EN
Cedefop
A comparative study
of five European countries
– France, Germany, Italy, Spain
and the United Kingdom –
with special reference
to the United States
EDEX
Educational Expansion
and Labour Market
A comparative study of five European countries
- France, Germany, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom with special reference to the United States
Catherine Béduwé
Jordi Planas
Cedefop Reference series; 39
Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2003
Table of contents
SUMMARY
PROJECT TEAMS
3
4
1. RESEARCH AIMS AND METHODOLOGY
1.1. Background
1.2. Research aims
1.3. Research method
1.3.1. Methodological decisions: the generation as the key starting point
1.3.2. A comparative and multidisciplinary approach
1.3.3. Conduct of the work
1.4. Research hypotheses
1.4.1. The nature and origin of the good exchanged in the labour market
1.4.2. Skills as the basis for exchange in the labour market
1.4.3. Skills as a vector of individual characteristics
1.4.4. Skills and job eligibility threshold
1.4.5. Skills jointly produced by the systems where they are acquired
1.4.6. Qualifications as a factor of skills production
5
5
8
11
11
12
14
14
15
15
16
17
18
18
2. PROCESS AND RESULTS OF THE RESEARCH
2.1. Production of qualifications and growth in skills:
A comparison of changes in European education systems
2.1.1. Comparing national processes leading to educational expansion
2.1.2. Factors influencing the expansion process and the rise
in levels of education
2.2. Impact of educational expansion on jobs, remuneration and social position
of more highly qualified generations: A comparative analysis
2.2.1. The analytical framework
2.2.2. The “supply-side effect”: A brief outline of the work of the
“Qualifications and Labour Markets” network
2.2.3. Remuneration for more education
2.2.4. Access to management positions by generation
2.2.5. Initial conclusions concerning the macro effects of educational expansion
2.3. Educational expansion, production demand and employers’ behaviour
2.3.1. Aims and method
2.3.2. Educational expansion and employers’ behaviour
2.3.3. The banking sector: Case study and international comparison
2.3.4. Demand for skills and output of persons with qualifications
2.3.5. Chapter conclusions
20
3. OUTLOOK FOR THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EDUCATION AND EMPLOYMENT
3.1. Stabilisation or a continuing rise in levels of education?
3.1.1. Study of the data: towards stabilisation of the rate
of entry to higher education
3.1.2. Elements of uncertainty: Education policies and young
people’s behaviour
20
21
39
48
48
51
59
68
73
76
76
80
87
99
108
112
112
113
117
3.2. Demand for skills
3.2.1. Towards an increased need for skills...
3.2.2. …which is more difficult to meet by recruiting young graduates
3.2.3. Tensions and skills output
3.3. Towards an increased role for continuing education?
4. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS
4.1. 40 years of educational expansion in the five project countries
4.2. Convergence and divergence between education systems
4.3. Irreversibility of educational expansion
4.3.1. Educational strategies
4.3.2. The symbolic role of education and qualifications
4.3.3. Qualifications as a signal in the labour market
4.3.4. Education and qualifications as an investment
4.4. From consensus on initial education to consensus on skills?
4.4.1. Outlook for the behaviour of the different players
4.4.2. Towards a greater role for continuing education in the production of skills
4.5. The identity of education systems and production of skills for the economy
4.5.1. Demand follows supply: Results of a macro-statistical approach
based on skills
4.5.2. The timescale of skills production
4.5.3. The needs of employers and the needs of the economy
4.5.4. Strengthening the identities of education systems in response
to the needs of the economy
5. BIBLIOGRAPHY
5.1. Research reports produced within the EDEX framework
5.1.1. National reports
5.1.2. International reports
5.2. General Bibliography
126
127
128
130
133
137
138
141
143
145
146
147
148
149
150
153
154
156
157
159
161
163
163
163
165
166
6. ANNEXES
1.1. Grid used to compare national qualifications nomenclatures
172
1.2. Qualifications structure of generations studied
173
1.3. Demography of European project countries
176
1.4. Graphs of the German, Spanish and French education systems
177
2.1. Four models
181
2.2. Two ways of reading the supply model
182
2.3. Cumulative table of international results for the supply-side effect
184
2.4. Data and variables used by the countries for salary analysis
185
2.5a. Table of results of earnings function model for education as a whole (DIP)
186
2.5b. Table of results of earnings function model for education broken down (DF and RDP) 186
2.6. Additional work done on the supply-side effect
187
3.1. France: Evolution of educational expansion
189
3.2. Spain: Qualifications structure of generations, population
aged 16-65 years. LFS 2000
190
3.3. Germany: Rate of upper secondary completion
190
3.4. Italy: Completion of upper secondary (Maturità) and university entrance
191
3.5. United Kingdom (England): Participation in full-time and part-time
post-compulsory education and training, 1979-1999
191
Summary
Between November 1998 and September 2001, LIRHE co-ordinated the
EDEX project (Educational Expansion and Labour Markets). This is a
European research project conducted under the 4th RDFP (TSER line) in
collaboration with British, German, Italian and Spanish teams, together with
a U.S. team for certain aspects. The aim was to analyse the long-term
consequences of the rise in levels of education on mechanisms of access to
employment and on human resources management.
The teams involved in the project were LIRHE in Toulouse, the Centre for
Economic Performance (CEP) of the London School of Economics, the
Zentrum für Sozialforschung Halle (ZSH), the Centro di Ricerche
Economiche e Sociali (CERES) in Rome, the Grup de Recerca Educació i
Treball (GRET) in Barcelona, and the Center for Research on Innovation and
Society, (C.R.I.S. International) in Santa Barbara.
This LIRHE document contains the final report of the project. It has been
compiled from national contributions from the teams and interim synthesis
reports produced during the research, all of which may be consulted at the
website: http://edex.univ-tlse1.fr/edex/
Four major questions were addressed in succession, taking a comparative
approach:
• In each of the countries, what are the processes leading to educational
expansion and the production of generations with increasing levels of
qualifications? Can the factors influencing these processes be identified?
• How – in macro-economic terms – have these generations with increasing
levels of qualifications spread throughout the employment system, and with
what returns in terms of salary and social position?
• What has been the impact of an increased supply of graduates on
company organisation and human resources management? How is it
viewed and used by companies? What links have been established
between qualifications (produced) and skills (demanded)?
• From the above results, is it possible to deduce implications for the future
evolution of national systems linking education with employment? To what
extent are countries converging or diverging?
CHAPTER 4
Conclusions and policy
recommendations
The rise in the level of education among British, French, German, Italian and
Spanish populations is a continual process which forms part of the economic
and social history of these developed countries. A phenomenon of the period
since the end of the War, it has resulted from the converging strategies of the
State, families and employers, all of whom – albeit for reasons that may have
been completely opposite – have pushed for educational expansion.
Of these three protagonists, the State played the key role: they were the
main source of funds for educational expansion, and drew up the relevant
legal framework. Families have sometimes provided more support for
expansion than governments expected, even in times when qualified people
find it difficult to get a first job.
Though they have not explicitly played a major part in the expansion of
education, employers have always had a stake in vocational education and
training, and have supported this expansion if only by taking qualifications
into account in recruiting staff. The State has also played a crucial role in its
function of entrepreneur, by making level of qualifications a core criterion for
appointments in the public sector and soaking up large numbers of new
graduates (especially in health and education provision).
The strategies of each of the players have obviously influenced those of
the others: governments have tried to interpret the needs of employers and
to incorporate these into the expansion of education systems, particularly
vocational education. Families have also picked up the signals coming from
employers and have taken these into account in their educational behaviour.
Employers, while participating globally in the process of educational
expansion by expecting particular specialist skills, have been essentially
concerned with non-formal and formal continuing education and training, the
manner, amount and cost of which depend on the characteristics of the
labour supply, i.e., on decisions taken earlier by governments and families.
In EDEX, the link between developments in education and the needs of the
economy rests on the notion of skills. An individual’s skills have been defined
as the knowledge and abilities acquired, which the individual may modify at
any time of life and in a variety of places, the chief ones being of course
school and work. The higher an individual’s initial education, the more
138
Educational expansion and labour market
quickly, effectively and efficiently he or she will learn. Employers buy these
individual skills and develop them, implicitly through the work experience that
they allow individuals to acquire, and explicitly by providing continuing
education and training. Although this development of skills within a company
depends on the ability to learn of each employee, it serves the company’s
particular aims of adapting resources. These hypotheses have proved both
extremely useful and generally valid in the course of this work.
Analysing the consequences of the rise in levels of education via the
increase in individual and collective skills in the labour market enabled us to
move on from the classic question of the link between qualifications and
employment to a more coherent way of looking at the interactions between
developments in education and the economy. Both the education system and
the employment system need to transform themselves; but although they are
relatively autonomous, in the sense that they obey forces that are peculiar to
them, their interests coincide in that the one produces and the other uses –
and together they jointly produce – socially and economically relevant skills.
And while they safeguard their own interests, they also develop their
relationship (their joint production) in order to protect themselves as best they
can against the unpredictability of long-term changes in work.
From the results of this research (1), we have selected some basic ideas
which have policy implications: on the convergence of education systems (2),
on the irreversible aspects of educational expansion (3), on the shift in
consensus (4) and on the place of education systems in the production of
skills (5).
4.1.
40 years of educational expansion in the five
project countries
The EDEX project set out to identify the educational changes that had led to
a huge expansion in education in five European countries. The educational
careers and behaviour of the generations born between 1940 and 1980 were
analysed, compared and contrasted with the education policies which
governments had been pursuing. We also took into account the role of
companies in the expansion of formal and non-formal vocational education
and training. Lastly, the question whether these trends would continue was
examined and discussed country by country. The conclusions of this work
may be summed up in the following points:
• All the countries considered experienced a significant rise in levels of
education in the generations born between 1940 and 1980. In the majority
Conclusions and policy recommendations
•
•
•
•
of the countries, this rise accelerated among the 1970s generations, and
then apparently slowed among the generations of the early 1980s.
In all five countries, the expansion in education essentially affected the
initial education of each generation within the education system. This
result, which needs to be qualified according to country, shows up the (as
yet) secondary role of continuing education (lifelong learning) in building
the qualifications structure of the population that is currently of working
age. The initial education, which each generation receives in youth, leaves
a lasting trace.
The process by which each generation acquires qualifications has become
longer as education has expanded but generally stops before the age of 30
years. This period of life comprises both initial education before entry into
active life, vocational training via apprenticeships, and various
combinations of periods of work and study. The distinction between the
education phase and the work phase is becoming less and less clear, even
in countries with ‘school-based only’ models such as France and Spain.
For a growing number of individuals, the ten or twelve years following the
end of compulsory education are a time of searching for an identity and
position in society through education and work. However, the order in
which this occurs is not immutable: there is considerable overlap between
the two and a wide variety of combinations.
The changes occurring in national education systems agree in two
essential respects: a considerable fall in the number with “no qualifications”
(although this category has not disappeared) and a rise in the percentage
of each generation obtaining qualifications granting them entry to university
at the end of secondary education. In each country, therefore, there is an
appreciable increase in the average level of education of the labour supply
as these generations with more education and more qualifications enter
active life and “spread” throughout employment. This should not mask the
fact that there is a considerable proportion with “no qualifications” in each
country, even among recent generations. This sends a particularly negative
signal in times of educational expansion and may lead to exclusion from
the labour market.
The similar developments taking place have far from eradicated all
structural differences between countries. In 40 years we have moved from
a situation of wide gaps between the proportions with no qualifications
(ranging from 33% to 89%) and small gaps between the proportions with
higher education qualifications (fewer than 16%) to a completely opposite
situation: a drawing together of the proportions with no qualifications (fewer
than 15%) and growing gaps between the proportions with higher
139
140
Educational expansion and labour market
•
•
•
•
•
•
qualifications (ranging from 7% to 37%). Thus, the countries where
education was poorly developed have caught up. More precisely, this result
means that the various countries have, while expanding education,
retained or even strengthened their individuality in their educational
decisions. The factors that have led to the international phenomenon of
educational expansion take forms peculiar to each country.
These strong initial differences between levels of formal education and
training, i.e., education and training attested by qualifications, among
generations born in the years 1930-1940, are matched by equally strong
differences in economic development. Such economic and educational
gaps have now been reduced, although it is not possible to identify any
simple causal link within the framework of this study.
In all five countries, the main force driving educational expansion is the
notion of equity. But the idea of “meritocracy”, which generally guides the
implementation of equality of opportunity in the school system, does not
entirely solve the problem. Maintaining equality of opportunity for longer
has led European education systems above all to postpone the first true
differentiation within each generation until after the end of compulsory
education – except in Germany, which retains its hierarchy of three types
of school.
In all five countries, educational expansion is the joint product of a) longer
compulsory education, which, in effect, is creeping closer to entry into higher
education, and b) an increase in post-compulsory study. The average level
of education among recent generations has moved from secondary towards
university and/or vocational higher education, and this has profoundly
affected the nature of vocational education. The institutional emphasis of
education has shifted towards higher education in all countries studied.
The educational system is an increasingly important variable in young
people’s careers (education, work, transition to adult life, socialisation and
first employment).
After more or less continual growth over nearly 30 years, educational
expansion speeded up radically in all the countries examined – except
Germany – among generations born in 1970 and later.
The outlook:
The most likely hypothesis for the future, in the light of the behaviour of the
generations currently undergoing initial education (the generations of
1980 and beyond) appears to be stabilisation of educational expansion in
the next ten years. This already seems to be a reality in France and the
United Kingdom, a new development in Spain, and a possibility in
Germany and Italy.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
• With the exception of the United Kingdom, existing institutional
arrangements do not show much room for manoeuvre in order to
encourage study beyond the end of compulsory education.
• Study after the end of secondary education (e.g., baccalauréat) appears to
be a crucial factor in stabilising or raising levels of education. It depends
heavily on national policies for the development or diversification of higher
education.
4.2.
Convergence and divergence between
education systems
The results of EDEX show the way in which the countries have managed
educational expansion, which may be summarised in terms of convergence
and divergence. But has there been a convergence between education
systems themselves? As systems evolve, are they drawing closer together,
structurally speaking?
The national peculiarities of education systems have much to do with the
extent to which vocational education is integrated into a unified system under
State supervision. Germany gives vocational education a central place in its
“dual” system managed jointly by the social partners; the United Kingdom
has no unified system of vocational education after compulsory education;
and France, Spain and Italy have integrated initial vocational education into
a unified system under State supervision, though responsibility may be
shared between various levels of government, especially in the regions.
The rise in levels of education is certainly a key feature of the last quarter
of the 20th century which is common to different European societies. The
factors influencing it cannot be confined solely to the actions of the State or
of individuals, or to the needs of the economy. The rise in levels of education
is one of the essential components of the overall transformation of Western
societies. This transformation is quite obviously common to the various
European countries.
It is nonetheless worth noting that the rise in levels of education has taken
place simultaneously in countries whose education systems are very different
for historical, cultural and economic reasons. Yet these differences have not
hindered the general growth in education. Education systems remain very
different and have retained their particular national forms of coherence. They
have handled educational expansion in their own particular ways.
Education systems have nonetheless been through considerable internal
and structural change. The more centralised have tried to become more
141
142
Educational expansion and labour market
flexible, and the more decentralised have set out to introduce national
standards or more exact common rules. Each country has found examples or
ideas in other countries’ systems that have helped to bring about change.
There is also a certain permeability between education and training systems.
But this is far from enough for us to reach the conclusion that systems are
converging.
For one thing, the changes are responses to socio-economic tensions and
developments, which are fundamentally similar in the different countries.
Unemployment, changes in the labour market and labour organisations,
rising standards of living and even growth in the demand for education, have
pushed every education system to adapt. The causes of change are thus
largely similar, and each system has aimed at greater professionalisation,
adaptability to changes in employment, less rigid educational tracks and a
wider range of courses. The objectives are relatively similar, especially in
higher education, where the issues of professionalisation and diversification
of courses are currently key topics. However, the responses to these needs
for change have differed in the past, and still differ today from country to
country. It would not be accurate to speak of a standardisation of education
systems.
The fact that all countries can produce a more or less equivalent level of
skills to meet similar economic needs by means of quite different education
systems is part and parcel of the very concept of skills. Their vectoral nature
and their joint production by systems and other places, ranging from schools
to companies and including social life, are transnational, but the way in which
these different elements fit together is peculiar to the society of each country.
Let us simply take one example: it is quite common for pupils and students
in initial education to work while at school or college in France
(Béduwé, Giret, 2001) and Spain (Planas 1990). In some cases at least, this
may amount to a sort of spontaneous version of the highly formalised
German dual system of vocational education. Both may turn out relatively
similar skills on the basis of school learning, work experience, etc., that are
peculiar to each education system (with its own rules, permits, etc.), of
employers’ behaviour towards young people and of labour market conditions
(regulations) specific to each country.
Where it proves necessary or merely beneficial, such behaviour tends to
become institutionalised. But its institutional form remains closely related to
the society in which it is produced. For instance, secondary and higher
education in France and Spain increasingly frequently include work
placements in companies as part of vocational education courses, even
though such placements are far from constituting a true dual system. It is well
Conclusions and policy recommendations
known that the societal framework of the German dual system has
implications that go well beyond the mere education system. This makes it
difficult to export to countries lacking these strong traditions and rules
governing the labour market.
Clearly, the continued presence of important structural differences
between countries is no obstacle to educational expansion; in fact,
comparing and contrasting the different systems is of benefit to all parties.
Certain difficulties arise, however, in making a comparative analysis of the
rise in levels of education and the cross-fertilisation between education
systems.
In the first place, little is known about the effectiveness of the systems and
their contributions to the economic and social development of each country.
It is probable there have been some changes in this area over the last 25
years. There is no point in examining responses to economic and social
change unless they can be related to each system as a coherent whole, and
unless there is some way to assess their relative effectiveness.
Secondly, it is still difficult for one person to understand another’s
education system and the significance of the rise in levels of education since
there are great differences and knowledge of that system as a whole is
required. The best solution is probably not to aim at convergence or
standardisation of systems but gradually to build up some common points of
reference, particularly for similar levels of education.
4.3.
Irreversibility of educational expansion
The results of EDEX (cf. Section 4.1) show that educational expansion,
having gone on for a long time, recently speeded up dramatically, after which
it would appear that there has been a stabilisation, in at least four of the five
countries. Is the huge and continuous expansion in education, except in
Germany, at a turning point in its history? It is still very difficult to answer this
question, but it is obvious that it could have very significant consequences.
The “stabilisation” currently observed may perhaps amount, as has
already been seen (Chauvel, 1998, Vignoles, Steedman, 2000), to a
consolidation, following the rapid acceleration among the generations of the
1970s which will precede a renewed period of expansion. The conditions for
an upturn have been described (Chapter 3): renewed expansion depends on
the removal of a number of institutional barriers within education systems,
and on young people’s demand for education, which now appears more
sensitive to economic fluctuations than in the past. This would mean that we
143
144
Educational expansion and labour market
do actually face a consolidation of the preceding period, which saw the 1970s
generations advance dramatically: having made significant progress, the
system would then maintain its level while it digested this advance.
But is a reverse trend conceivable? The power of the behavioural factors
that led to the expansion of education, and the strong potential resistance to
a decline, suggest that the expansion of education will stabilise (at least), will
definitely last and cannot be reversed.
Educational expansion is a cumulative process which, in turn, profoundly
influences family behaviour, decision-makers’ strategies for the organisation
of general and vocational education systems, and employers’ attitudes
towards qualifications. The upward shift in the minimum threshold of
qualifications allowing access to employment and social status has a knockon effect on the behaviour of the players, who regard it as a fait accompli. The
fact that over half of each generation enter upper secondary or higher
education has thus acquired a symbolic value for the generations that have
contributed to it, and has come to form part of families’ histories and fixed
beliefs.
The role of qualifications as a social and economic signal also means that
the development would be difficult to reverse. According to the “Investment in
Education” model (Hartog, 2000, p. 9), only drastic action by the State (more
obstacles and less funding) and a heavy fall in returns to investment, could
lead to a return to the past, at least in the absence of severe shortages of
labour.
At this point, mention should be made of a significant consideration: the
results of EDEX over a long period show low sensitivity to economic
conditions and cycles in the output of persons with qualifications. This output
has been rising since the War without any obvious breaks, either during the
period of strong growth (“the 30 glorious years”) or during employment crises
(the oil crises of 1974 et 1989). That said, observations about acceleration
and stabilisation of educational expansion relate to a period characterised by
abundance of labour rather than shortages. The low opportunity cost of postcompulsory education (Chapter 2) has encouraged further study. The period
to come, however, will see the retirement of the large post-war generations.
This may create quite significant job opportunities, to which young people will
perhaps respond.
Subject to this reservation, four points suggest that educational expansion
has a knock-on effect.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
4.3.1. Educational strategies
The lengthening of the period spent in education has been supported by a
wide consensus of all those involved in each European country. Everyone
was in favour, although it was the State and families that were the main
players. What has become of this consensus?
The State, the principal funder and organiser of educational expansion,
does not seem inclined to reduce its commitment in any country despite the
increasingly rapid pace of educational expansion in the recent past. In the
United Kingdom, for example, “institutions at all levels are undergoing great
political changes because of the Government’s desire to raise the level of
education of pupils and students. The aim is also to increase student
participation at all levels, especially in the field of technology and at
intermediate level” (Steedman, 2000). This is in fact the only country of the
five which appears to have significant room to give levels of education
another boost in the near future.
Even if qualifications were to become less cost-effective (which is not
proven), young people would still find it helpful to obtain the highest possible
level of qualifications in order to occupy the most favourable position in the
market. Young people might, however, reason that they should take
advantage of earlier opportunities to move into the labour market. Although
this has actually occurred in some countries when there has been an upturn
in the economy or in sectors where there is a shortage of skills (computing,
for example), it is possible that these young people will seek to have their
knowledge validated later in one way or another. The greater flexibility in
educational demand found in some countries can be interpreted in this way.
It is obvious nonetheless that the policy of diversifying higher education
courses will crucially influence the decisions of young people who hesitate to
commit themselves to long courses. This clearly seems easier to achieve in
unified systems (Chapter 3, 3.1.2.1.2). In the case of the United Kingdom, the
cost/benefit advantages need to be sufficiently attractive to pupils and
students: firstly, the new courses introduced (the equivalent of baccalauréat
+ 2 years’ apprenticeship) must lead to high-quality qualifications that are
recognised by employers and the labour market, and secondly, the
apportionment of costs between the State, employers and students must be
resolved in a manner that is satisfactory for all. In general terms, however, it
does not look as though we are moving towards clear changes in young
people’s behaviour.
As for employers, their skills requirements are complex. On the one hand,
they have to cope with an economic environment that is increasingly subject
to forces of change (internationalisation of markets, advances in technology,
145
146
Educational expansion and labour market
new models of company organisation) bringing about a greater need for skills
and therefore higher qualifications. On the other hand, they also need to find
staff for low-skilled jobs (cf. the banking sector, Chapter 2), the supply of
whom is becoming smaller because of rising levels of education. There are
tensions in this area, particularly in Germany where they have been brought
into the open, but no doubt also in other countries. There are cases, for
example, where companies have been unable to recruit and pay salaries at
the intended level, and even of their shifting employment to somewhere
where labour is less well educated and cheaper. This pressure exists, but
ultimately appears to be minor in such a wide accountancy exercise as this.
Now that the study has ended, no reason has emerged with sufficient force
to call into question the notion of the educational consensus. The common
strategy continues to be educational expansion, even though changes may
be made to the way in which this is organised (cf. the following concluding
point). But the interests of the three main players will not change so much
that educational expansion goes into reverse.
4.3.2. The symbolic role of education and qualifications
The irreversibility of a certain level of investment in education is also affected
by its symbolic role. This reflects the many different functions of education in
the social system, which go beyond the mere search for purely economic
benefits. We need to move away from too reductionist an approach to the
education system, and must not restrict its role to responding to the demands
for skills expressed by production. The relative independence of educational
demand from the needs expressed by employers strengthens this argument.
The value of qualifications is greater than the productive value accorded
them by the market. This value, and the demand for academic education
associated with it, is governed by the role of qualifications in overall social
and occupational relationships. The growth in educational demand is not
solely linked to employment prospects, anticipated productivity and the
returns expected by each individual. Nearly 20 years on, we see that Carnoy
(1982) was right: “even in an economy that shows itself incapable of
absorbing larger numbers of graduates and obliges some of them to accept
jobs previously occupied by less educated people, the factors causing
educational expansion will continue to apply.”
P. and A. D’Iribarne (1993, 1999, p. 28) also point to the significance of the
symbolic role of education in France: “It is impossible to grasp the relationship
between the education system and the production system in France if one
overlooks the symbolic aspect of education. And this means above all
appreciating the role played in France today by the contrast between what is
Conclusions and policy recommendations
more, and what is less “noble”…. In contemporary French society, it is
essentially a person’s “academic noblesse ”, governed by their educational
career, that will determine their personal noblesse for the rest of their life.”
What is true of France applies equally, in various ways, to all the countries
of “old Europe”, each of which divides up and distributes its “noblesses” on
the basis of education. However, as Shavit and Muller suggest (1998, pp. 1920), in all countries, access to higher social positions is heavily influenced by
the level of qualifications achieved.
The relationship between education and jobs, and the match between
level of education and level of employment, are part of a broader issue that
includes social signals. The education system produces both skills and a
social hierarchy (in the case of the various élites, it does so through courses
with very wide occupational goals – D’Iribarne A., D’Iribarne P., 1993).
4.3.3. Qualifications as a signal in the labour market
Given the lack of complete information about the labour market, the “signal”
theory (Spence, 1973) and its more radical version, the “filter” theory
(Arrow, 1973), have always been regarded as relevant factors in the
interpretation and distribution of qualifications in the labour market (see
Chapter 1). In this context, qualifications play a key role in signalling the skills
that are asked for by employers (Chapter 2).
These theories, particularly the filter theory, also have their limitations: they
do not necessarily imply optimum use of the knowledge associated with
qualifications. Nor do they rule out the possibility of “wastage” in the matching
of qualified persons with jobs. This “wastage” may be temporary, as
companies may in fact be stockpiling adaptation abilities that they will need
in order to evolve.
With the increase in the number of people with qualifications, there is also
the danger that the value of qualifications as a signal will become weaker and
decline (Gamel, 2000, pp. 71-74). But even if we make such an assumption
adapting to the decline will not automatically lead to a slowing of the
qualifications race among young people and their families. Rather, there will
be “longer periods spent in study and a quest for higher or more selective
qualifications” (although another form of behaviour, which is more difficult to
measure, deliberately aims at a first job that is more modest in relation to the
qualifications obtained). In other words, if qualifications provide a weaker
signal, some people will go along with this trend and lower their expectations,
while others will look for a stronger signal in order to keep them up.
The role of qualifications and hierarchies should not be forgotten in the
creation of standard levels in the labour market. Although their effects differ
147
148
Educational expansion and labour market
according to the structure of the education system, “The nature of the links
established between education and employment, and particularly their
normative quality…have become a key reference point in the decisions made
by those involved in the labour market” (Germe, Planas, 2000, p. 4).
Qualifications gained at the end of long courses, for example, are judged by
their capacity to ease access to a given level of job for which they are
assumed to offer some preparation. This is neither a rule, nor a description
of what actually happens, nor yet a mere response to the market, but a
socially constructed point of reference that guides those managing the
system, those in search of a qualification, and those who are recruiting or
looking for a job.
These more or less explicit standards allow young people and their
families to arrive at occupational expectations and make their educational
decisions. They have a push and pull effect on these expectations, although
the gap between symbolic perception and reality cannot be too wide. Given
current perceptions, it is hard to imagine a reversal of the trend.
4.3.4. Education and qualifications as an investment
Another argument that should not be forgotten, which supports the
irreversibility of educational expansion, is that though qualifications are less
and less a sufficient condition for access to middle-level and higher positions
in the jobs hierarchy, they are nonetheless increasingly a necessary condition
(and a factor in protection against unemployment).
The positive results eventually found in respect of remuneration
(Chapter 2) are in full agreement with the Human Capital Theory approach
(Becker, 1964), which argues that individuals are inclined to sacrifice
resources and satisfaction in the present in exchange for compensatory
satisfaction and resources in the future. They regard education as an
investment and reason that they can expect to profit from it. The future is thus
a dynamic extension of the present: investment has not yet been affected by
any potential weakening of the signal.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
4.4.
From consensus on initial education
to consensus on skills?
Let us return to the question of the consensus on education: young people
and their families, the State and employers have all had an interest in the
expansion of education, although their reasons may have been different, and
even contradictory. Educational expansion has thus occurred in a largely
consensual context. It has taken the form, at least implicitly, of an expansion
of initial education and an increased output of people with qualifications. In
the preceding section we argued that the bases of this consensus were
sufficiently firm to prevent a reversal of educational expansion. None of those
involved – in the current state of the market – would benefit sufficiently to
want to cause a breach in the consensus.
However, educational expansion seems to have come to a pause in most
of the countries studied. The reasons for this phenomenon are not clear. The
idea of a maximum threshold suggests itself, as the bulk of each generation
is now educated beyond compulsory education. Solving the matter of young
people with “no skills” or “no qualifications” has more to do with educational
behaviour than with “level of education”. Here also, while the situation in the
different countries appears to be more and more similar, there are subtle
distinctions. It is not the primary focus here, although this dimension must be
borne in mind in speaking of the future of educational expansion and the
educational consensus.
Skills requirements are still rising. Until now, they have largely been
satisfied by a mixture of expanding initial education and/or the acquisition of
work experience during active life. If the output of people with qualifications
from initial education declined, it could no longer provide all the skills on its
own that are needed throughout the market. Its role in the production of skills
would cease to be paramount and would have to be compensated –
assuming a constant need for qualifications – by certificated continuing
education and training. The phenomenon would be even more marked if an
increased need for skills were to make itself felt.
From the likely future behaviour of the three protagonists, it can be shown
that a scenario in which continuing education and training take on more and
more importance in the production of skills is plausible. The consensus would
then move to the maintenance and expansion of skills in lieu of increased
output of skills by initial education.
149
150
Educational expansion and labour market
4.4.1. Outlook for the behaviour of the different players
What indicators are available to provide information on the future behaviour
of the players towards education and training, and their new strategies to
cope with the changed context created by the “stabilisation” of levels of
education?
Young people and their families
As was reiterated in point 4.1.:
• In the recent past, the 1970s generations were the turning point in the
development of educational expansion, and the 1980s generations have
today reached another turning point. Of the young people in the five
countries born in the 1980s, over 50% should eventually have an upper
secondary (baccalauréat level) qualification. According to this criterion,
they have attained the highest level of education ever found.
• Furthermore, except in the UK where there still seems to be some room for
manoeuvre, it would appear that the rise in levels of education has reached
an upper limit and that the proportion of upper secondary qualifications will,
in the near future, only vary slightly. A return to below 50% of a generation
at that level appears equally unlikely.
• These generations at the pinnacle of educational expansion are, except in
Germany, less numerous than preceding generations (France, UK) or even
falling appreciably in size (Italy, Spain). Assuming an equal demand for
labour, they should find it easier to get a first job of higher quality. These
fortunate employment circumstances may even improve given the
opportunities created by the retirement of the numerically large post-war
generations and/or a continuing economic upturn. But a favourable
employment situation may a priori have a negative effect on continued
study (Section 3.1.2.2.1.): on the one hand, it may increase the opportunity
cost of continuing to study and reduce the tendency to seek shelter within
the education system, but on the other, it may increase the returns to study
and therefore encourage take-up of long courses.
One hypothesis put forward to accommodate these contradictory effects
(Chapter 3) is that the behaviour of the new generations will be more variable
and flexible in terms of educational demand, tracking economic conditions
more closely. This is a powerful hypothesis which, from a study of the
situation in these countries, appears to be holding up. The risk inherent in
leaving education and entering the labour market early, which may be
justified by favourable economic conditions, would be compensated by the
possibility of returning to study, including certificated education and training,
during active life.
4.4.1.1.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
This would be made easier by the high level of education achieved by the
young people in question: it is established that the more initial education an
individual has acquired, the more he or she will demand continuing
vocational education and the more he or she will be able to make effective
use of it. What is true of the new generations will also apply to the whole of
the active population, which will, by a demographic process, become more
and more highly qualified.
This “new” behaviour could lead, if it were confirmed, to new links between
initial and continuing education, between continuing study and return to
study. If such behaviour spread, tensions would doubtless emerge owing to
the rigidity and inflexibility of the education system. More broadly, the rise in
the population’s levels of initial education would threaten the balance
between the roles of initial and continuing education in the building of skills.
Employers
According to the information collected on employers’ possible attitudes
towards qualifications in the near future (Chapter 3):
• Employers’ behaviour will depend essentially on two factors: first, the
“forces driving economic change”; second, changes in the supply of
persons with qualifications leaving the education system.
• The forces driving economic change (Chapter 2) are unlikely in the near
future to cease or let up the pressure they place on companies. In
consequence, employers’ demand for skills should continue to rise.
• Employers will need to recruit both more skills and skills suited to changing
and largely unforeseeable needs.
Employers express their needs in terms of skills. These increased needs
have in the recent past often been met by young persons with qualifications
from initial education. The question is to what extent the output of persons
with qualifications by the education system will continue to supply the skills
needed by employers if the latter continue to place the emphasis on
recruiting young graduates.
A person’s set of skills can be acquired in different places and by different
means, in a wide range of combinations. The sources of skills are school and
higher education, working and social life, and continuing education and
training. What will be the most relevant (effective and efficient) combination
for the acquisition of the skills needed by employers in the future?
Given national demographic trends and the likely hypothesis of
stabilisation of educational expansion, it is inconceivable that the huge output
of young people with qualifications entering the labour market in the 1990s
will continue in the second half of this decade. It is difficult to imagine that the
4.4.1.2.
151
152
Educational expansion and labour market
relatively abundant supply of young qualified labour, of which employers have
been able to take advantage over the last ten years, will continue.
On the other hand, the decline in the output of qualified persons entering
the labour market will not prevent a continued rise in the level of qualifications
of the active population as a whole: even though it will be smaller, the flow of
qualified entrants will more than replace those who retire.
The labour supply will therefore move in two directions: a) a probable
decline in the flow of entrants to the labour market with qualifications, and b)
a sustained rise in the level of qualifications of the labour force.
Countries will thus have at their disposal active populations that have been
educated for longer and longer, have more qualifications and, above all, are
more easily to educate further through continuing education and training.
While tensions in the labour market will arise in certain occupations as a
result of the slower rise in the level of education of the population of working
age, it may be assumed that companies will more readily encourage their
staff to return to study through continuing education and training.
The State
Until now, governments have not slackened in their commitment to education
despite some evidence here and there of educational Malthusianism. Not the
least of the challenges that they will nevertheless face in the future is how to
implement lifelong education in practice. From the statements made by
governments, European supranational bodies and educational institutions,
especially in higher education, it is evident that this issue may result in a
reorganisation of education and training systems. But to achieve this we have
is little budgetary room for manoeuvre.
Educational institutions as a whole, despite appreciable differences
between countries, are more sensitive today to the demands of their clients.
They are in fact looking for new clients. In order to maintain, and if possible
to widen their base, they are prepared to be more flexible in both course
provision and routes of entry. These changes, already the norm in continuing
education, are also beginning to affect initial education. They are a reaction
to the new needs and behaviours detected among employers and young
people, and are being developed as part of policies aimed at expanding
educational provision without appreciably increasing budgets. Governments
believe that the initial education system must become more flexible and open
to new sections of the population without any substantial change in the
overall costs of education.
4.4.1.3.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
Towards a greater role for continuing education in the
production of skills
This look at some aspects of the likely future behaviour of the various players
engaged in education suggests that the consensus on educational expansion
will continue, but on a new footing that is modified to take account of current
circumstances and the behaviour and interests of all those involved.
Assuming that the role of qualifications remains constant, satisfying
employers’ needs will mean a shift in skills provision to sources other than
certificated initial education, even though this will continue to play a key part
in the renewal of the active population.
From the quantitative point of view we have seen that the supply of
persons with qualifications is likely to be more limited than in the past unless
there are significant social and institutional changes or a shift in young
people’s behaviour. These changes are not improbable, but they presuppose
“…profound changes in education systems so that these make education
available at more flexible times. This is not inconceivable. Here and there,
such options are making their appearance. Changes in behaviour in choice
of subject and pattern of study are actually to be seen in some countries.
Different routes of entry to higher education are developing in certain
countries” (Frey, Germe, Ghignoni, 2001).
At all events, this new behaviour by young people, adults and employers
should lead them to demand far more continuing education. This may be
encouraged by the high level of education among recently recruited staff,
which may reduce the costs of training and adaptation. Employers will need
to manage the tensions created by the intra-company competition between
the generations: “...if the pressure of competition (in the banking sector)
increases and methods of regulating internal markets are not modified
(recognition of skills and training effort, and career progression), these
characteristics are likely to create serious tensions” (Bruniaux, 2001, p. 26).
These possible changes therefore contain the seeds of a skills production
scenario in which certificated courses provided by continuing or lifelong
education complements and partly replaces the certificated courses provided
by initial education systems. This would take the form of:
(a) greater flexibility in young people’s demand for education, linked
particularly to the immediate economic situation,
(b) the possibility that some form of work might become more common
during initial education (especially in systems giving greater weight to
academic education), allowing more young people, particularly of student
age, to study while working,
4.4.2.
153
154
Educational expansion and labour market
(c) new opportunities for young people to decide between continued initial
education and return to study after a first period spent working, which
might call into question the “30 years of age” frontier (Section 3.1.).
(d) an increasingly important role for continuing education and training
(some of it leading to certification) among the employed, leading to a
wider distribution of formal qualifications and to a closer adaptation of the
skills acquired during initial education to employers’ needs.
Once again, such a scenario is very hypothetical. “It would probably
require very profound long-term changes in employment, the labour market
and education and training systems” (Germe, 2001).
This scenario would nonetheless suit all those involved for the following
reasons:
Young people would be able to adjust their new pattern of educational
“consumption”, using continuing education to maintain and even increase their
chances of being educated and gaining higher education qualifications which,
it should be remembered, play a symbolic role and act as significant signals or
standards in the labour market. They are also a key factor in opportunities for
occupational mobility, and hence a crucial element in career development.
By means of this new regime, reflecting demographic and institutional
changes, employers might still have access to a better-educated, more highly
skilled and more adaptable work force. They would continue to use education
as a means of supplying the reservoir of skills they needed in order to
respond to future changes.
Finally, governments would be able to deal with the new challenges of
meeting the needs of increasingly well educated societies; and education
systems and educational institutions would find the means both to adapt to
young people’s new behaviour and to widen their potential public, thereby
consolidating their position in the economy and in society.
4.5.
The identity of education systems and
production of skills for the economy
The question addressed in this point is the interaction between the supply of
and demand for qualifications. For this we need to look at a number of
aspects: the timescale of the production and consumption of skills, the
response to the needs of the economy versus the needs of employers, the
differences between these two sorts of needs and their links with the needs
of individuals, and, finally, against this background, the role of educational
institutions.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
The supply of persons with qualifications is relatively independent of
demand. This is explained by the social diversity of the functions of
education, which cannot be reduced solely to the economic domain. Even in
this domain, the difference in the timescale between the supply of
qualifications and the demand for skills, and the differences between
employers’ short-term needs and the long-term needs of the economy, not to
mention those of individuals, may help to explain the relative independence
of the supply.
Much attention has been given to the key part played historically in the
evolution of the output of qualifications by the protagonists involved – the
State, young people and their families. It has also been shown that the
behaviour of these players regarding the rise in education has been affected
by changes in the demand for labour.
The results of EDEX also point to an obvious interaction between
educational expansion and economic developments, even though long-term
educational growth does not appear to be very sensitive to variations in
economic conditions: “...even though the study makes no pretence of being
exhaustive, the employers interviewed usually perceived the issue of
educational expansion and the greater availability of people with
qualifications in the market – at least this is a strong trend – as a response to
the increasingly urgent needs for retraining labour and anticipating those
retraining needs. Technological advances bring about changes in work that
often tend towards greater complexity. In recent years, moreover, they have
also speeded up extraordinarily because of the growth in computerised
information and communications (to mention but one factor). Since the vast
majority of individuals acquires qualifications during initial education, it is
young people who are the “carriers” of educational expansion. There is an
assumption that the higher the qualifications, the greater the individual’s
adaptability. Employers see qualifications as a guarantee of greater and
faster – and ultimately less costly – adaptability. And that may a major factor
in the decision to recruit young people” (Béduwé, 2000).
Although employers may not play a leading role in educational expansion,
they have certainly supported it through their recruitment behaviour in France,
Spain and Italy; as also in Germany, where they show a preference for offering
apprenticeships to young people who have completed upper secondary
education. It is in any case unthinkable that such a widespread and long-term
phenomenon should have been contrary to the needs of employers.
Employers express their opinions on the matter by default: they accept the
products of the education system when they recruit people with qualifications.
The initiative for expansion would thus rest with the State and families.
155
156
Educational expansion and labour market
On the other hand, if we focus on the production of skills rather than the
qualifications produced by education systems, it is apparent that skills –
additional and specialist skills – are produced jointly by both systems, i.e. by
educational institutions and by employers.
Demand follows supply: Results of a macro-statistical approach
based on skills
The work done in EDEX was based on a macro-statistical finding from earlier
studies (Mallet et al., 1997): demand for qualifications follows supply.
These studies were explored and built on in EDEX (Chapter 2).
The studies were conducted on the basis that the skills needed to do a job
are made up of a variety of components acquired through initial education,
experience, continuing education and social learning. We attempted to reflect
this essential fact statistically in our work, although we had to work around
the limitations of our statistical systems: thus, we added age as a proxy for
work experience to level of qualifications in order to evaluate individual skills.
These three results were common to all the countries taking part in the
study:
• Educational expansion has spread in all categories of employment, as the
result of a strong supply-side effect that is relatively independent of the
parallel growth in the numbers of people employed in various categories.
• If requirements for access to each occupation are taken into account, the
rise in levels of education within employment has overall been reflected
wages and salaries.
• The likelihood of reaching management positions, all other things being
equal, (qualifications, age, economic situation) has declined among
generations born after 1940.
The rise in levels of education within employment has been reflected in the
pay scale according to complex and changing patterns that combine the
supply-side effect and employers’ requirements (Haas, Tahar, 2001). People
with more qualifications are being recruited (by default, given the changes in
the supply), but this is beneficial as the additional human capital is better
rewarded overall within a given occupation. It also leads to changes in the
system of occupational mobility, access to management positions being
merely one aspect.
The questions that arise relate to employers’ behaviour in response to the
greater availability of people with qualifications in the labour supply; the
reasons they give for recruiting qualified people; and the use they make of
them.
4.5.1.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
4.5.2. The timescale of skills production
One basic finding of EDEX is that the skills which employers were able to use
with some success to meet the commercial challenges of the second half of
the 1990s (which resulted from technological change and the globalisation of
trade), were largely produced through educational expansion, well before the
demand for them became visible. In other words, the demand of the 1990s
was satisfied thanks to educational decisions taken by governments and
families in the 1970s and 1980s. The nature of the supply made it possible
to satisfy the demand that actually arose.
The answer to the question of what qualifications are needed varies
according to the timescale in which it is asked; similarly, every mismatch
arising between the supply of skills and the demand for skills is essentially a
problem of timing. The changes occurring as a result of globalisation mean
that decisions about the production, circulation and accumulation of capital
are governed by the short term, while decisions about human and social
reproduction m0ust take into account the long and very long term (Vinokur,
1998).
In the relationship between the supply of skills and the demand for skills,
time plays widely varying roles. There are the time taken to acquire skills, the
length of time for which they are used, and the timescale for forward
planning, all of which have financial consequences. In order to clarify these
roles, it would appear helpful to distinguish between the players involved
(individuals, institutions and employers), thereby demonstrating the
incompatibility of the timescales in which they each make their financial
calculations.
The individual timescale in the acquisition of qualifications
Individuals largely acquire qualifications during initial education.
People logically have long-term strategies for initial education, being
aware that investment in this education will provide the basis for their social
and occupational positions (D’Iribarne A., D’Iribarne P., 1993) and hence for
their ability to enter continuing education. The minimum timescale for these
decisions about initial education is necessarily the same as the anticipated
length of active life.
Individuals are also aware of the irreversible nature of their initial education
for at least two reasons. First, such a long period of full-time education cannot
be repeated later in life. Secondly, people are only young once. Youth, the
age of initial education, is a period of life when individuals are more
malleable, both psychologically and physically, and this again reinforces the
irreversible nature of initial education (Planas, Plassard, 2000).
4.5.2.1.
157
158
Educational expansion and labour market
4.5.2.2. The time taken to produce and renew the overall supply of skills
Two major processes may influence the renewal of the overall supply of
skills: a) demographic renewal through the flow of leavers from initial
education, and b) continuing education.
The overall supply of skills is therefore affected by the long-term inertia of
demography and of the initial education acquired by each of the generations
making up the active population of each country (see Chapters 1 and 2). In
the short term, it has the adjustment mechanism of continuing education, in
the broad sense, i.e., education comprising work experience, continuing
education and training courses and any other activity from which skills can be
learnt during active life.
The time taken by education systems to produce persons with
qualifications is expanding, both because the period spent in compulsory
education is becoming longer, and because post-compulsory education is
becoming increasingly common (see Chapter 2). This reflects individuals’
strategic decisions.
The time taken to produce skills must distinguish between the long periods
spent in basic education on the one hand – which are structural – and the
history of experience incorporated into human capital and the short periods
required to produce specialist abilities on the other – which are situationspecific.
The timescale for demand: short-term tactics and long-term strategy
As a tactical approach (see Chapter 3), employers quite independently make
the best use of the opportunities offered by the environment in which they find
themselves in order to respond to production needs that are increasingly
dominated by the short term.
Nowadays, when a company decides on its initial requirements, the skills
needed are laid down in ignorance of the skills that will be required in the
future. It is reasonable that companies should try to anticipate, either by
recruiting people whose skills may not all be used until later, or by recruiting
workers capable of acquiring cheaply the skills that may prove to be
necessary later. In both cases, it would be possible to speak of a “reservoir
of skills” associated with level of qualifications and possibly with specific
subject areas (Haas, 2000).
As for the organisation and design of jobs, a lack of full information
suggests that “constructivist” theories of organisation apply, i.e., that
problems are resolved as they appear. Companies must therefore have the
requisite skills (skills necessarily possessed by individuals or a group of
individuals) to respond to these issues. The adaptation cost analysis
4.5.2.3.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
proposed by Stanckiewicz (2000) addresses this issue.
The lack of complete information also relates to outlets and hence to shortterm flexibility of production. Being flexible has consequences for the
organisation, and therefore for jobs and the skills required
(Vincens, 2000 p. 3).
But companies are not a homogeneous whole, and the time constraints on
a company will depend on two groups of variables (Planas et al., 2001):
(a) On its strategic timescale (Galtier, 1996). If a company plans to continue
its current activities for a long time, its timescale will be long and its main
problem will be the uncertainties that are inseparable from any project. If,
on the other hand, a company has a short timescale, this will mean that
it intends to change the way in which it uses its capital in the relatively
near future. It is therefore highly likely that it will also change its demand
for labour and hence its skills requirements in order to match the use
made of its capital.
(b) On staff relations within the company. By this term we mean the whole
web of relationships which together form the human resources
management policy governing the potential existence of an internal
market or a company training policy, etc.
The combination of these two groups of variables governs the policy of the
company. It is obvious that a company with a short timescale will seek to
obtain the skills needed from the market without worrying about their future
use. A company with a long timescale, however, may try to make sure of the
skills needed in both the short and the long term. It will tend to develop a
training policy and to recruit its staff with an eye to individuals’ potential.
However, even with a long timescale, staff relations may be such that the
company has no long-term policy and is content to look to the market for what
it requires at any given time. Here, the situation on the labour market will
obviously be of huge importance.
The needs of employers and the needs of the economy
The needs of the economy are not the same as the aggregate needs of
employers at any given time. This difference rests on two key factors: the
long-term needs of the economy cannot be discerned from the needs of
companies; on the other, individuals’ education and training behaviour does
not exactly match the needs of the companies employing them.
Because of the unemployment associated with finding a first job or losing
a job, part of the active population is not in employment. Moreover, if an
employee’s education is to coincide with his or her company’s training plan,
their aims would need to be remarkably similar.
4.5.3.
159
160
Educational expansion and labour market
There is no guarantee that the needs of employers (usually short-term)
and those of individuals (usually medium or long-term) will coincide. In
managing their careers, individuals take decisions which do not fit with the
skills requirements of the companies employing them, and are sometimes
even contradictory. Nonetheless, the sum of these individual behaviours, as
has just been said, is a crucial factor in economic development.
Furthermore, in a world of growing complexity and uncertainty, a
“supercomplex” (45) world as Barnett (2000) might say, the want of complete
information about the needs of employers increases with the length of the
timescale.
It is thus shown that there is no equivalency between the needs of the
economy and the needs of employers. In other words, the needs of the
economy cannot be likened to the sum of the needs of employers that obtain
in the economy at any given time. The needs of the economy do not, of
course, run counter to those of employers, but the results of EDEX show that
there are asymmetries in the information needed to manage production of the
skills needed by both. This raises the major policy issue: What should be the
orientation of the initial education system? and what is its place in the
development of lifelong learning and the systems that will deliver it?
The economy and education systems will evolve in line with the major
trends that companies also have to cope with. Both the forces driving the
economy, and educational expansion, have provided the framework within
which companies have acted as consumers of qualifications and as
producers and consumers of skills. In the field of education it is obvious that
the production of qualifications has proved beneficial for the economy over
the long term, despite the differences in timescale between the need (and
therefore the demand) for skills expressed by employers, and the production
by the education system of generations of people with qualifications.
Can all of this be summed up in the simple phrase “the more education,
the better”, whereby the nature and purpose of the education ultimately
matter little? The answer is a clear No.
The independence of each system reflects the complexity of European
societies and economies: greater independence reflects increased
complexity. The consequence for education systems, especially universities,
is that they will be forced to find the time and the means to define mediumterm development objectives jointly with the supervisory bodies funding them
(45) The term supercomplexity, as used by R. Barnett, is employed here to indicate an extraordinary
increase in the complexity of the frame of reference in European societies and, in consequence,
in the unpredictability of its evolution.
Conclusions and policy recommendations
– and then to implement and attain these objectives. The time that they
spend on this, which might be seen as a search by education systems for
their own identities (in relation to continuing education, the economy and so
on), and on reporting on the objectives attained, will justify their
independence in return. This leads on to the very fashionable quest for
enhanced quality in education systems and for evaluation of that quality.
According to Cave et al. (1997), for example, in an analysis of the situation
in the United Kingdom, evaluation of higher education institutions based on
“objective” indicators and “external” evaluators has led to “adaptive” rather
than innovative behaviour. It would appear that greater innovation is
achieved through models based on joint definition of objectives, and through
independence for institutions in implementing these.
Strengthening the identities of education systems in response to
the needs of the economy
It may be deduced from the preceding points that the market, which is subject
to growing pressure leading to greater uncertainty and complexity, cannot be
expected to provide education systems with the long-term information that
they need to guide their development.
According to Barnett (2000, p. 257), a supercomplex world is one in which
facts, arguments, data, tasks, etc., do not develop a priori in fixed patterns.
Even the patterns that allow us to make sense of the world, our place in the
world and our frame of action, are in doubt. In a world of this type, Barnett
argues, it is necessary to preserve the “identity” of education systems (he is
referring to higher education) in the light of, and in balance with, their
“performativity” dominated by the “know-how” that is governed by the needs
of the market.
To put it simply, education systems must, in order to respond to the needs
of the market in a supercomplex world, preserve their function of initial
education in the long term and support the growth of lifelong education while
avoiding the pressures of a market governed by the short term, failing which
they may quickly become ineffective and inefficient.
“This presents a challenge to governments and the European
Commission: modernising the education system without subjecting it to the
strict constraints of the market while arguing for education for the long term
(rather than adaptive learning), maintaining a vocational approach (to ensure
that employees learn lasting skills), monitoring the subject-matter taught (to
enhance cognitive ability and critical distance at the same time as vocational
behaviour)…. What the recent past has shown is the independence of
education systems relative to employers’ needs. The former change more
4.5.4.
161
162
Educational expansion and labour market
slowly than the latter does, and are less subject to crises of market
adjustment. Education often seems to give an unchanging answer (adjusted
or not) to a wide range of social and economic problems (social life, production, economic development). It serves as a palliative for growing
uncertainties and complexities in a world where traditions are in crisis and all
sorts of activities continually have to be (excessively?) reformulated” (Louart,
2001).
In order to fulfil their economic and social functions in the long term,
education systems need to develop their own identities, taking into account
the needs of European societies and economies. As Barnett (2000, p. 265)
says in relation to university curricula, “...a policy perspective has opened up,
too, in our discussion. Curricula, I have suggested, are in a state of transition
but they are not necessarily moving in any clear or even deliberate direction.
Such dominant directions of change as there are – towards performative
models – are inappropriate to conditions of supercomplexity. Accordingly, a
new responsibility is falling on universities to demonstrate that the education
that they offer is likely to be adequate to the challenges of a supercomplex
world. It is a responsibility – and an educational project – that most
universities and most curricula are failing to meet.”
Defining the place of education systems in society, and creating their
identity as chiefly responsible for initial education, means being able to
handle a long-term balancing act between, firstly, managing the link between
its economic function and its other functions – which must not be forgotten –
and, secondly, within its economic function, managing the needs and
interests of the economy, employers and individuals, particularly the longterm needs. And this all has to be done against a background of
“supercomplexity” and hence of uncertain information.
It is not the purpose of this report to prescribe how educational institutions
should set about achieving this balance. From our results it is evident that two
diametrically opposite dangers have to be avoided: on the one hand, being
dependent, as provider, on clients (companies) governed by the temporary
economic needs of the market, and on the other, managing education on the
basis of internal and/or academic inertia in the “donnish” British tradition
(Halsey, 1982). The latter course runs the risk of ignoring the social and
economic needs to which institutions must respond.
What information is relevant? What points of reference do education
systems need to create and update their identities? It is not within the
province of this research to provide the answers. It is well known that a wide
range of information is required, taking into account, among other things, the
needs of the economy, employers and individuals, all of which are changing.
Cedefop (European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training)
EDEX
∂ducational expansion
and Labour Market
A comparative study of five European countries
– France, Germany, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom –
with special reference to the United States
Catherine Béduwé
Jordi Planas
Luxembourg:
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities
2003 – VI, 191 pp. – 17.5 x 25 cm
(Cedefop Reference series; 39 – ISSN 1608-7089)
ISBN 92-896-0201-5
Cat. No: TI-49-02-345-EN-C
Price (excluding VAT) in Luxembourg: EUR 25
No of publication: 3030 EN
Educational expansion
and labour market
A comparative study of five European
countries – France, Germany, Italy, Spain
and the United Kingdom – with special
reference to the United States
European Centre for the
Development of Vocational Training
Europe 123, GR-570 01 Thessaloniki (Pylea)
Postal address: PO Box 22427, GR-551 02 Thessaloniki
Tel. (30) 23 10 49 01 11, Fax (30) 23 10 49 00 20
E-mail:
[email protected]
Homepage: www.cedefop.eu.int
Interactive website: www.trainingvillage.gr
Price (excluding VAT) in Luxembourg: EUR 25
3030 EN
ISBN 92-896-0201-5
9 789289 6 0 2 0 1 3
TI-49-02-345-EN-C
Catherine Béduwé, Jordi Planas (project coordinators)
Manfred Tessaring (Cedefop)
16
The analyses provide a sound basis for understanding and shaping
the links between education and employment, and thus between
the supply of and demand for skills on labour markets.
05
Taking a comparative approach, four major questions are addressed:
• What are the processes and factors leading to educational
expansion?
• How are generations with increasing levels of qualification spread
throughout the employment system, and with what private returns?
• How has this affected company organisation and management
of human resources and what links have been established between
skills supply and demand?
• What are the implications for national systems linking education
to employment, and to what extent are countries converging or
diverging?
04
This is the final report of the TSER project ‘Educational expansion
and labour markets’ (EDEX) carried out in cooperation with British,
French, German, Italian and Spanish teams. It analyses the longterm consequences of the rise in levels of education on access to
employment and human resource management.