Aggregation of Energy
CUTLER J. CLEVELAND and ROBERT K. KAUFMANN
Boston University
Boston, Massachusetts, United States
DAVID I. STERN
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute
Troy, New York, United States
Glossary
variable as an independent variable, (ii) the relation is
bidirectional, or (ii) no meaningful relation exists. This
is usually done by testing whether lagged values of one
of the variables add significant explanatory power to a
model that already includes lagged values of the
dependent variable and perhaps also lagged values of
other variables.
marginal product of energy The value marginal product of
a fuel in production is the marginal increase in the
quantity of a good or service produced by the use of one
additional heat unit of fuel multiplied by the price of
that good or service.
net energy analysis Technique that compares the quantity
of energy delivered to society by an energy system to the
energy used directly and indirectly in the delivery
process.
Divisia index A method of aggregation used in economics
that permits variable substitution among material types
without imposing a priori restrictions on the degree of
substitution.
emergy The quantity of solar energy used directly and
indirectly to produce a natural resource, good, or
service.
energy quality The relative economic usefulness per heat
equivalent unit of different fuels and electricity.
energy/real gross domestic product (GDP) ratio (E/GDP
ratio) The ratio of total energy use to total economic
activity; a common measure of macroeconomic energy
efficiency.
energy return on investment (EROI) The ratio of energy
delivered to energy costs.
exergy The useful work obtainable from an energy source
or material is based on the chemical energy embodied in
the material or energy based on its physical organization relative to a reference state. Exergy measures the
degree to which a material is organized relative to a
random assemblage of material found at an average
concentration in the crust, ocean, or atmosphere.
Granger causality A statistical procedure that tests
whether (i) one variable in a relation can be meaningfully described as a dependent variable and the other
Investigating the role of energy in the economy
involves aggregating different energy flows. A variety
of methods have been proposed, but none is accepted
universally. This article shows that the method of
aggregation affects analytical results. We review the
principal assumptions and methods for aggregating
energy flows: the basic heat equivalents approach,
economic approaches using prices or marginal
product for aggregation, emergy analysis, and
thermodynamic approaches such as exergy analysis.
We argue that economic approaches such as the
index or marginal product method are superior
because they account for differences in quality
among different fuels. We apply economic approaches to three case studies of the U.S. economy.
In the first, we account for energy quality to assess
changes in the energy surplus delivered by the
extraction of fossil fuels from 1954 to 1992. The
second and third case studies examine the effect of
energy quality on statistical analyses of the relation
between energy use and gross domestic product
1.
2.
3.
4.
Energy Aggregation and Energy Quality
Economic Approaches to Energy Quality
Alternative Approaches to Energy Aggregation
Case Study 1: Net Energy from Fossil Fuel Extraction in
the United States
5. Case Study 2: Causality in the
Energy/GDP Relationship
6. Case Study 3: The Determinants of the
Energy/GDP Relationship
7. Conclusions and Implications
Encyclopedia of Energy, Volume 1. r 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
17
Aggregation of Energy
(GDP). First, a quality-adjusted index of energy
consumption is used in an econometric analysis of
the causal relation between energy use and GDP
from 1947 to 1996. Second, we account for energy
quality in an econometric analysis of the factors that
determined changes in the energy/GDP ratio from
1947 to 1996. Without adjusting for energy quality,
the results imply that the energy surplus from
petroleum extraction is increasing, that changes in
GDP drive changes in energy use, and that GDP has
been decoupled from aggregate energy. These conclusions are reversed when we account for changes in
energy quality.
1. ENERGY AGGREGATION AND
ENERGY QUALITY
Aggregation of primary-level economic data has
received substantial attention from economists for a
number of reasons. Aggregating the vast number of
inputs and outputs in the economy makes it easier for
analysts to discern patterns in the data. Some
aggregate quantities are of theoretical interest in
macroeconomics. Measurement of productivity, for
example, requires a method to aggregate goods
produced and factors of production that have diverse
and distinct qualities. For example, the post-World
War II shift toward a more educated workforce and
from nonresidential structures to producers’ durable
equipment requires adjustments to methods used to
measure labor hours and capital inputs. Econometric
and other forms of quantitative analysis may restrict
the number of variables that can be considered in a
specific application, again requiring aggregation.
Many indexes are possible, so economists have
focused on the implicit assumptions made by the
choice of an index in regard to returns to scale,
substitutability, and other factors. These general
considerations also apply to energy.
The simplest form of aggregation, assuming that
each variable is in the same units, is to add up the
individual variables according to their thermal
equivalents (Btus, joules, etc.). Equation (1) illustrates this approach:
Et ¼
N
X
Eit ;
energy and the fact that thermal equivalents are
easily measured. This approach underlies most
methods of energy aggregation in economics and
ecology, such as trophic dynamics national energy
accounting, energy input–output modeling in economies and ecosystems, most analyses of the energy/
gross domestic product (GDP) relationship and
energy efficiency, and most net energy analyses.
Despite its widespread use, aggregating different
energy types by their heat units embodies a serious
flaw: It ignores qualitative differences among energy
vectors. We define energy quality as the relative
economic usefulness per heat equivalent unit of
different fuels and electricity. Given that the composition of energy use changes significantly over time
(Fig. 1), it is reasonable to assume that energy quality
has been an important economic driving force. The
quality of electricity has received considerable attention in terms of its effect on the productivity of labor
and capital and on the quantity of energy required to
produce a unit of GDP. Less attention has been paid
to the quality of other fuels, and few studies use a
quality-weighting scheme in empirical analysis of
energy use.
The concept of energy quality needs to be
distinguished from that of resource quality. Petroleum and coal deposits may be identified as highquality energy sources because they provide a very
high energy surplus relative to the amount of energy
required to extract the fuel. On the other hand, some
forms of solar electricity may be characterized as a
100
Percent of total energy use
18
75
50
where E is the thermal equivalent of fuel i (N types)
at time t. The advantages of the thermal equivalent
approach are that it uses a simple and well-defined
accounting system based on the conservation of
Coal
Oil
Gas
25
Animal
feed
Electricity
ð1Þ
i¼1
Wood
0
1800 1825 1850 1875 1900 1925 1950 1975 2000
FIGURE 1 Composition of primary energy use in the United
States. Electricity includes only primary sources (hydropower,
nuclear, geothermal, and solar).
Aggregation of Energy
low-quality source because they have a lower energy
return on investment (EROI). However, the latter
energy vector may have higher energy quality
because it can be used to generate more useful
economic work than one heat unit of petroleum or
coal.
Taking energy quality into account in energy
aggregation requires more advanced forms of aggregation. Some of these forms are based on concepts
developed in the energy analysis literature, such as
exergy or emergy analysis. These methods take the
following form:
Et ¼
N
X
lit Eit ;
ð2Þ
i¼1
where l represents quality factors that may vary
among fuels and over time for individual fuels. In the
most general case that we consider, an aggregate
index can be represented as
f ðEt Þ ¼
N
X
lit gðEit Þ;
ð3Þ
i¼1
where f( ) and g( ) are functions, lit are weights, the Ei
are the N different energy vectors, and Et is the
aggregate energy index in period t. An example of
this type of indexing is the discrete Divisia index or
Tornquist–Theil index described later.
2. ECONOMIC APPROACHES TO
ENERGY QUALITY
From an economic perspective, the value of a heat
equivalent of fuel is determined by its price. Pricetaking consumers and producers set marginal utilities
and products of the different energy vectors equal to
their market prices. These prices and their marginal
productivities and utilities are set simultaneously in
general equilibrium. The value marginal product of a
fuel in production is the marginal increase in the
quantity of a good or service produced by the use of
one additional heat unit of fuel multiplied by the
price of that good or service. We can also think of the
value of the marginal product of a fuel in household
production.
The marginal product of a fuel is determined in
part by a complex set of attributes unique to each
fuel, such as physical scarcity, the capacity to do
useful work, energy density, cleanliness, amenability
to storage, safety, flexibility of use, and cost of
conversion. However, the marginal product is not
uniquely fixed by these attributes. Rather, the energy
19
vector’s marginal product varies according to the
activities in which it is used; how much and what
form of capital, labor, and materials it is used in
conjunction with; and how much energy is used in
each application. As the price rises due to changes on
the supply side, users can reduce their use of that
form of energy in each activity, increase the amount
and sophistication of capital or labor used in
conjunction with the fuel, or stop using that form
of energy for lower value activities. All these actions
raise the marginal productivity of the fuel. When
capital stocks have to be adjusted, this response may
be somewhat sluggish and lead to lags between price
changes and changes in the value marginal product.
The heat equivalent of a fuel is just one of the
attributes of the fuel and ignores the context in which
the fuel is used; thus, it cannot explain, for example,
why a thermal equivalent of oil is more useful in
many tasks than is a heat equivalent of coal. In
addition to attributes of the fuel, marginal product
also depends on the state of technology, the level of
other inputs, and other factors. According to
neoclassical theory, the price per heat equivalent of
fuel should equal its value marginal product and,
therefore, represent its economic usefulness. In
theory, the market price of a fuel reflects the myriad
factors that determine the economic usefulness of a
fuel from the perspective of the end user.
Consistent with this perspective, the price per heat
equivalent of fuel varies substantially among fuel
types (Table I). The different prices demonstrate that
end users are concerned with attributes other than
heat content. Ernst Berndt, an economist at MIT,
noted that because of the variation in attributes
among energy types, the various fuels and electricity
are less than perfectly substitutable, either in
production or in consumption. For example, from
the point of view of the end user, 1 Btu of coal is not
perfectly substitutable with 1 Btu of electricity; since
the electricity is cleaner, lighter, and of higher quality,
most end users are willing to pay a premium price per
Btu of electricity. However, coal and electricity are
substitutable to a limited extent because if the
premium price for electricity were too high, a
substantial number of industrial users might switch
to coal. Alternatively, if only heat content mattered
and if all energy types were then perfectly substitutable, the market would tend to price all energy types
at the same price per Btu.
Do market signals (i.e., prices) accurately reflect
the marginal product of inputs? Empirical analysis of
the relation between relative marginal product and
price in U.S. energy markets suggests that this is
20
Aggregation of Energy
industrial output, and that electricity is 2.7–18.3
times more productive than coal.
TABLE I
U.S. Market Price for Various Energy Typesa
Market price ($/106 btu)
Energy type
Coal
If marginal product is related to its price, energy
quality can be measured by using the price of fuels to
weight their heat equivalents. The simplest approach
defines the weighting factor (l) in Eq. (2) as
Pit
lit ¼
;
ð4Þ
P1t
Bituminous
Mine-mouth
Consumer cost
Anthracite
Mine-mouth
Oil
Wellhead
Distillate oil
2.97
7.70
Jet fuel
4.53
LPG
7.42
Motor gasoline
9.73
Residual fuel oil
2.83
Biofuels
Consumer cost
Natural gas
Wellhead
2.10
Consumer cost
a
2.1 Price-Based Aggregation
20.34
Source. Department of Energy (1997). Values are 1994 prices.
TABLE II
Marginal Product of Coal, Oil, Natural Gas, and Electricity
Relative to One Another
Minimum
Year
Maximum
Year
Oil : coal
1.83
1973
3.45
1990
Gas : coal
1.43
1973
2.76
1944
Electricity : coal
4.28
1986
16.42
1944
Oil : gas
0.97
1933
1.45
1992
Electricity : oil
1.75
1991
6.37
1930
Electricity : gas
2.32
1986
6.32
1930
indeed the case. In the case of the United States, there
is a long-term relation between relative marginal
product and relative price, and several years of
adjustment are needed to bring this relation into
equilibrium. The results are summarized in Table II
and suggest that over time prices do reflect the
marginal product, and hence the economic usefulness, of fuels.
Other analysts have calculated the average product of fuels, which is a close proxy for marginal
products. Studies indicate that petroleum is 1.6–2.7
times more productive than coal in producing
where Pit is the price per Btu of fuel. In this case, the
price of each fuel is measured relative to the price of
fuel type 1.
The quality index in Eq. (4) embodies a restrictive
assumption—that fuels are perfect substitutes—and
the index is sensitive to the choice of numeraire.
Because fuels are not perfect substitutes, an increase
in the price of one fuel relative to the price of output
will not be matched by equal changes in the prices of
the other fuels relative to the price of output. For
example, the increase in oil prices in 1979–1980
would cause an aggregate energy index that uses oil
as the numeraire to decline dramatically. An index
that uses coal as the numeraire would show a large
decline in 1968–1974, one not indicated by the oilbased index.
To avoid dependence on a numeraire, a discrete
approximation to the Divisia index can be used to
aggregate energy. The formula for constructing the
discrete Divisia index E* is
ln Et ln Et1
¼
n
X
i¼1
P E
Pit1 Eit1
P it it
þ P
2 ni¼1 Pit Eit 2 ni¼1 Pit1 Eit1
ðln Eit ln Eit1 ÞÞ
ð5Þ
where P are the prices of the n fuels, and E are the
quantities of Btu for each fuel in final energy use.
Note that prices enter the Divisia index via cost or
expenditure shares. The Divisia index permits variable substitution among material types without
imposing a priori restrictions on the degree of
substitution. This index is an exact index number
representation of the linear homogeneous translog
production function, where fuels are homothetically
weakly separable as a group from the other factors
of production. With reference to Eq. (3), f( ) ¼
g( ) ¼ Dln( ), whereas lit is given by the average cost
share over the two periods of the differencing
operation.
Aggregation of Energy
21
2.2 Discussion
3.1 Exergy
Aggregation using price has its shortcomings. Prices
provide a reasonable method of aggregation if the
aggregate cost function is homothetically separable in
the raw material input prices. This means that the
elasticity of substitution between different fuels is not
a function of the quantities of nonfuel inputs used.
This may be an unrealistic assumption in some cases.
Also, the Divisia index assumes that the substitution
possibilities among all fuel types and output are equal.
Another limit on the use of prices is that they
generally do not exist for wastes. Thus, an economic
index of waste flows is impossible to construct.
It is well-known that energy prices do not reflect
their full social cost due to a number of market
imperfections. This is particularly true for the
environmental impact caused by their extraction
and use. These problems lead some to doubt the
usefulness of price as the basis for any indicator of
sustainability. However, with or without externalities, prices should reflect productivities. Internalizing externalities will shift energy use, which in turn
will change marginal products.
Moreover, prices produce a ranking of fuels (Table I)
that is consistent with our intuition and with previous
empirical research. One can conclude that government policy, regulations, cartels, and externalities
explain some of the price differentials among fuels but
certainly not the substantial ranges that exist. More
fundamentally, price differentials are explained by
differences in attributes such as physical scarcity,
capacity to do useful work, energy density, cleanliness,
amenability to storage, safety, flexibility of use, and
cost of conversion. Eliminate the market imperfections and the price per Btu of different energies would
vary due to the different combinations of attributes
that determine their economic usefulness. The different prices per Btu indicate that users are interested in
attributes other than heat content.
Other scientists propose a system of aggregating
energy and materials based on exergy. Exergy
measures the useful work obtainable from an energy
source or material, and it is based on the chemical
energy embodied in the material or energy based on
its physical organization relative to a reference state.
Thus, exergy measures the degree to which a material
is organized relative a random assemblage of
material found at an average concentration in the
crust, ocean, or atmosphere. The higher the degree of
concentration, the higher the exergy content. The
physical units for exergy are the same as for energy
or heat, namely kilocalories, joules, Btus, etc. For
fossil fuels, exergy is nearly equivalent to the
standard heat of combustion; for other materials,
specific calculations are needed that depend on the
details of the assumed conversion process.
Proponents argue that exergy has a number of
useful attributes for aggregating heterogeneous energy and materials. Exergy is a property of all energy
and materials and in principle can be calculated from
information in handbooks of chemistry and physics
and secondary studies. Thus, exergy can be used to
measure and aggregate natural resource inputs as
well as wastes. For these reasons, Ayres argues that
exergy forms the basis for a comprehensive resource
accounting framework that could ‘‘provide policy
makers with a valuable set of indicators.’’ One such
indicator is a general measure of ‘‘technical efficiency,’’ the efficiency with which ‘‘raw’’ exergy from
animals or an inanimate source is converted into final
services. A low exergy efficiency implies potential for
efficiency gains for converting energy and materials
into goods and services. Similarly, the ratio of exergy
embodied in material wastes to exergy embodied in
resource inputs is the most general measure of
pollution. Some also argue that the exergy of waste
streams is a proxy for their potential ecotoxicity or
harm to the environment, at least in general terms.
From an accounting perspective, exergy is appealing because it is based on the science and laws of
thermodynamics and thus has a well-established
system of concepts, rules, and information that are
available widely. However, like enthalpy, exergy
should not be used to aggregate energy and material
inputs aggregation because it is one-dimensional.
Like enthalpy, exergy does not vary with, and hence
does not necessarily reflect, attributes of fuels that
determine their economic usefulness, such as energy
density, cleanliness, and cost of conversion. The same
is true for materials. Exergy cannot explain, for
3. ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO
ENERGY AGGREGATION
Although we argue that the more advanced economic
indexing methods, such as Divisia aggregation, are
the most appropriate way to aggregate energy use for
investigating its role in the economy, the ecological
economics literature proposes other methods of
aggregation. We review two of these methods in this
section and assess limits on their ability to aggregate
energy use.
22
Aggregation of Energy
example, impact resistance, heat resistance, corrosion resistance, stiffness, space maintenance, conductivity, strength, ductility, or other properties of
metals that determine their usefulness. Like prices,
exergy does not reflect all the environmental costs of
fuel use. The exergy of coal, for example, does not
reflect coal’s contribution to global warming or its
impact on human health relative to natural gas. The
exergy of wastes is at best a rough first-order
approximation of environmental impact because it
does not vary with the specific attributes of a waste
material and its receiving environment that cause
harm to organisms or that disrupt biogeochemical
cycles. In theory, exergy can be calculated for any
energy or material, but in practice the task of
assessing the hundreds (thousands?) of primary and
intermediate energy and material flows in an
economy is daunting.
3.2 Emergy
The ecologist Howard Odum analyzes energy and
materials with a system that traces their flows within
and between society and the environment. It is
important to differentiate between two aspects of
Odum’s contribution. The first is his development of
a biophysically based, systems-oriented model of the
relationship between society and the environment.
Here, Odum’s early contributions helped lay the
foundation for the biophysical analysis of energy and
material flows, an area of research that forms part of
the intellectual backbone of ecological economics.
The insight from this part of Odum’s work is
illustrated by the fact that ideas he emphasized—
energy and material flows, feedbacks, hierarchies,
thresholds, and time lags—are key concepts of the
analysis of sustainability in a variety of disciplines.
The second aspect of Odum’s work, which we are
concerned with here, is a specific empirical issue: the
identification, measurement, and aggregation of
energy and material inputs to the economy, and their
use in the construction of indicators of sustainability.
Odum measures, values, and aggregates energy of
different types by their transformities. Transformities
are calculated as the amount of one type of energy
required to produce a heat equivalent of another type
of energy. To account for the difference in quality of
thermal equivalents among different energies, all
energy costs are measured in solar emjoules, the
quantity of solar energy used to produce another
type of energy. Fuels and materials with higher
transformities require larger amounts of sunlight to
produce and therefore are considered more economically useful.
Several aspects of the emergy methodology reduce
its usefulness as a method for aggregating energy
and/or material flows. First, like enthalpy and exergy,
emergy is one-dimensional because energy sources
are evaluated based on the quantity of embodied
solar energy and crustal heat. However, is the
usefulness of a fuel as an input to production related
to its transformity? Probably not. Users value coal
based on it heat content, sulfur content, cost of
transportation, and other factors that form the
complex set of attributes that determine its usefulness relative to other fuels. It is difficult to imagine
how this set of attributes is in general related to,
much less determined by, the amount of solar energy
required to produce coal. Second, the emergy
methodology is inconsistent with its own basic
tenant, namely that quality varies with embodied
energy or emergy. Coal deposits that we currently
extract were laid down over many geological periods
that span half a billion years. Coals thus have vastly
different embodied emergy, but only a single
transformity for coal is normally used. Third, the
emergy methodology depends on plausible but
arbitrary choices of conversion technologies (e.g.,
boiler efficiencies) that assume users choose one fuel
relative to another and other fuels based principally
on their relative conversion efficiencies in a particular
application. Finally, the emergy methodology relies
on long series of calculations with data that vary in
quality. However, little attention is paid to the
sensitivity of the results to data quality and
uncertainty, leaving the reader with little or no sense
of the precision or reliability of the emergy calculations.
4. CASE STUDY 1: NET ENERGY
FROM FOSSIL FUEL EXTRACTION
IN THE UNITED STATES
One technique for evaluating the productivity of
energy systems is net energy analysis, which compares the quantity of energy delivered to society by
an energy system to the energy used directly and
indirectly in the delivery process. EROI is the ratio of
energy delivered to energy costs. There is a long
debate about the relative strengths and weaknesses of
net energy analysis. One restriction on net energy
analysis’ ability to deliver the insights it promises is
its treatment of energy quality. In most net energy
23
Aggregation of Energy
analyses, inputs and outputs of different types of
energy are aggregated by their thermal equivalents.
This case study illustrates how accounting for energy
quality affected calculations for the EROI of the U.S.
petroleum sector from 1954 to 1992.
30
4.1 Methods and Data
Following the definitions in Eq. (2), a qualitycorrected EROI* is defined by
Pn
o
i¼1 li;t Ei;t
EROIt ¼ Pn
ð6Þ
c ;
i¼1 li;t Ei;t
where li,t is the quality factor for fuel type i at time t
and Eo and Ec are the thermal equivalents of energy
outputs and energy inputs, respectively. We construct
Divisia indices for energy inputs and outputs to
account for energy quality in the numerator and
denominator. The prices for energy outputs (oil,
natural gas, and natural gas liquids) and energy
inputs (natural gas, gasoline, distillate fuels, coal,
and electricity) are the prices paid by industrial end
users for each energy type.
Energy inputs include only industrial energies: the
fossil fuel and electricity used directly and indirectly
to extract petroleum. The costs include only those
energies used to locate and extract oil and natural gas
and prepare them for shipment from the wellhead.
Transportation and refining costs are excluded from
this analysis. Output in the petroleum industry is the
sum of the marketed production of crude oil, natural
gas, and natural gas liquids.
The direct energy cost of petroleum is the fuel and
electricity used in oil and gas fields. Indirect energy
costs include the energy used to produce material
inputs and to produce and maintain the capital used
to extract petroleum. The indirect energy cost of
materials and capital is calculated from data for the
dollar cost of those inputs to petroleum extraction
processes. Energy cost of capital and materials is
defined as the dollar cost of capital depreciation and
materials multiplied by the energy intensity of capital
and materials (Btu/$). The energy intensity of capital
and materials is measured by the quantity of energy
used to produce a dollar’s worth of output in the
industrial sector of the U.S. economy. That quantity
is the ratio of fossil fuel and electricity use to real
GDP produced by industry.
4.2 Results and Conclusions
The thermal equivalent and Divisia EROI for
petroleum extraction show significant differences
EROI
20
10
Divisia
Thermal equivalent
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
FIGURE 2 Energy return on investment (EROI) for petroleum
extraction in the United States, with energy inputs and outputs
measured in heat equivalents and a Divisia index.
(Fig. 2). The quality-corrected EROI declines faster
than the thermal-equivalent EROI. The thermalequivalent EROI increased by 60% relative to the
Divisia EROI between 1954 and 1992. This difference was driven largely by changes in the mix of fuel
qualities in energy inputs. Electricity, the highest
quality fuel, is an energy input but not an energy
output. Its share of total energy use increased from 2
to 12% during the period; its cost share increased
from 20 to 30%. Thus, in absolute terms the
denominator in the Divisia EROI is weighted more
heavily than in the thermal-equivalent EROI. The
Divisia-weighted quantity of refined oil products is
larger than that for gas and coal. Thus, the two
highest quality fuels, electricity and refined oil
products, comprise a large and growing fraction of
the denominator in the Divisia EROI compared to
the thermal-equivalent EROI. Therefore, the Divisia
denominator increases faster than the heat-equivalent denominator, causing EROI to decline faster in
the former case.
5. CASE STUDY 2: CAUSALITY IN
THE ENERGY/GDP RELATIONSHIP
One of the most important questions about the
environment–economy relationship regards the
strength of the linkage between economic growth
and energy use. With a few exceptions, most analyses
ignore the effect of energy quality in the assessment
24
Aggregation of Energy
of this relationship. One statistical approach to
address this question is Granger causality and/or
cointegration analysis. Granger causality tests
whether (i) one variable in a relation can be
meaningfully described as a dependent variable and
the other variable as an independent variable, (ii) the
relation is bidirectional, or (iii) no meaningful
relation exists. This is usually done by testing
whether lagged values of one of the variables add
significant explanatory power to a model that
already includes lagged values of the dependent
variable and perhaps also lagged values of other
variables.
Although Granger causality can be applied to both
stationary and integrated time series (time series that
follow a random walk), cointegration applies only to
linear models of integrated time series. The irregular
trend in integrated series is known as a stochastic
trend, as opposed to a simple linear deterministic
time trend. Time series of GDP and energy use are
usually integrated. Cointegration analysis aims to
uncover causal relations among variables by determining if the stochastic trends in a group of variables
are shared by the series so that the total number of
unique trends is less than the number of variables. It
can also be used to test if there are residual stochastic
trends that are not shared by any other variables.
This may be an indication that important variables
have been omitted from the regression model or that
the variable with the residual trend does not have
long-term interactions with the other variables.
Either of these conclusions could be true should
there be no cointegration. The presence of cointegration can also be interpreted as the presence of a longterm equilibrium relationship between the variables
in question. The parameters of an estimated cointegrating relation are called the cointegrating vector.
In multivariate models, there may be more than one
such cointegrating vector.
vector autoregression model of GDP, energy use,
capital, and labor inputs. The study measures energy
use by its thermal equivalents and the Divisia
aggregation method discussed previously. The relation among GDP, the thermal equivalent of energy
use, and the Divisia energy use indicates that there is
less ‘‘decoupling’’ between GDP and energy use when
the aggregate measure for energy use accounts for
qualitative differences (Fig. 3). The multivariate
methodology is important because changes in energy
use are frequently countered by substitution with
labor and/or capital and thereby mitigate the effect of
changes in energy use on output. Weighting energy
use for changes in the composition of the energy
input is important because a large portion of the
growth effects of energy is due to substitution of
higher quality energy sources such as electricity for
lower quality energy sources such as coal (Fig. 1).
Bivariate tests of Granger causality show no
causal order in the relation between energy and
GDP in either direction, regardless of the measure
used to qualify energy use (Table III). In the
multivariate model with energy measured in primary
Btus, GDP was found to ‘‘Granger cause’’ energy use.
However, when both innovations—a multivariate
model and energy use adjusted for quality—are
employed, energy Granger causes GDP. These results
show that adjusting energy for quality is important,
as is considering the context within which energy use
is occurring. The conclusion that energy use plays an
important role in determining the level of economic
450
GDP
400
350
Primary Btus
Quality adjusted energy
300
250
5.1 Granger Causality and the Energy
GDP Relation
A series of analyses use statistical tests to evaluate
whether energy use or energy prices determine
economic growth, or whether the level of output in
the United States and other economics determine
energy use or energy prices. Generally, the results are
inconclusive. Where significant results are obtained,
they indicate causality from output to energy use.
One analysis tests U.S. data (1947–1990) for
Granger causality in a multivariate setting using a
200
150
100
50
0
1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
FIGURE 3 Energy use and GDP in the United States, with
energy use measured in heat equivalents and a Divisia index. From
Stern (1993).
Aggregation of Energy
25
TABLE III
Energy GDP Causality Tests for the United States, 1947–1990a
Bivariate model
Energy causes GDP
GDP causes Energy
Multivariate model
Primary Btus
Quality-adjusted
energy
0.8328
0.9657
0.5850
0.4428
0.4402
0.5628
0.3188E01
0.3421
0.7125
0.7154
0.5878
9.0908
0.7163E03
0.8458
0.5106
Primary Btus
Quality-adjusted
energy
3.1902
a
The test statistic is an F statistic. Significance levels in italics. A significant statistic indicates that there is Granger causality in the
direction indicated.
activity is consistent with results of price-based
studies of other energy economists.
6. CASE STUDY 3: THE
DETERMINANTS OF THE ENERGY/
GDP RELATIONSHIP
One of the most widely cited macroeconomic
indicators of sustainability is the ratio of total energy
use to total economic activity, or the energy/real GDP
ratio (E/GDP ratio). This ratio has declined since
1950 in many industrial nations. There is controversy regarding the interpretation of this decline.
Many economists and energy analysts argue that the
decline indicates that the relation between energy use
and economic activity is relatively weak. This
interpretation is disputed by many biophysical
economists, who argue that the decline in the E/
GDP ratio overstates the ability to decouple energy
use and economic activity because many analyses of
the E/GDP ratio ignore the effect of changes in
energy quality (Fig. 1).
The effect of changes in energy quality (and
changes in energy prices and types of goods and
services produced and consumed) on the E/GDP ratio
can be estimated using Eq. (7):
E
natural gas
oil
¼ a þ b1 ln
þ b2 ln
GDP
E
E
þ b3 ln
primary electricity
PCE
þ b4
E
GDP
þ b5 ðproduct mixÞ þ b6 ln ðpriceÞ þ e;
ð7Þ
where E is the total primary energy consumption
(measured in heat units); GDP is real GDP; primary
electricity is electricity generated from hydro, nuclear, solar, or geothermal sources; PCE is real personal
consumption expenditures spent directly on energy
by households; product mix measures the fraction of
GDP that originates in energy-intensive sectors (e.g.,
chemicals) or non-energy-intensive sectors (e.g.,
services); and price is a measure of real energy prices.
The effect of energy quality on the E/GDP ratio is
measured by the fraction of total energy consumption from individual fuels. The sign on the regression
coefficients b1–b3 is expected to be negative because
natural gas, oil, and primary electricity can do more
useful work (and therefore generate more economic
output) per heat unit than coal. The rate at which an
increase in the use of natural gas, oil, or primary
electricity reduces the E/GDP ratio is not constant.
Engineering studies indicate that the efficiency with
which energies of different types are converted to
useful work depends on their use. Petroleum can
provide more motive power per heat unit of coal, but
this advantage nearly disappears if petroleum is used
as a source of heat. From an economic perspective,
the law of diminishing returns implies that the first
uses of high-quality energies are directed at tasks that
are best able to make use of the physical, technical,
and economic aspects of an energy type that combine
to determine its high-quality status. As the use of a
high-quality energy source expands, it is used for
tasks that are less able to make use of the attributes
that confer high quality. The combination of physical
differences in the use of energy and the economic
ordering in which they are applied to these tasks
implies that the amount of economic activity
generated per heat unit diminishes as the use of a
high-quality energy expands. Diminishing returns on
energy quality is imposed on the model by specifying
the fraction of the energy budget from petroleum,
primary electricity, natural gas, or oil in natural
26
Aggregation of Energy
logarithms. This specification ensures that the first
uses of high-quality energies decrease the energy/
GDP ratio faster than the last uses.
The regression results indicate that Eq. (7) can be
used to account for most of the variation in the E/
GDP ratio for France, Germany, Japan, and the
United Kingdom during the post-World War II period
and in the United States since 1929. All the variables
have the sign expected by economic theory and are
statistically significant, and the error terms have the
properties assumed by the estimation technique.
Analysis of regression results indicate that changes
in energy mix can account for a significant portion of
the downward trend in E/GDP ratios. The change
from coal to petroleum and petroleum to primary
electricity is associated with a general decline
in the E/GDP ratio in France, Germany, the United
Kingdom, and the United States during the
post-World War II period (Fig. 4). The fraction of
total energy consumption supplied by petroleum
increased steadily for each nation through the
early 1970s. After the first oil shock, the fraction
of total energy use from petroleum remained steady
or declined slightly in these four nations. However,
energy mix continued to reduce the E/real GDP
ratio after the first oil shock because the fraction of
total energy use from primary electricity increased
steadily. The effect of changes in energy mix on the
E/GDP ratio shows no trend over time in Japan,
where the fraction of total energy consumption
supplied by primary electricity declined through the
early 1970s and increased steadily thereafter. This U
shape offsets the steady increase in the fraction of
total energy use from petroleum that occurred prior
to 1973.
These regression results indicate that the historical
reduction in the E/GDP ratio is associated with shifts
in the types of energies used and the types of goods
and services consumed and produced. Diminishing
returns to high-quality energies and the continued
consumption of goods from energy-intensive sectors
such as manufacturing imply that the ability of
changes in the composition of inputs and outputs to
reduce the E/real GDP ratio further is limited.
7. CONCLUSIONS AND
IMPLICATIONS
Application of the Divisia index to energy use in the
U.S. economy illustrates the importance of energy
quality in aggregate analysis. The quality-corrected
index for EROI indicates that the energy surplus
delivered by petroleum extraction in the United States
is smaller than indicated by unadjusted EROI. The
trend over time in a quality-adjusted index of total
primary energy use in the U.S. economy is significantly different, and declines faster, than the standard
heat-equivalent index. Analysis of Granger causality
and cointegration indicates a causal relationship
running from quality-adjusted energy to GDP but
not from the unadjusted energy index. The econometric analysis of the E/real GDP ratio indicates that
the decline in industrial economies has been driven in
part by the shift from coal to oil, gas, and primary
electricity. Together, these results suggest that accounting for energy quality reveals a relatively strong
relationship between energy use and economic output. This runs counter to much of the conventional
wisdom that technical improvements and structural
change have decoupled energy use from economic
performance. To a large degree, technical change and
substitution have increased the use of higher quality
energy and reduced the use of lower quality energy. In
economic terms, this means that technical change has
been ‘‘embodied’’ in the fuels and their associated
energy converters. These changes have increased
energy efficiency in energy extraction processes,
allowed an apparent decoupling between energy use
and economic output, and increased energy efficiency
in the production of output.
The manner in which these improvements have
been largely achieved should give pause for thought.
If decoupling is largely illusory, any increase in the
cost of producing high-quality energy vectors could
have important economic impacts. Such an increase
might occur if use of low-cost coal to generate
electricity is restricted on environmental grounds,
particularly climate change. If the substitution
process cannot continue, further reductions in the E/
GDP ratio would slow. Three factors might limit
future substitution to higher quality energy. First,
there are limits to the substitution process. Eventually, all energy used would be of the highest quality
variety—electricity—and no further substitution
could occur. Future discovery of a higher quality
energy source might mitigate this situation, but it
would be unwise to rely on the discovery of new
physical principles. Second, because different energy
sources are not perfect substitutes, the substitution
process could have economic limits that will prevent
full substitution. For example, it is difficult to imagine
an airliner running on electricity. Third, it is likely
that supplies of petroleum, which is of higher quality
than coal, will decline fairly early in the 21st century.
Aggregation of Energy
A
B
France
MTOE/million 1980 deutch marks
MTOE/million 1980 francs
0.08
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
1950
1970
1980
2.20e-4
2.00e-4
1.80e-4
1.60e-4
1955
1990
MTOE/million 1980 pound sterling
1.60e-3
1.40e-3
1.20e-3
1975
1985
United Kingdom
1.10e-3
1.80e-3
1965
1975
1965
D
Japan
2.00e-3
MTOE/billion 1980 yen
2.40e-4
1.40e-4
1960
C
1.00e-3
1955
Germany
2.60e-4
0.09
1.00e-3
9.00e-4
8.00e-4
7.00e-4
6.00e-4
5.00e-4
1950
1985
1960
1970
1980
United States
E
Thousand Kcal per 1972 dollar
25
20
15
10
5
0
1925
FIGURE 4
27
1935
1945
1955
1965
1975
1985
The results of a regression analysis (Eq. (7) that predicts the E/GDP ratio as a function of fuel mix and other
variables. , actual values; solid lines, values predicted from the regression equation; J, actual values for the United States.
From Kaufmann (1992) and Hall et al. (1986).
1990
28
Aggregation of Energy
Finally, our conclusions do not imply that onedimensional and/or physical indicators are universally inferior to the economic indexing approach we
endorse. As one reviewer noted, ecologists might
raise the problem of Leibig’s law of the minimum, in
which the growth or sustainability of a system are
constrained by the single critical element in least
supply. Exergy or mass are appropriate if the object
of analysis is a single energy or material flux. Physical
units are also necessary to valuate those flows.
Integrated assessment of a material cycle within
and between the environment and the economy is
logical based on physical stocks and flows. However,
when the question being asked requires the aggregation of energy flows in an economic system, an
economic approach such as Divisa aggregation or a
direct measure of marginal product embody a more
tenable set of assumptions than does aggregation by
one-dimensional approaches.
SEE ALSO THE
FOLLOWING ARTICLES
Economic Thought, History of Energy in Emergy
Analysis and Environmental Accounting Entropy
and the Economic Process Exergy Exergy Analysis
of Energy Systems Exergy: Reference States and
Balance Conditions Net Energy Analysis: Concepts
and Methods Thermodynamics and Economics,
Overview
Further Reading
Ayres, R., and Martiñas, K. (1995). Waste potential entropy: The
ultimate ecotoxic? Econ. Appliqueé 48, 95–120.
Berndt, E. (1990). Energy use, technical progress and productivity
growth: A survey of economic issues. J. Productivity Anal. 2,
67–83.
Cleveland, C. J. (1992). Energy quality and energy surplus in
the extraction of fossil fuels in the U.S. Ecol. Econ. 6,
139–162.
Cleveland, C. J., Costanza, R., Hall, C. A. S., and Kaufmann, R.
(1984). Energy and the U.S. economy: A biophysical perspective. Science 255, 890–897.
Cottrell, W. F. (1955). ‘‘Energy and Society.’’ McGraw-Hill, New
York.
Darwin, R. F. (1992). Natural resources and the Marshallian
effects of input-reducing technological changes. J. Environ.
Econ. Environ. Management 23, 201–215.
Gever, J., Kaufmann, R., Skole, D., and Vorosmarty, C. (1986).
‘‘Beyond Oil: The Threat to Food and Fuel in the Coming
Decades.’’ Ballinger, Cambridge, UK.
Hall, C. A. S., Cleveland, C. J., and Kaufmann, R. K. (1986).
‘‘Energy and Resource Quality: The Ecology of the Economic
Process.’’ Wiley Interscience, New York.
Hamilton, J. D. (1983). Oil and the macroeconomy since World
War II. J. Political Econ. 91, 228–248.
Kaufmann, R. K. (1992). A biophysical analysis of the energy/real
GDP ratio: Implications for substitution and technical change.
Ecol. Econ. 6, 35–56.
Odum, H. T. (1996). ‘‘Environmental Accounting.’’ Wiley, New
York.
Rosenberg, N. (1998). The role of electricity in industrial
development. Energy J. 19, 7–24.
Schurr, S., and Netschert, B. (1960). ‘‘Energy and the American
Economy, 1850–1975.’’ Johns Hopkins Univ. Press, Baltimore.
Stern, D. I. (1993). Energy use and economic growth in the USA: A
multivariate approach. Energy Econ. 15, 137–150.