapter 1 in
Furceri, D., J. T. Jalles, and A. Zdzienicka. 2016. “China
Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington,
Spillovers: New Evidence from Time-Varying Estimates.”
DC, October.
IMF Spillover Note 7, International Monetary Fund,
———. 2017c. “Restoring Sub-Saharan Africa’s Growth Engine.
Washington, DC.
“Chapter 1 in Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa,
Games, D. 2017. “South Africa’s Economic Engagement in
Chapter 1. Washington, DC, April.
Sub-Saharan Africa: Drivers, Constraints and Future Pros-
Jorion, P., and G. Zhang. 2009. “Credit Contagion from Coun-
pects.” Unpublished research paper, Chatham House, Royal
terparty Risk” Journal of Finance 64 (5): 2053–87.
Institute of International Affairs., London
Kinda, T., M. Mlachila, and R. Ouedraogo. 2016. “Commodity
Gonzalez-Garcia, J., E. Hitaj, M. Mlachila, A. Viseth, and M.
Price Shocks and Financial Sector Fragility.” IMF Working
Yenice. 2016. “Sub-Saharan Africa Migration: Patterns and
Paper 16/12, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Spillovers.” IMF Spillover Note 9, International Monetary
Mecagni, M., D. Marchettini, and R. Maino. 2015. “Evolving
Fund, Washington, DC.
Banking Trends in Sub-Saharan Africa: Key Features and
Challenges.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund | August 2018 43
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
SPILLOVER NOTES
Mlachila, M., E. Ruggiero, and D. Corvino. 2015. “Unintended Rey, H., 2015. “Dilemma Not Trilemma: The Global Financial
Consequences: Spillovers from Nigeria’s Fuel Pricing Policies Cycle and Monetary Policy Independence.” NBER Working
to Its Neighbors.” IMF Working Paper 15/17, International Paper No. 21162, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Cambridge, MA.
Mwase, N., P. N’Diaye, H. Oura, F. Ricka, K. Svirydzenka, and The World Bank, “Remittance Prices Worldwide” Issue 22, June
Y. Zhang. 2016. “Spillovers from China: Financial Chan- 2017, available at http://remittanceprices.worldbank.org.
nels.” IMF Spillover Note, International Monetary Fund, United Nations Development Programme. 2017. “Ugan-
Washington, DC. da’s Contribution to Refugee Protection and Manage-
Overseas Development Institute (ODI). 2010. “Impediments ment.”UNDP, Uganda.
to Intra-Regional Trade in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Lon-
don, September.
Presbitero, A. F., D. Ghura, O. S. Adedeji, and L. Njie. 2016.
“Sovereign Bonds in Developing Countries: Drivers of Issu-
ance and Spreads." Review of Development Finance 6.1: 1–15.
44 International Monetary Fund | August 2018
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution