JOURNAL
OF URBAN ECONOMlCS
30, 310-328
(1991)
The Elusive
PAUL
Hamilton
Received
Flypaper
GARY
College,
July 23,1989;
Effect
WYCKOFF*
Clinton,
revised
New York 13323
December
28, 1989
The flypaper
effect is the common empirical
result that lump-sum
intergovernmental grants stimulate
more local government
spending than increases in private
income which are theoretically
equivalent.
In this paper, four of the best-known
explanations
of the fiypaper
effect are tested, using data from Michigan
school
districts. None of these explanations
are confirmed
by the data. The cause of the
flypaper
effect is likely to be much more deeply rooted in the nature of local
o 1991 Academic
PMS, IX.
decision-making
than is currently
recognized.
I. INTRODUCTION
The flypaper effect is a well-known
anomaly in empirical studies of local
government expenditure behavior: compared to the effect of private income on government spending, lump-sum intergovernmental
aid causes a
disproportionately
large increase in spending. Money in the private sector,
from private income, tends to stick like flypaper to the private sector, and
not be taxed away. Money in the public sector, from intergovernmental
aid, tends to stick in the public sector and get spent there.
The exact meaning of the word “disproportionate”
in the previous
definition depends upon the model of local expenditure
determination
being used. In general, it means that the effect of lump-sum aid exceeds
that anticipated by the model. In the most popular model of Iocal public
choice, the median voter model, lump-sum aid affects spending by altering
the voter’s effective income. Since the median voter can vary local public
spending to suit his tastes, his share of lump-sum aid becomes a fungible
asset which can be used for public or private purposes, and which
therefore ought to be included in his total income. For example, if the
median voter decides to use his share of lump-sum
aid for private
consumption, he directs that the aid be used entirely to lower local taxes,
and his after-tax income rises by the amount of the lump-sum aid times his
tax share times the community’s share of expenditures under any matching
*I thank
Tom
Means
and the referee
for helpful
310
0094-1190/91
Copyright
All rights
$3.00
0 1991 by Academic
Press, Inc.
of reproduction
in any form rcservcd.
comments
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
EFFECT
311
grants. In the median voter model, then, a flypaper effect occurs when
increases in this share of lump-sum aid have a larger effect on spending
than increases in the median voter’s private income.
Almost every study of local public finance concludes that flypaper
effects do occur (for a review of such studies, see Fisher [5] and Gramlich
[6]). Although it may seem that, the flypaper effect is a minor detail in our
understanding of local public choice, it is likely to be a central question in
research on the process of public expenditure at all levels of government.
Lump-sum intergovernmental
grants represent one of the few observable
exogenous variables affecting real-world public finance decisions. For this
reason, it is possible to construct consistent models of their effects, and to
test those models. Other public finance variables, such as the price of
public goods, income in the community, and population, are endogenous
variables which both influence and are influenced by public expenditure
decisions. Hence, several theoretical relationships between these variables
are consistent with the data. Testing with these variables is difficult, and
progress in these areas is problematic. Lump-sum intergovernmental
aid,
therefore, represents one of the best available opportunities to understand
public finance decision-making.
In this paper I test four of the best-known explanations of the flypaper
effect: the arguments of Megdal [9] and Moffitt [ll] that econometric
misspecification is the cause of the flypaper effect; the position of Hamilton [7] that omitted variables create the flypaper effect; the suggestion by
Courant et al. [2] and Oates [13] that voters use the average price of public
goods as a proxy for their marginal price; and the explanation of Filimon
et al. [31 that voters are unaware of the existence of intergovernmental
aid.
No test of Hamilton’s hypothesis has ever been performed. Moffitt and
Megdal provide econometric tests of their theories, but there is no
comparison of their models with competing explanations. Filimon et al.
compare only their model and the fiscal illusion models of Courant et al.
and Oates.
Moreover, the Moffitt, Megdal, and Filimon et al. tests were performed
with different, specialized data sets making interpretation
of the results
difficult. For example, Moffitt uses state level spending on AFDC for his
dependent variable, and Filimon et al. use spending for school districts in
Oregon. To sort out the flypaper effect and with it the nature of local
public decision-making,
a comprehensive test of all these models with the
same data set is needed.
Based on the tests below, none of these theories hits the mark-the
cause of the flypaper effect eludes these authors. Each of these authors
suggests a “disease” which might be responsible for the “symptom” of
flypaper effects. But I find in each case that either the patient does not
have this disease (the data rejects the model) or the patient has the
312
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
private goods
expenditure
ity's
share of matching grant
education expenditure
FIG. 1. The bias created by using OLS with closed-end matching grants.
disease but it is not the cause of this particular symptom (correcting for
the problem does not reduce the flypaper effect).
Section II below tests the Moffitt-Megdal
and Hamilton models. Section III does the same for the fiscal illusion models. Section IV offers some
concluding comments.
II. FLYPAPER
EFFECTS DUE TO ANALYST
ERROR
The theoretical literature on flypaper effects can be broken into two
categories. In the first group, including the Moffitt-Megdal
and Hamilton
models, the analyst is fooled into erroneous conclusions about the flypaper
effect by failure to recognize an important feature of the problem. Most of
these explanations are confined to particular grant types, expenditure
categories, or institutional situations.
a. The Mo#itt-h4egdal
Model
i. The nature of the analyst’s error. In the case of closed-end matching
grants, Moffitt [ll] and Megdal [9] argue that contemporaneous correlation between the error term and the price and income variables of an OLS
equation have led to an observed flypaper effect. Figure 1 illustrates the
source of the problem.
Under a closed-end matching grant, the community receives matching
money up to some expenditure limit E*. Up to this limit, the price to the
community is reduced by the matching rate. Above the limit, the price
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
313
EFFECT
again returns to its original level. The grant has only an income effect, and
is usually classified as lump-sum.
Now suppose a community has characteristics such that, given the
functional form of the equation employed by the analyst, the community
should locate at point A on the diagram. But suppose instead that, due to
errors in observing the community’s output, or administrative and bureaucratic errors in carrying out the wishes of the community, we observe the
community at point B. The analyst records the community as having the
price and income associated with point B, and the estimation procedure
registers an error component for this community. This means that the
error term and the price and income variables are correlated, since
communities like this one which have large error terms also have low price
and income terms. As a result, the 0L.S estimates are inconsistent.
ii. Michigan’s aid to school districts. Michigan’s state aid system during
the 1978-1979 school year represents an ideal test of the Moffitt-Megdal
model. Because of the unusual aid system employed, all school districts
faced the nonlinear budget constraint discussed by these authors. General
school aid consisted of a lump-sum component of $274 per pupil and a
matching component in which the state share depended upon the level of
assessed value per pupil (measured by SEVPP-state
equalized value per
pupil) in the community.
Matching aid per pupil was set equal to
($40,000-SEVPP) times the tax rate of the school district. As the expenditures of the district increased, state matching continued until the community reached a tax level of 30 mills (one mill equals one one-thousandth of
the taxable value of property).
This system resulted in two budget constraints for these districts, depending upon their level of SEVPP. For districts with less than $40,000
SEVPP, state aid lowered the price of education up to the 30 mill limit. At
low tax rates, the school district contributed (tax rate) (SEVPP) (pupils),
with the state contributing (tax rate) (40,000-SEVPP) (pupils). The “price”
of a dollar of education was therefore
(tax rate) (SEVPP) (pupils)
[tax rate* SEVPP + (tax rate) (40,000-SEVPP)]
= SEVPP/$40,000.
* pupils
(1)
Beyond 30 mills, the community financed additional spending on its own;
state aid was lump-sum and equaled (0.03[$40,000-SEVPP]
+ $274) per
pupil. The budget set faced by these districts was convex but included a
kinked budget constraint, as depicted in Fig. 2.
For districts above $40,000 SEVPP, the same formulas applied, but they
had different effects. The school district still got $274 per pupil in
314
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
private
goods
expenditure
education
(.03[40,000+274])pUpilS=
1474*pupi1s
expenditure
FIG. 2. The convex case.
lump-sum aid, but it received negative matching aid. The district continued to pay SEVPP/$40,000
for extra dollars of school spending, but this
ratio was now bigger than one. The extra dollars were “taxed away” by the
state in the form of reduced state aid. This effect lasted until the aid
reached zero; the district did not have to pay any “tax” to the state. Thus,
at the point where -274 = (tax rateX$40,000-SEVPP),
aid was zero, and
private
goods
expenditure
= -SEvPP/40,00
+elope
= -1
m
education
SEVPP-40,000
FIG. 3. The concave case.
expenditure
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
EFFECT
315
the budget line became the same as under no state financing. The result is
the nonconvex budget set depicted in Fig. 3.
iii. Estimation technique. The biases inherent in ordinary least-squares
estimation under this aid scheme were avoided by using the nonlinear
procedure suggested by Wales and Woodland [17].l They reasoned that
the difficulty with OLS is that, by determining price and income according
to the observed position of the community on the budget constraint, the
analyst runs the risk of observing the community’s position incorrectly, or
that the community errs in trying to achieve its optimal position. These
problems create a specification error which leads to correlation between
the error term and the price and income variables. Wales and Woodland’s
solution to this problem is to assign points to segments according to the
community’s predicted demand, since this represents demand free of the
error term. By freeing price and income of their correlation with the error
term in this way, the bias caused by OLS regression is eliminated.
This sorting of communities by predicted demand was performed by a
nonlinear least-squares iterative technique. In each round, parameter
values were selected and communities were assigned to segments based on
their predicted demand under these parameters. Using the price and
income terms associated with these segments, the sum of squared residuals
was then calculated. The machine searched and selected the final parame‘Megdal [lo] presented Monte Carlo evidence that suggests that maximum likelihood
estimation gives the most desirable results for this estimation problem. However, as pointed
out by Moffitt [12], under certain circumstances nonlinear least-squares estimates are
equivalent to maximum likelihood estimates. Moffitt distinguishes between heterogeneity
error, which arises because individuals have differences in their utility function, and optimization or measurement error, which arises because the decisionmaker fails to achieve his utility
maximizing point or because the investigator measures the optimum point incorrectly. In the
case of optimization or measurement error only, nonlinear least-squares and maximum
likelihood estimates are equivalent.
Moffitt further points out that the two types of error can be distinguished by examining the
clustering of the data around the kink points. Optimization or measurement error tends to
spread points evenly around the constraints, while heterogeneity error tends to bunch points
around the kink points in the convex case (Fig. 2) and disperse points away from the kink in
the concave case (Fig. 3).
An examination of the data revealed no indication of heterogeneity error. One hundred
thirty-eight school districts in our sample faced a convex budget constraint, and only one of
those districts was on the kink. Further, only eight districts were within one mill of the
30-mill kink.
In the concave case, no bunching away from the school district’s limit of 274/(40,000SEVPP) occurred. There was a bimodal distribution, but the trough between the peaks
occurred well below the limit. Although there were only three observations in the range from
16 to 4 mills below the kink, there were 16 observations in the interval from 4 mills below the
kink to 8 mills above the kink.
316
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
ters so as to minimize the total sum of squares. To avoid the “Tiebout
bias” inherent in using metropolitan
data (see Rubinfeld et al. [KY]), all
school districts within SMSAs were deleted from the sample.
iv. Results. Table 1 presents a comparison of estimates using OLS and
the Wales and Woodland procedure. Table 2 presents variable definitions.
Four of the variables deserve special mention. First, following the median
voter literature, the price variable is the median voter’s tax share times the
community’s share of the costs under matching grants. Second, following
Tumbull [16] I have added the median voter’s share of lump-sum aid (as
described above) to his private income in order to determine his total
effective income Z. Third (and fourth), while median household income
would be the appropriate measure of private income, only median fumi/y
income was available for these school districts. Accordingly, I added the
ratio of families to unrelated individuals (HSRATIO)
and the percentage
of population 16 and up (PC16UP) to account for differences in the
composition of households across school districts. Neither variable, however, had a significant coefficient.
The two sets of estimates in Table 1 are close. In no case are the
differences in values in the two regressions statistically significant; for
example, the 0.171 value for the OLS regression for the income term is
within one standard error of the 0.207 value for the nonlinear regression.
More interesting, using the Moffitt-Megdal
approach does not appear to
“fix” the flypaper effect; in fact, it increases it. I measured the flypaper
effect by including the variable INCRATIO
in both regressions. This is the
ratio of the voter’s lump-sum aid share to his total effective income. If
there is no flypaper effect, the composition of income should not matter,
so this variable should have a zero coefficient; if flypaper effects exist, the
coefficient should be positive. Table 1 shows that correcting the inconsistency of OLS estimates increases the coefficient on INCRATIO
from
1.301 to 2.079, and makes the coefficient significant. There is no doubt that
Moffitt and Megdal have pointed out the theoretically correct way to
estimate demand functions in the face of closed-end matching grants, but
their correction does not explain the flypaper effect.
b. The Hamilton Model
In the case of police protection and education, Hamilton [7] argues,
private income represents both a pool of resources for consumption and a
surrogate for certain unobserved factors in the production of local public
goods. In education, for example, increased income in a community makes
possible increased spending on schools, but it also reduces the expenditure
levels necessary to reach a given level of learning on the part of pupils,
since educational studies show that children from families with higher
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
317
EFFECT
TABLE 1
Comparison of OLS and Nonlinear Least-Squares Regressions
OLS results
Variable
LNP
LNZ
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCIRANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCICH
INCRATIO
CATAID
HSRATIO
PC16UP
n = 202
R2
Nonlinear least-squares results
Estimate
(std. error)
- 0.153*
(0.033)
0.171”
(0.062)
0.630*
to.1751
-0.148
(0.104)
- 0.059
(0.096)
0.074
(0.072)
0.663*
(0.255)
- 0.200*
(0.100)
- 0.031
(0.239)
0.239
(0.149)
- 0.370
(0.209)
- 0.306*
(0.109)
- 0.823*
(0.395)
-0.186*
(0.032)
- 0.048*
(0.015)
0.414*
(0.064)
1.301
(1.1821
6.127E-04*
(6.412505)
4.486E-03
(3.312E-03)
0.108
(0.158)
,704
Variable
LNP
LNZ
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCTRANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNClCH
INCRATIO
CATAID
HSRATIO
PC16UP
n = 202
R*
Estimate
(std. error)
- 0.186*
(0.033)
0.207*
(0.0621
0.607*
to.1711
-0.146
(0.102)
- 0.036
(0.094)
0.049
(0.070)
0.534*
CO.2491
- 0.203*
(0.097)
- 0.092
CO.2341
0.254
(0.146)
- 0.422*
(0.204)
- 0.309*
(0.1071
- 0.646
(0.383)
-0.216*
(0.031)
- 0.047*
(0.015)
0.415*
(0.0631
2.079*
(0.584)
6.015E-04*
(6.254E-05)
4.579E-03
(3.253E-03)
0.143
(0.154)
.718
Nore. Dependent variable in both regressions is log of general expenditures, 1978-1979.
*Indicates variable is statistically significant at the 5% level.
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
318
TABLE 2
Variable Definitions
LNP
LNZ
PCBLACK
PCK05
PCK61
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCTRANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCTCH
INCRATIO
CATAID
HSRATIO
PC16UP
logarithm of tax price. Tax price is equal to the
voter’s tax share (median house value/taxable
property value in community) times the community’s
share of expenditures under matching aid
logarithm of total income, defined as
Z = median family income in community + p * G,
where G is lump-sum aid and p is tax price
percentage of population that is black
percentage of population aged 0 to 5
percentage of population aged 6 to 11
percentage of population in nonpublic schools
percentage of population that graduated from college
percentage of population that did not graduate from
high school
percentage of population that is female
percentage of population that is retired or permanently
disabled
percentage of population aged 65 and over
percentage of population that is unemployed
percentage of population receiving AFDC or food stamps
logarithm of enrollment in school district (1977-1978)
logarithm of 1977-1978 enrollment/number
of school
buildings
logarithm of county average teacher’s salary (1977-1978)
=p*G/Z
categorical aid
ratio of families to unrelated individuals
percentage of population age 16 or more
Note. Sources: US Census Bureau, “1970 Censuses of Population and Housing”; Michigan
Department of Education, Bulletin 1014, “Michigan School Districts Ranked by Selected
Financial Data, 1978-79.”
income and educational levels learn more rapidly than other children.
Thus, as income increases, expenditure increases may be held down by the
fact that children from higher-income homes require fewer educational
resources to achieve a given level of educational achievement. This effect
again causes lump-sum aid to have a greater expenditure effect than
income increases.
Table 3 contains a test of the Hamilton hypothesis that missing variables
cause the flypaper effect. In the table is a comparison of regressions with
and without many of the variables deemed important by Hamilton:
age,
sex, race, education level, unemployment
rates, and welfare recipient
rates. There may be missing variables not included in this list, but it
certainly includes the crucial variable-educational
level of the commu-
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
319
EFFECI
TABLE 3
Comparison of Regressions With and Without Socioeconomic Variables
Without extra variables
Variable
LNP
LNZ
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCTCH
INCRATIO
CATAID
HSRATIO
Estimate
(std. error)
-0X33*
(0.035)
0.296”
(0.050)
- 0.201*
(0.034)
- 0.048*
(0.016)
0.455*
(0.063)
1.491*
(0.613)
5.143E-04*
(4.779E-05)
l.O18E-03
(3.482E-03)
n = 202
R2
With extra variables
Variable
LNP
LNZ
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
Estimate
(std. error)
-0.186*
(0.033)
0.207*
(0.062)
0.607*
(0.171)
-0.146
(0.1021
- 0.036
(0.094)
0.049
(0.070)
0.534*
(0.249)
- 0.203*
(0.097)
- 0.092
(0.234)
623
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCTRANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCTCH
INCRATIO
CATAID
HSRATIO
PC16UP
0.254
(0.146)
- 0.422*
(0.204)
- 0.309*
(0.107)
- 0.646
(0.383)
- 0.216*
(0.031)
- 0.047*
(0.015)
0.415*
(0.063)
2.079*
(0.5841
6.015E-04*
(6.254E-05)
4.579E-03
(3.253E-03)
0.143
(0.154)
II = 202
R2
.718
Note. Dependent variable in both regressions is log of general expenditures, 1978-1979.
*Indicates variable is statistically significant at the 5% level.
320
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
TABLE 4
Correlation of INCRATIO with Socioeconomic Variables
Variable
Correlation with INCRATIO
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCTRANSF
PR16UP
- 0.015
0.276
0.290
0.004
-0.111
- 0.035
- 0.029
- 0.201
- 0.289
0.028
0.114
- 0.172
nity-which
Hamilton suggested was a cause of the flypaper effect in
education. To account for possible bias in the price and income terms, the
nonlinear approach of Moffitt and Megdal was employed in estimating
both equations.
These additional socioeconomic variables help explain expenditure levels in these communities. An F test of the hypothesis that these additional
explanatory variables are irrelevant rejects the hypothesis at the 1% level.
But these additional variables do not help to explain the flypaper effect.
First, the coefficient on INCRATIO
is increased, not reduced, when we
move to the more complete model. Second, as Table 4 shows, the correlation coefficients between INCRATIO
and the socioeconomic variables are
small-the
largest absolute value is less than 0.3. This suggests that the
flypaper effect is unlikely to fade away with the inclusion of these omitted
variables.
III.
FLYPAPER
EFFECTS
a. The Courant-Gramlich-Rubinfeld-Oates
DUE
TO VOTER
(CGRO)
ERROR
Model
i. The nature of the voter’s error. In the second fiscal illusion group of
flypaper effect theories, the voter is fooled by grants into making erroneous estimates of his effective income and the price of public goods.
Courant et al. [2] and Oates [13] argue that the typical voter has little
information about the extent of grants to his community. Accordingly, the
voter estimates the unknown marginal cost of public goods using other
known variables. By taking the ratio of his tax payments to total expenditures in the community, the voter can determine the average cost of public
goods and use this as an approximation
for their marginal cost. When
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
EFFECT
321
lump-sum aid is present, however, the use of this proxy causes the voter to
err in his estimate of marginal cost. If lump-sum aid is initially used to
finance additional expenditure, total expenditure increases while the median voter’s tax payments remain unchanged, thus driving down the
average price of public goods and leading the voter to mistakenly demand
more public goods. Because of this fiscal illusion, these writers argue,
lump-sum aid has a price as well as an income effect and we should not
expect the aid to have an expenditure impact that is equivalent to the
effect of an income increase.
ii. Estimation.
The most precise specification of the CGRO model of
flypaper effects is given by Oates [131. Oates employs the following formal
system:
E=T+A
P = T/E
p=mP
E = alYa2pa3
where
E is the
T is the
A is aid
P is the
p is the
Y is the
m is the
(budget constraint)
(formation of price to community)
(formation of price to the median voter)
(median voter’s demand function),
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
expenditure of the community,
community’s combined tax payment,
to the community (of all types),
price of the community,
price to the median voter,
median voter’s income, and
median voter’s tax share.
In this system, the voter first estimates the marginal price to the
community by looking at the average price of public goods. He then
multiples this figure by his tax share to get the price to him. p is then
incorporated into his demand function to determine the median voter’s
optimal output of public goods, and political competition ensures that this
is the output realized by the community.
Unfortunately,
because of the log-linear demand function, it is not
possible to solve this system explicitly for E. It is possible, however, to
formulate the following two-equation simultaneous system:
In E = a,/(1
+ a3) + [a,/(1
+ a,)]lnY
+ [a,/(1
+ a,)](lnm
+ 1nY)
(6)
T=E-A
(7)
Table 5 shows the results of two-stage least-squares estimation of (6)
and (7) using the Michigan school district data, when several additional
socioeconomic variables have been added to the equation. (Since the voter
322
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
TABLE 5
The CGRO Model
Variable
LNM + LNT
LNY
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCTRANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCTCH
HSRATIO
PC16UP
Estimate
(std. error)
- 0.322*
(0.048)
0.416*
(0.076)
1.493*
(0.192)
- 0.334*
(0.1221
0.007
(0.111)
0.212*
(0.084)
0.801*
(0.290)
- 0.389*
(0.1181
- 0.438
(0.275)
0.337
co.1751
- 0.275
(0.242)
0.244*
(0.106)
- 0.270
(0.442)
- 0.397*
to.0491
- 0.062*
(0.017)
0.723*
(0.0761
1.856E-03
(3.833E-03)
- 0.224
(0.1791
Fl = 202
R2
.596
Note. All variables defined in Table 2, except: LNM + LNT = the
sum of the logarithms of the voter’s tax share (median voter’s house
value/total property value in community) and the total tax revenue
of the community; LNY-logarithm of median family income in the
community. Dependent variable is log of general expenditures,
1978-1979.
*Indicates variable is statistically significant at the 5% level.
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
EFFECT
323
is unaware of the effect of aid on income and marginal price in the fiscal
illusion models, the nonlinear specification of Moffitt and Megdal is
unnecessary.) Although the estimates of the price and income elasticities
of demand are plausible, R2 is significantly less than in Table 1, suggesting
that the model does not fit the data well.
iii. Testing the CGRO model. Since the CGRO model is not a special
case of any more general model in this paper, a formal test of the CGRO
hypothesis is difficult. However, both the CGRO and Moffitt-Megdal
models can be considered special cases of the following theoretical model:
In E = b, + b,ln(Y + b,nmG)
+ b,[ln m + b4 In II + b, ln( T/E)]
+ b, incratio + b, categorical aid,
(8)
where, as before, additional socioeconomic variables have been omitted, G
stands for lump-sum aid, and n stands for the local government’s share of
expenditures under any matching grants. Under the CGRO assumptions,
b,, b,, b,, and b, are all zero and b, equals one, while under the
Moffitt-Megdal
model, b, and b, are zero while b, and b4 equal one.
Equation (8) would be extremely difficult to estimate as a general case.
Not only is it nonlinear, but the estimation technique must account for
both the endogeneity of n and G (as Moffitt and Megdal insist) and the
simultaneity of E and T (as required by CGRO). However, the purpose of
estimating (8) would be to find the unrestricted sum of squared residuals
to perform an F test on the CGRO restrictions. This suggests that we
might use the Moffitt-Megdal
model as a stand in for (8). Since the
Moffitt-Megdal
case is a restricted form of (81, its sum of squared
residuals must be larger than that of (8). Therefore,
using the
Moffitt-Megdal
model as a stand-in works in &or of the CGRO model,
because the difference in the sum of squared residuals will be smaller. If
an F test using the Moffitt-Megdal
stand-in rejects the CGRO model, an
F test using (8) would also reject CGRO.’
*Proof: The appropriate F statistic is given by
(SSRQ - SSR,)(n - Q)
’
SSE&Q - K)
where:
SSRe is the regression sum of squares for the unrestricted model,
SSR, is the regression sum of squares for the restricted model,
n is sample size,
Q is the number of parameters in the unrestricted regression,
SSEp is the error sum of squares in the unrestricted regression, and
K is the number of parameters in the restricted regression (see Kmenta [8]). Since the
Moffitt-Megdal model is a restricted form of the unrestricted model, it must have a smaller
324
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
Using this procedure, the CGRO restrictions are rejected. The F
statistic is 15.395, while the appropriate cutoff value is 3.17 at the 1%
level. Therefore, it is extremely unlikely that the CGRO model is correct.
As an additional check on incomplete fiscal illusion, average tax rates
were added to the Moffitt-Megdal
specification (including all the variables
in Table l), again using two-stage least-squares to account for simultaneity. (As explained above, due to the complexity of the estimated equation,
the Wales-Woodland
procedure could not be employed, but its use
appears to have little influence on the results.) In this case the coefficient
on average tax rate, although significant, was of the wrong sign. It should
have the same sign as the coefficient on the median voter’s tax share. Also,
the inclusion of average tax rate increased, rather than decreased, the
coefficient on INCRATIO.
b. The Filimon-Romer-Rosenthal
(FRR) Model
Filimon et al. [3] suggest another stronger variant of these voter ignorance theories. In their version, voter ignorance about aid and expenditure
levels is combined with budget-maximizing
bureaucrats. Voters in their
model are unaware of the existence of intergovernmental
grants, and they
calculate the marginal cost of public goods by estimating their share of
taxes in the community. Moreover, because of voter misinformation,
the
bureaucrat can find ways to pad the budget without altering the voters’
perceived level of output.
Intergovernmental
grants, then, do not alter the voter’s perception of
his budget constraint. This leaves the bureaucrat free to use these “hidden” resources to expand his budget through hidden expenditures. In the
FRR model, then, intergovernmental
aid must be eliminated from the
price and income terms of the equation, and $1 of intergovernmental
aid
(of whatever type) expands the budget by $1. In Table 6, a simple test of
this hypothesis is performed, using the log-linear specification. Intergovernmental aid appears only in the term LNTOTAID.
The effect of
intergovernmental
aid is much more modest than predicted by FRR.
Differentiating
the FRR specification gives:
dE/d( aid) = (coefficient
The
upper
on LNTOTALAID)*
end of the confidence
interval
E/( aid).
for the coefficient
(9)
on
SSRO and a larger SSEQ than the unrestricted model. Hence its use biases the numerator
downward, the denominator upward, and the F statistic downward, and biases our test
toward the conclusion that there is no significant difference between the CGRO and
unrestricted models.
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
TABLE 6
The Romer-Rosenthal
Variable
LNM
LNY
LNTOTAID
PCBLACK
PCKOS
PCK611
PCKNPUB
PCCLGRAD
PCNONHS
PCFEMALE
PCRTRDI
PCAGE65
PCUNEMP
PCT RANSF
LNENRL
LNPPB
LNCTCH
HSRATIO
PC16UP
n = 202
R2
EFFECT
Model
Estimate
(std. error)
-0.142*
(0.031)
0.224*
(0.071)
0.044*
(0.020)
1.128”
(0.207)
-0.159
(0.127)
0.040
(0.118)
0.089
(0.087)
0.479
(0.338)
- 0.214
(0.121)
- 0.350
(0.290)
0.224
(0.183)
- 0.240
(0.255)
0.210
(0.113)
0.444
(0.489)
-0.201*
(0.032)
- 0.044*
(0.018)
0.551*
(0.076)
- 1.644E-03
(4.002E-03)
- 0.162
(0.188)
.544
Note. All variables defined in Tables 2 and 5, except:
LNTOTAID
= log of total aid to the community. Dependent
variable is log of general expenditures, 1978-1979.
*Indicates variable is statistically significant at the 5% level.
325
326
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
LNTOTAID
is 0.084. When multiplied by the sample mean for E/(aid) of
3.632, the estimated derivative is just 0.305, implying a strong rejection of
the FRR specification.
VI. CONCLUSION
There are other explanations of the flypaper effect in the literature.
These explanations are not tested in this paper, but for the most part they
do not apply to the circumstances faced in this study. For example,
Chernick [l] developed an explanation of flypaper effects when project
grants are included in the lump-sum aid category, but project grants are
not present in the lumps-sum aid variable in the regressions below. Romer
and Rosenthal [14] developed a second theory which blames flypaper
effects on the institutional
arrangements for approving the bureaucrat’s
budget in some states, in which the budget drops to a state-mandated
reversion level if the bureaucrat’s proposed budget is not approved.
Therefore, this second Romer-Rosenthal
explanation of flypaper effects is
confined to a limited set of circumstances. The Michigan school districts in
this study faced a more complex set of institutional arrangements in which
the reversion level was not likely to have a significant effect.3 Similarly,
Fisher [4] has noted that tax effort requirements in revenue sharing
formulas can cause a flypaper effect, but Michigan school districts do not
receive revenue sharing of this type.
The skeptical reader might argue that all of the results above relate only
to the case of Michigan school districts at this particular time. There is no
guarantee, of course, that Michigan school districts are not unusual, and
that these four theories do not have relevance for other circumstances.
‘Michigan property tax laws require voter approval of property tax rates, and there are
state-mandated “allocated” millage rates if the voters refuse to approve a specific tax rate.
But the situation is more complicated than the simple binary choice analyzed by Romer and
Rosenthal. First, in Michigan, additional higher tax requests are separated from requests to
renew the existing millage. Hence the typical voter has a three-part, rather than two-part,
choice: he can vote for the additional millage and the renewal, he can vote for the renewal
only, or he can vote against both proposals. This complicates the analysis. Furthermore, the
allocated millage is typically so low (less than one-third of current tax rates) that few voters
are likely to find it attractive, so the choice for most voters is between the existing millage
and a new, higher proposed tax rate. Second, tax approvals are for varying periods of time.
Voters approve the term of the tax rate as well as its amount at the time of voting. Tax rates
can be approved for an indefinite period, but most referenda are for less than 5 years
duration. This means that the voter and the bureaucrat must introduce future expectations of
each other’s demands into their thinking. Third, a sequence of elections is common in
Michigan. After the initial proposal is defeated, school boards can go back to the voters for a
second, a third, or even a fourth time. Hence voters know that the alternative to defeating
the school boards proposal is not the state-mandated reversion level, but rather approving a
later, smaller proposal from the school board. All these factors reduce the influence of the
state-mandated reversion on the expenditures of the school district.
THE ELUSIVE
FLYPAPER
EFFECT
327
But the skeptic’s position requires the simultaneous conjunction of a
number of unlikely factors. If flypaper effects are caused by different
factors in different places and times, why do these effects show up so
consistently and so significantly in empirical studies? If a number of
factors were involved, surely the empirical results on flypaper effects
would be more mixed than we observe. This problem is particularly severe
since many of the explanations of flypaper effects-such
as those of
Moffitt and Megdal and Hamilton-relate
only to particular types of
grants of particular types of public goods. How can these particular
explanations account for the nearly universal phenomenon of flypaper
effects?
The data are more consistent with the idea that the flypaper effect is
caused by a single factor which is imbedded much more deeply in the
process of local government decision-making
than is currently acknowledged. Only through such a consistent factor could the strength and
universality of flypaper effects be easily explained. The nature of this
factor has eluded the authors of these four theoretical explanations.
In a previous article in this journal (Wyckoff [IS]), I suggested that
bureaucracy might be such a deeply imbedded factor. My explanation
included two components: (1) a bureaucrat who sought to increase the size
of his budget or “pad” it with unnecessary expenses; and (2) a voter whose
alternative to living with a particular bureaucracy was to move to a new
jurisdiction. The flypaper effect occurs because of an asymmetry in the
voter’s bargaining position with bureaucrats under lump-sum aid and
increases in income. A lump-sum aid increase stays with the jurisdiction if
the voter moves, so the voter’s bargaining position is not enhanced by the
aid. An income increase, on the other hand, would be moved to the new
jurisdiction if the voter gets fed up with the bureaucracy, so it increases
the value of the voter’s threat to leave. This difference in threat value
holds down spending in the income increase case but not in the lump-sum
aid case, creating a flypaper effect.
It must be admitted, however, that testing for these more deeply
imbedded factors is more difficult than testing for the explanations offered
above, because there is no way to correct for or isolate the factor. If
flypaper effects are caused by the use of the wrong econometric technique,
we can simply use the right technique, see if that eliminates the problem,
and attribute the flypaper effect to econometric causes if it does. But the
only way to correct for bureaucratic influence is to find a jurisdiction
without that influence, which presumably would be difficult.
In the future, then, tests of the causes of flypaper effect will probably be
accomplished only indirectly, through testing for the presence of other
empirical implications
of the underlying models. For example, in two
papers (Wyckoff [18, 1911, I showed that the theoretical implications of
328
PAUL GARY WYCKOFF
bureaucratic influence are consistent with the empirical behavior of local
governments. In this way, the debate about the flypaper effect is likely to
merge into the more general debate about who controls the local fist.
REFERENCES
1. H. A. Chemick, An economic model of the distribution of project grants, in “Fiscal
Federalism and Grants-in-Aid” (P. Mieszkowski and W. H. Oakland, Eds.), The
Urban Institute, Washington, DC (1979).
2. P. N. Courant, E. M. Gramlich, and D. L. Rubinfeld, The stimulative effects of
intergovernmental grants: Or why money sticks where it hits, in “Fiscal Federalism
and Grants-in-Aid” (P. Mieszkowski and W. H. Oakland, Eds.), The Urban Institute,
Washington, DC (1979).
3. R. Filimon, T. Romer, and H. Rosenthal, Asymmetric information and agenda control:
The bases of monopoly power in public spending, Journal of Public Economics,
17,
51-70 (1982).
4. R. C. Fisher, A theoretical view of revenue sharing grants, National Tax Journal, 32,
173-84 (1979).
5. R. C. Fisher, Income and grant effects on local expenditure: The flypaper effect and
other difficulties, Journal of Urban Economics, 12, 324-45 (1982).
6. E. M. Gramlich, Intergovernmental grants: A review of the empirical literature, in “The
Political Economy of Fiscal Federalism” (W. E. Oates, Ed.), Lexington Press,
Lexington, MA (1977).
7. B. W. Hamilton, The flypaper effect and other anomalies, Journal of Public Economics,
22, 347-61 (1983).
8. J. Kmenta, “Elements of Econometrics,” Macmillan, New York (1971).
9. S. B. Megdal, The flypaper effect revisited: An econometric explanation, Review of
Economics
and Statistics, 69, 232-240
(1987).
10. S. B. Megdal, The econometrics of piecewise-linear budget constraints: A Monte Carlo
study, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 5, 243-248 (1987).
11. R. Moffitt, The effects of grants-in-aid on state and local expenditures: The case of
AFDC,
Journal of Public Economics,
23, 279-305
(1984).
12. R. Moffitt, The econometrics of piecewise-linear budget constraints: A survey and
exposition of the maximum likelihood method, Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics, 4, 317-328 (1986).
13. W. E. Oates, Lump-sum intergovernmental grants have price effects, in “Fiscal Federalism and Grants-in-Aid” (P. Mieszkowski and W. H. Oakland, Eds.), The Urban
Institute, Washington, DC (1979).
14. T. Romer and H. Rosenthal, Bureaucrats versus voters: On the political economy of
resource allocation by direct democracy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 563-87
(1979).
15. D. L. Rubinfeld, P. Shapiro, and J. Roberts, Tiebout bias and the demand for local
public schooling, Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 426-437 (1987).
16. G. K. Turnbull, On the interpretation of reduced form public demand parameter
estimates, National Tax Journal, 33, 567-569 (1985).
17. T. J. Wales and A. D. Woodland, Labor supply and progressive taxes, Review of
Economic
Studies, 46, 83-95 (1979).
18. P. G. Wyckoff, A bureaucratic theory of flypaper effects, Journal of Urban Economics, 23,
115-129 (1988).
19. P. G. Wyckoff, Testing bureaucratic influence by comparing survey and expenditure data,
Review of Economics
and Statistics, forthcoming.