Cass Business School
MSc Investment Management - 2005
Structuring Venture Capital Deals
by
Shikhir Singh
Supervisor: Robert Cressy
This dissertation is submitted as part of the requirements
for the award of the MSc in Investment Management
1
Abstract
Fundraising with venture capitalists can remain a largely mysterious
process. In a world shrouded with non-disclosure agreements, the entrepreneurs
are often unaware of the common practices of deal terms and are unable to
benchmark their term sheets with respect to those given to others. Inherent
conflicts of interest in the split of the financial returns, liquidation, and control of
the company lead the venture capitalists to structure the deals which benefit
their interests at cost to the interests of the entrepreneurs. This dissertation
identifies and characterizes the term sheet structures used by venture capitalists
today and establishes their frequency. This information can be used by
entrepreneurs to benchmark their term sheets and by venture capitalists to
evaluate their investment strategies.
2
Acknowledgements
I am very grateful for guidance, comments, and massive assistance
provided by Katherine who made this dissertation possible.
My sincere
thanks goes out to my dissertation advisor Dr Robert Cressy who made this
dissertation very enjoyable.
3
Table of Contents
1
Introduction ………………………………………………………………
2
Expectations of Entrepreneurs When Structuring
3
4
9
a Deal with Venture Capitalists …………………………………….
14
Liquidation and Financial Split Provisions ………………………..
17
Redemption Provision ………………………………………………
17
Redeemable Preferred Stock ………………………………………..
18
Redeemable Preferred & Common Stocks …………………………
19
Convertible Preference Shares ………………………………………
20
Participating Convertible Preference Shares ………………………
21
Multiple Rounds Standards …………………………………………
22
Liquidation Multiple …………………………………………………
23
Industry Sector Liquidation Multiple ………………………………
24
Dilution Provisions in Venture Capital …………………………….
25
Anti-Dilution Clause …………………………………………………
28
Pay to Play Provision …………………………………………………
32
Employee Stock Options ……………………………………………..
33
Control Provisions ……………………………………………………….
34
Board Members ……………………………………………………….
34
Milestone Provision …………………………………………………..
35
Voting Rights ………………………………………………………….
36
4
Class Veto Rights ……………………………………………………..
36
Dividend Provision …………………………………………………..
37
Fees …………………………………………………………………….
37
Lockup Provision ……………………………………………………..
39
Founder Shares Vesting ………………………………………………
40
Drag Along Provisions ……………………………………………….
40
Tag Along Provisions …………………………………………………
41
5 Findings and Conclusion ………………………………………………… 42
6 Work Cited …………………………………………………………………. 44
Appendix
A: Effects of VC Investment on Allocations of Equity ……………………
46
B: Online Questionnaire ………………………………………………………
48
5
List of Figures
Figure 3.1: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green)
with respect to liquidation values if the investor holds preferred stock. Note that the
VC’s upside potential is capped. …………………………………………………
20
Figure 3.2: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green)
with respect to liquidation values if the investor holds preferred & common stock.
Note that the VC’s upside is not capped as shown earlier. ……………………….
21
Figure 3.3: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green)
with respect to liquidation values if the investor holds convertible preference shares.
……………………………………………………………………………………
22
Figure 3.4: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green)
with respect to liquidation values if the investor holds participating convertible
preference shares. The investor gets free ordinary shares and maintains his preference
shares if the liquidation event is a sale, and if the liquidation event is an IPO, the
investor will get either the ordinary shares or the preference shares’ face value. … 22
6
List of Tables
Table 2.1: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different stages…. 15
Table 2.2: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different locations
15
Table 2.3: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different sectors… 16
Table 2.4: Number of VCs approached and the average number of term sheets
received by each company (after 2002)……………………………………………. 16
Table 2.5: Average Time taken to negotiate and close the deal (after 2002)………
17
Table 3.1: Common penalty clauses required by VCs in Redemption clauses……
19
Table 3.2: Study by Fenwich & West LLP (reprinted with permission) shows that
significant percentages of companies can require more than 4 rounds of financing. 23
Table 3.3: Answers to our USA survey when asked which type of shares were issued
in this round of financing?........................................................................................ 24
Table 3.4: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
entire sample………………………………………………………………………
24
Table 3.5: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
the Biotechnology sector. ………………………………………………………… 25
Table 3.6: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
the Software sector. ………………………………………………………………
25
7
Table 3.7: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
the Life Science sector. ……………………………………………………………
25
Table 3.8: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
those companies offered only 1 term sheet. ………………………………………
25
Table 3.9: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of
those companies offered only 1 term sheet…………………………………………
26
Table 3.10: Questionnaire conducted shows that the VC is more likely to offer
participating preferred shares if the entrepreneur has only 1 other term sheet …… 26
Table 3.11: Questionnaire conducted shows breakdown of both types of anti-dilution
clauses. ……………………………………………………………………………
31
Table 3.12: Above are the penalties which are common in pay to play clauses.
Generally, there is more than one penalty. ………………………………………
32
Table 3.13: Our questionnaire asked, does your company offer employee stock
options? The results are categorized by sectors. …………………………………
32
Table 3.14: Employee stock option pool as a percentage of total equity (not including
founder shares). ……………………………………………………………………
33
Table 3.15: Shows that the employee stock option pool generally needs to be increased
as more rounds of financing are required. ………………………………………
33
Table 4.1: Common milestone targets set in milestone agreement..
33
Table 4.2: Common penalties for not meeting milestones. ……………………
36
Table 4.3:
Percentages of dividend types required by VCs according to our
questionnaire. ……………………………………………………………………
38
Table 4.4: Payer of legal fees. .……........................................................................ . 39
Table 4.5: Payer of Due Diligence fees. …………………………………………… 39
8
Table 4.6: Duration of lockup provisions for entrepreneurs and VCs in USA and
Europe.
………………………………………………………………………………….
Table
4.7:
Vesting
time
by
location
at
Startup
…………………………………………………………………………………..
40
Stage.
40
Table 4.8: Drag along percentages in the startup and expansion phases.
……………….. …………………………………………………………………
41
9
I. Introduction
Venture capital financing is attractive due to many reasons. Venture
capitalists (VCs) allow the entrepreneur to raise the money all from one place.
Given that VCs are in the business of building businesses, they have plenty of
experience with the challenges of startups. Also, VCs usually have been
through the process growing the company to Initial Public Offering (IPO) and
other desired liquidation events (Bagley, 2003). VCs usually have a large
rolodex of contacts which can help the company become successful. VCs can
also give assistance in hiring members of the management team if necessary.
Furthermore,
research
shows
“venture-backed
firms
also
perform
significantly better after they go public than similar non-venture-backed
firms” (Bagley, 2003).
Although the reasons to seek venture capital are obvious, the
entrepreneur and the venture capitalist must be aware of the conflicts of
interest that exist between them. Deal terms structured by the venture
capitalist should address these conflicts of interest by minimizing the risk and
maximizing the returns for the VC. Structuring deal terms in the venture
capital world can be a very complex process.
Before we begin analyzing why and how the deals are structured, certain
terminology and assumptions need to be clarified.
Liquidation Event is any exit event for the VCs. This may include sale of the
company, merger, closing down of the company, and an IPO. Creating a
successful company, and then successfully liquidating it, is the primary
objective of the VC. Usually the venture capitalist wants to invest his money
for three to five years and expects returns in excess of 40%.
10
Pre-Money is the value of the company prior to receiving the outside (VC)
financing.
Post-Money is equal to Pre-Money + external funding received.
Share price offered by the VC is equal to the pre-money divided by the sum of
the number of shares outstanding (excluding the new VC shares) and options.
The share price is often the point of contention in negotiation between an
entrepreneur and a VC. This dissertation will show that deal terms are
imposed on the entrepreneur by the VC which aims to minimize its risk and
maximize its returns.
Share Price =
premoney
SO + Options
where SO = # of shares outstanding
Calculations of how VC investment causes equity to be divided up between
the entrepreneur and the VC are shown in appendix A. An understanding of
the calculations in appendix A will enrich one’s comprehension of this
dissertation.
Venture capitalists have the daunting task of taking huge risks by investing a
very significant amount of money into sometimes nothing more than a
business plan. They also have the luxury of rejecting 99% of all investment
opportunities that come their way. Conflicts of interest occur between the VC
and the entrepreneur because there is a difference between some of their goals
and objectives. In an effort to minimize their risk and maximize their ROI
(Return on Investment), the VC often asks for provisions that align their
interests with the interests of the entrepreneur.
The goals of an entrepreneur of a company which is seeking funding are to
(Schoar, 2002):
1. Create a successful company
2. Get the funding necessary to create a successful company
11
3.
4.
5.
6.
Maintain maximum value and control of the company
Share the risks with the investors
Obtain the expertise and contacts that help the growth of the company
Obtain a reward for creating a successful company
The goals of a VC which is seeking to provide funding are to:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Maximize return to justify the risks and effort in funding company
Ensure that the company makes best use of the capital provided
Ensure the ability to invest in later financing rounds if it so chooses
Ensure the ability to liquidate their assets to match their funding cycle
Develop a reputation that attracts other venture opportunities
Conflicts of interest arise due to differing objectives between VCs and
entrepreneurs on:
1. Split of the Financial return of the company
2. Liquidation of the company
3. Control of the company
Conflict of interest (1) occurs due to the following: The VC wants to give the
entrepreneur just enough percentage of the company to keep them motivated
until the liquidation event, and the entrepreneur wants to give the VC just
enough percentage of the company so that the VC will choose to invest. In
this way, the VC and the entrepreneur have a conflict of interest in regards to
their view of the appropriate way to split the financial return of the company.
Conflict of interest (2) occurs due to the following: VCs have very precise
timetable expectations of when and how they want their shares liquidated.
The VCs set these timetables for the companies which they have funded.
These timetables must match the timetables which were dictated by investors
of the venture capital fund. The VCs and their investors agree on a length of
time (generally 5 years) that the VCs have to fund companies with the
investor’s money. The VCs must hold the funded companies to a precise
timetable because they must return the money to their investors at that
previously agreed upon time. To receive funds according to their timetable,
VCs can set provisions which extract value to meet their objectives. In contrast
to VCs, entrepreneurs are generally involved in management of the company
12
for a longer period. The VCs also want preference to any shareholders. In
other words, VCs want their money in any liquidation event before any of the
other common stockholders receive anything. The difference (between VCs
and entrepreneurs) in timetables and the preferences for shareholders when
there is a liquidation event of the company is a conflict of interest in regards
to liquidation of the company.
Conflict of interest (3) occurs due to the following: After investing, the VC is
now part owner of the company and needs to be consulted on how money is
being spent. Furthermore, the VC wants rights which will ensure that
management is performing well and maximizing returns. Conflict over
control of the company thus naturally arises between the entrepreneur and
the VC as a struggle for power over company decisions ensues.
From these conflicts of interest, an inherent power struggle is created where
the VC wants to minimize risk and maximize returns but the entrepreneur
wants to share risk and receive the VC investments.
Although the reason for deal structures is to control the conflicts of interest
between VCs and entrepreneurs, the reasons for the variation in the value of
deal structures includes, but is not limited to, the strength of the market, the
sector of the company, the desperation of the CEO, the competition for the
deal, and the stage of the company. These reasons are analyzed in depth in
this dissertation. Other possible reasons for the variation in the value of deal
structures which are discussed, but not analyzed, include the management
team, the emotional climate of the investing community, the integrity of the
VC firm, the philosophy of the fund, the stage of the fund, and the personal
view of the investor.
Chapter three will discuss how deal terms are structured in a manner which
addresses the conflicts over the split of the financial return and liquidation of
13
the company. Chapter four will discuss how deal terms are structured in a
manner which addresses the conflict over control of the company. Both
chapters three and four will also analyze the reasons involved in the variation
of the value of deal structures.
For this dissertation, we determined the common set of provisions asked by
the VCs by completing a literature survey and interviewing VCs. After which,
we sent a personalized email and questionnaire to approximately 5000 CEOs,
founders, and CFOs asking them about their last venture capital round of
financing. Of the 5000 emailed, 123 responded. This dissertation uses their
answers to analyze the deal structures of term sheets and as such, is
inherently limited by their knowledge of their own VC deal terms.
14
II. Expectations of Entrepreneurs When Structuring a Deal with Venture
Capitalists
The process of raising funds can be a difficult one, but our questionnaire shows
that it may not be as difficult as anticipated if the entrepreneur has a solid
company. Of the companies that got funding, the majority did not struggle much
in accomplishing this feat. In the questionnaire, the level of difficulty for raising
funds in the latest round of financing was asked on a scale from one to five. As
high as 42% of startups said that it was not difficult (lowest on the scale) to raise
funds. Only 8% of startups said it was extremely difficult (highest on the scale).
Our questionnaire shows that the difficulty of raising VC funds also varied by
location. It is more (not much) difficult on average to raise funds in Europe than
in the USA. Our questionnaire also shows that difficulty raising funds varies by
industry sectors. It easier to raise funds in the software sector, than it is in the
Biotechnology, Life Sciences, and Pharmaceutical sectors. Tables 2.1 through 2.3
show the complete results.
Difficulty in Raising Funds By Stage
Not
Somewhat
Difficult
Difficult
(1)
(2)
Startup
42%
15%
Expansion 39%
20%
All
34%
22%
Surveyed
Moderately
Difficult
(3)
35%
29%
33%
Very
Difficult
(4)
0%
7%
6%
Extremely
Difficult
(5)
8%
5%
5%
Table 2.1: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different stages.
Difficulty in Raising Funds by Location
Not
Difficult
(1)
Somewhat
Difficult
(2)
Moderately Very
Difficult
Difficult
(3)
(4)
Extremely
Difficult
(5)
USA
42%
26%
17%
11%
4%
Europe
24%
24%
38%
2%
11%
Table 2.2: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different locations.
15
The websites of many VCs state that only 1% of the business plans which they
receive get funding. Our questionnaire asked entrepreneurs which received
venture capital funding the number of term sheet offers that they received out of
the number of different VC investors that the entrepreneurs approached.1 Out of
the entrepreneurs that received funding in the startup or seed phase, 24% of the
venture capitalists that they approached gave them funding. In the expansion
stage, the number is around 25%. Although surprisingly, entrepreneurs on
average only approached 12 to 13 VCs and received about two term sheets each.
Difficulty in Raising Funds by Sector
Software
Not
Difficult
(1)
Somewhat
Difficult
(2)
Moderately Very
Difficult
Difficult
(4)
(3)
Extremely
Difficult
(5)
42%
26%
17%
11%
4%
24%
24%
38%
2%
11%
21%
29%
33%
13%
4%
Life Science &
Pharmaceutical
Biotechnology
Table 2.3: Difficulty in Raising Funds with VCs after 2002 for different sectors.
Phase
Approached VC #
Startup
Expansion
12.1
12.8
Received Term Sheets
from Different VCs
1.78
2.0
Table 2.4: Number of VCs approached and the average number of term sheets received by each company
(after 2002).
Another question we asked companies was; how long did it take to negotiate and
close the deal after the first contact with the VC? For both the startup and
expansion stage, it took about 5.5 months to close the deal.
1
The 24% and 25% calculations were done by dividing the number of term sheets received by the number
of approached VCs for each entrepreneur individually and then averaging the percentages.
16
Phase
Startup
Expansion
Time
5.5 months
5.4 months
Standard Deviation
3.2 months
2.98 months
Table 2.5: Average Time taken to negotiate and close the deal (after 2002).
It is worth noting that the standard deviation for the negotiating time is
relatively large. Our questionnaire asked the entrepreneurs in the “expansion
stage,” would their company have existed for one more year if they didn’t
receive the VC funding, and 50% responded no. After sending our questionnaire,
we received many responses from entrepreneurs stating that the biggest factor in
determining the variance in deal structures is the desperation of the CEO. The
majority of CEOs don’t give themselves enough time to go out and seek funds,
thus they very often land themselves in trouble (i.e. CEOs put themselves in a
situation where they may be forced into a set of deal terms because their need for
funding is urgent). In the later chapters we measure how much not seeking more
than one term sheet can cost an entrepreneur.
17
III. Liquidation and Financial Split Provisions
A conflict of interest arises in liquidation events when VCs want preference or
first rights to any cash available to any stockholders. To achieve this, VCs usually
require an issue of a new class of stock which have preference to the common
stock in case of a liquidation event. The conflict of interest occurs because the
entrepreneur argues that both he and the VC are investing in a risky venture and
thus they should both share the burden in case of a poor liquidation event. The
VC argues that if it invests, for example, £2m into a company that has a premoney valuation of £2m resulting in £4m post-money, then in exchange for the
£2m cash, the VC receives half the company where the entrepreneur receives the
other half mainly for his idea and the time taken to put the business together.
The entrepreneur the next day could sell the company for £2m and he would get
to keep £1m resulting in a £1m dollar immediate loss for the VC. The above
scenario is obviously not one that a VC can afford to get itself into, and as such it
must make provisions which aim to protect against such exploitation. The
following are deal terms which may be required by the VCs to ensure that the
type of losses in the above example will not happen and that the VC will make
money from the deal with the entrepreneur. These deal terms serve as protection
for the VCs which is necessitated by the conflicts of interest concerning
liquidation and financial split provisions.
Redemption Provision:
The VC and the entrepreneur’s objective also differ in terms of the exit timetable.
To motivate the company to exit quickly and to extract value if a company
cannot, a clause that require some sort of payment back to the VC is constructed.
It can be structured so that the company has to buy back the preferred shares at a
multiple of the price paid. It can also be structured so that the VC does not lose
his shares if the repayment occurs. Out of the total sample in our survey 21% of
18
the rounds of financing had a redemption clause. Redemption clauses usually are
structured in stages. The first stage is to give management a wake-up call to find
a liquidation opportunity, and the second stage is designed to extract value. The
average time in our survey before some provision of the redemption clause to
kick in was 5.83 years.
Unpaid dividends require payment
Appoint Committee to look for exit opportunities
Pay back initial value
Pay back multiple of initial value
VCs get more board seats
VCs get more special rights
22%
11%
39%
11%
6%
11%
Table 3.1: Common penalty clauses required by VCs in Redemption clauses
Redeemable Preferred Stock:
VCs often require a new class of stock which has preference to any cash available
from a liquidation event; preferred stock. If the business is sold, the VCs will first
get their share and the common stockholders will have to divide up what is left.
Using the above example, if the entrepreneur sells his company the next day,
then the VC will get back his £2m and the entrepreneur will be left with neither a
company nor any money. Thus, this class of stock serves as a guarantee that the
VC will recover a certain amount of its investment. This class of stock can also
require a multiple of initial investment to be repaid before the common stock
holders receive any money. Using the example above, if the multiple was set at
2x, the entrepreneur worked very hard, and the company was now sold for £6m,
then the VC would get £4m and the entrepreneur would get £2m. Figure 3.1
shows that in a liquidation event, if the value of the liquidation is less than the
investment multiple or face value required by the preferred stock, then the
entrepreneur gets nothing (Schoar, 2002). If the value of the investment is greater
than this amount, then the entrepreneur only then gets the remaining amount
19
after face value is paid off. It should be noted that the entrepreneur has unlimited
upside potential but the VC’s upside potential is capped.
Figure 3.1: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green) with respect to
liquidation values if the investor holds preferred stock. Note that the VC’s upside potential is capped.
Redeemable Preferred & Common Stocks
The VC could request common stocks in addition to preferred stocks. This
enables the VC to get first rights to any cash available, thus making money from
both the initial investment multiple and the common stock. The VC’s upside is
not capped when this combination of stocks is utilized. Figure 3.2 shows that the
VC gets the upside as a percentage of the company common stock it owns
(Schoar, 2002).
20
Figure 3.2: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green) with respect to
liquidation values if the investor holds preferred & common stock. Note that the VC’s upside is not capped
as shown earlier.
Convertible Preference Shares
Convertible preference shares carry the right to convert preference shares to
ordinary shares at various points in the life of the company at pre-specified
conversion price. Possible conversion periods include when new stock is issued
or any exit. The investor will convert if the liquidation share price is greater than
pre-specified conversion price (Campbell, 2003). “If the stock is thinly traded, the
preferred investor is left with little ability to trade out the stock and analysts and
market makers have little motivation to follow the stock” (Wilmerding, 2003).
Figure 3.3 shows that the payoff functions of a convertible preferred stock.
21
Figure 3.3: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green) with respect to
liquidation values if the investor holds convertible preference shares.
Figure 3.4: Payoff graph of the VC investor (in blue) and the entrepreneur (in green) with respect to
liquidation values if the investor holds participating convertible preference shares. The investor gets free
ordinary shares and maintains his preference shares if the liquidation event is a sale, and if the liquidation
event is an IPO, the investor will get either the ordinary shares or the preference shares’ face value.
Participating Convertible Preference Shares
Participating convertible preference shares carry the right that in case of any
liquidation event other than an IPO, the VC will get face value plus get free
shares as though the VC had the convertibility option. In the case of an IPO, the
22
VC has just the liquidation preference or the convertibility option. So in a sale
event, the VC makes more than when there is an IPO. Figure 3.4 shows an
example of a payoff with this type of shares. Participating convertible preference
shares were once thought “to be faintly unethical, but now (are) fairly common”
(Campbell, 2003).
Multiple Rounds Standards
When multiple rounds of financing occur, each new investor usually will ask for
liquidation preference over the previous investors. It is convention for each new
round of financing to be indexed by letters starting from A. Thus a Series C
round is the third round of financing and will probably have liquidation
preference over the second round of financing (Series B).
Rounds Financed by VCs(Percentages)
Range Between Q1 2005
and Q2 2005
Series A
16% - 24%
Series B
24% - 30%
Series C
16% - 30%
Series D
15% - 22%
Series E and Up
9% - 21%
Q1 2005
24%
29%
16%
22%
9%
Table 3.2: Study by Fenwich & West LLP (reprinted with permission) shows that significant percentages of
companies can require more than 4 rounds of financing.
In Table 3.2, it can be seen that a significant round percentage of companies
require up to 5 rounds or more of financing.
In our survey, a question asked “which type of shares were issued in this round of
financing?.” Although remarkably these numbers are drastically different from other
studies performed at the same time as this one. Our answers from the USA are in table
3.3. In a study published Kramer and Patrick at a law firm Fenwick and West LLC in
Silicon Valley, California, 70% of the stocks in Silicon Valley are “Preferred in
Liquidation” (Kramer 2005). When we asked Kramer about reasons for the possible
23
variances between our data, he writes “In my own experience talking with CEOs, when
you get beyond the basic financial terms they often don't know the more esoteric legal
provisions, such as anti dilution, so that could account for the disparity”. Furthermore he
goes on to write “virtually every venture deal I see is for convertible preferred stock”.
The author is this dissertation believes that the data presented in the Fenwick study is
more accurate given their unique position in working with term sheets and their logic in
the reasons for the skew in our data. As result, the rest of this dissertation ignores the
class of shares in its discussion.
Ordinary Stocks
3%
Preferred Shares
65%
Convertible Preferred Shares
13%
Participating Convertible Preferred Shares
14%
Table 3.3: Answers to our USA survey when asked which type of shares were issued in this round of financing?
Liquidation Multiple
In the questionnaire of this study, the liquidation multiple was asked. The results
are shown in Tables 3.4 through 3.10. In the entire sample, the majority of the
liquidation multiple was 1x. The highest liquidation multiple recorded was 5x.
High liquidation multiples are dangerous; for even a successful company, only a
few rounds of financing need to take place with large liquidation multiples in
order for the founder shares to quickly become worthless.
Liquidation Multiple(Entire Sample)
Multiple
0
1
1<x≤2
2<x≤3
More than 3
Average
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
20 (19%)
59 (56%)
16 (15%)
7 (7%)
3 (3%)
1.17
Table 3.4: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of entire sample.
24
Industry Sector Liquidation Multiple
Liquidation Multiple(Biotechnology)
Multiple
0
1
1<x≤2
2<x≤3
More than 3
Average
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
2 (10%)
16 (76%)
1 (5%)
1 (5%)
1 (5%)
1.05
Table 3.5: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of the Biotechnology
sector.
Liquidation Multiple(Software)
Multiple
0
1
1<x≤2
2<x≤3
More than 3
Average
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
4 (15%)
15 (58%)
3 (12%)
2 (8%)
2 (8%)
1.37
Table 3.6: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of the Software sector.
Liquidation Multiple(Life Science)
Multiple
0
1
1<x≤2
2<x≤3
More than 3
Average
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
4 (25%)
8 (50%)
3 (19%)
1 (6%)
0
0.97
Table 3.7: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of the Life Science sector.
Liquidation Multiple(One Term Sheet)
Multiple
0
1
1<x≤2
2<x≤3
More than 3
Average
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
2 (6%)
17 (53%)
8 (25%)
3 (9%)
2 (6%)
1.49
Table 3.8: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of those companies offered
only 1 term sheet.
25
Liquidation Multiple (2 or more term sheets)
Multiple
Term Sheets in Multiple Range
0
10 (21%)
1
28 (60%)
1<x≤2
6 (13%)
2<x≤3
2 (4%)
More than 3
1 (2%)
Average
1.05
Table 3.9: Questionnaire conducted shows stats of liquidation multiple after 2002 of those companies offered
only 1 term sheet.
# of Term Sheets Obtained by Company
1 Term Sheet
More than 1 Term Sheet
Participating Preference Shares
All Types of Shares
20%
14%
Table 3.10: Questionnaire conducted shows that the VC is more likely to offer participating preferred shares
if the entrepreneur has only 1 other term sheet
Tables 3.4 through 3.6 shows that liquidation multiples vary based on share
classes. The liquidation multiple of participating convertible preferred shares are
much higher than the rest. Although due to the small data sample size, no clear
conclusion should be drawn.
Dilution Provisions in Venture Capital
Dilution provisions are possibly the most misunderstood areas in venture capital
finance. Generally, a shareholder’s shares are said to be diluted when the
percentage of shares he holds in the company goes down after new shares are
issued (Demmler, 2005). For example, if an entrepreneur holds 50% of the
company before the round of financing, and holds 45% afterwards, this is
defined as dilution. Although, this is not the kind of dilution which is referred to
in anti-dilution provisions in the VC contracts. Let’s explain by use of an example
which depicts the kind of dilution VCs are referring to when they utilize antidilution provisions.
26
Assumptions:
•
VC 1 offers an entrepreneur £300,000 for 30% of his company, thus buying
300,000 shares for £1 each. This leaves the entrepreneur with 700,000
shares and 70% of the company.
•
The pre-money value of the company is £700,000 and the post-money is
£1m.
Scenario 1:
•
The company is doing well a year later and seeks another round of
financing from VC 2. VC 2 offers £3,000,000 for 50% of the company.
£3,000,000
= £3.00
1,000,000 shares
•
Share Price =
•
VC 1’s shares are worth £0.9m and the entrepreneur’s shares are worth
£2.1m.
•
This satisfies VC 1 because after a year, the money he has invested has
gone up in value. Even if the percentage of ownership has gone down, VC
1 is satisfied.
Scenario 2:
•
The company is not doing very well and a year later it needs another
round of financing. VC 2 offers £400,000 for 50% of the company.
•
This means that the company is now worth £0.8m
•
VC 2 is buying 50% of the company so 1m shares.
•
Share Price =
•
VC 1 paid £1 per share and now the share is worth £0.40. VC 1 is not
£400,000
= £0.40
1,000,000 shares
satisfied. If VC 1 had set an anti-dilution clause, it would kick in if the
value of the share was less than £1 per share.
27
Anti-Dilution Clause
An anti-dilution clause protects the VC from dilution of share price which takes
place when new investors are taken on at a lower share price than the one paid
by the previous VC; this is known as a down-round. The right to anti-dilution
clauses only applies to investors holding convertible preferred shares and
participating convertible preferred shares. Anti-dilution clauses cause the
“investors to get additional ‘free’ shares so that their effective price equals the
new lower price” (Blaydon, 2002). Anti-dilution is most commonly achieved by
retroactively adjusting the conversion ratio between the preferred stock and
common stock. As a result, anti-dilution is done at the cost of non-protected
shareholders including the common stock shareholders whose shares end up
being diluted. Two of the most common structures for anti-dilution clauses are
known as full ratchet and weighted average provisions.
With a full ratchet, when new shares are issued, the conversion ratios between
the preferred shares and the ordinary shares are recomputed and adjusted as
though the investor had invested at the lower price. To put it another way, when
a conversion into common stock event takes place, enough new common stock
shares are issued so that the investor holding the anti-dilution right is effectively
investing in the new lower round price.
In scenario 2 of the example used above, the share price of the second round of
investment is £0.40. With a full-ratchet the conversion ratio would now be
adjusted such that VC 1 receives 450,000 shares for free.
Free Shares Received =
300,000
− 300,000 = 450,000 free shares to VC 1.
£0.40
28
The total of VC 1’s shares would now be 750,000 shares. VC 1 is now holding the
full-ratchet provision benefit from the down-round at the cost of the unprotected
shareholders who get their shares diluted.
In a weighted average anti-dilution clause, “the formula re-prices an earlier
round by issuing enough additional shares to that round to bring the effective
price down to the (weighted) average price of both the new and the previous
round” (Blaydon, 2002). The formula for the weighted average anti-dilution is
given as follows:
CP2= CP1 •
A+C
A+ D
where CP1= old conversion price
A= number of shares before the transaction
C = shares to be issued if the old conversion price held
CP2 = new conversion price
D = number of shares issued
In scenario 2 in the example above, the new conversion price would be computed
as follows (See also Example 3.1 below):
CP2 = 1 •
1,000,000 • 400,000
= 0.7
1,000,000+ 1,000,000
Free Shares Received =
300,000
- 300,000 = 128,571 shares
0. 7
The entrepreneur needs to be aware that, not only is full dilution the worst form
of anti-dilution, but it also discourages potential future investors from investing.
From the eyes of a prospective investor, putting money into a company
where the original investor has a full-ratchet looks like a bad deal. Instead
of holding a majority interest in the company, which the changed market
circumstances would dictate in the absence of ratchets, the new investor
has half the ownership of the original investor. (Blaydon, 2002)
29
In what are tough market conditions now, the VCs are insisting on these
provisions. After the tech-bubble burst, some VCs have even asked to setup a
retroactive anti-dilution clause. Blaydon (2002) in his article “Bury the Ratchet”
talks about his experience with a VC that demanded a retroactive anti-dilution
clause when they became the lead investor in another round of financing. These
types of problems were caused by the massively high valuations in the bubble
era.
One reason, which we refer to as the “Legacy Capitalization Problem,” exists when the
aggregate liquidation preference of the existing preferred stock is too large to provide
new investors with a sufficiently attractive incentive to make an investment in a
company. Such large liquidation preference can also significantly diminish management
incentives.
“Recent Developments in Venture Capital Terms”
by Barry J. Kramer and Michael J. Patrick
In our questionnaire, 69% of companies after 2002 had some form of an antidilution clause. The breakdown of different criteria’s is shown in Table 3.11.
30
Example 3.1: Anti-Dilution Styles (Scenario 2)
Assumptions
No Dilution
VC 1: Invests £300,000 for 30% of
company and gets 300,000 shares
for £1 a share.
300,000
= 15%
2,000,000
1,000,000
VC 2 % =
= 50%
2,000,000
700,000
= 35%
Entrepreneur =
2,000,000
Entrepreneur: owns 700,000 shares and 70%
of company
VC 2: Invests £400,000 a year later for
50% of company
Share Price =
£400,000
= £0.40
1,000,000 shares
Weighted Anti-Dilution
CP2= 1 •
VC 1 % =
1,000,000 • 400,000
= 0.7
1,000,000+ 1,000,000
300,000
= 428751 shares
0. 7
428,751
VC 1 % =
= 20%
2,128,751
1,000,000
VC 2 %=
= 47%
2,128,751
700,000
Entrepreneur % =
= 33%
2,128,751
VC 1 shares =
Full-Ratchet Dilution
VC 1 shares =
300,000
= 750,000
£0.40
VC 1 % =
750,000
= 30%
2,450,000
VC 2 % =
1,000,000
= 41%
2,450,000
Entrepreneur % =
700,000
= 29%
2,450,000
31
Weighted
Break Down
Average Anti- Full Ratchet
Dilution
Startup
12 (43%)
4 (14%)
Expansion
13 (38%)
7 (21%)
USA
30 (58%)
8 (15%)
Europe
12 (29%)
6 (15%)
One Term Sheet
21
9
Multiple Term Sheets 18
9
Entire Data Sample
45 (44%)
19 (19%)
No
Clause
Dilution
12 (43%)
14 (41%)
14 (27%)
23 (56%)
16
16
38 (37%)
Table 3.11: Questionnaire conducted shows breakdown of both types of anti-dilution clauses.
Pay to Play Provision
The pay to play provision is one of the few that benefits the entrepreneur over
the VC. Pay to play clauses require that VCs participate pro-rate in future
financing rounds or they will lose some or all of their privileges. In what is
known as a shadow series, the VC can lose its anti-dilution rights, liquidation
preferences, voting rights, or a combination and then the VC’s preferred stock is
converted to another class of stock. The most severe case of a pay to play clause
is when the preferred stock is converted to common stock. In our survey, 25% of
those entrepreneurs that received venture capital funding set a pay to play
clause. Out of those VCs that set an anti-dilution clause, 37% had a pay to play
clause. The most common penalty is the loss of anti-dilution privileges. Table
3.12 shows other common penalties against the VCs of a pay to play clause.
Pay to Play Penalties
Convert to Common Stock
32%
Lose Rights to Participate in Future
27%
rounds of financing
Lose Anti-Dilution Rights
68%
Lose Board Seats
14%
Others
8%
Table 3.12: Above are the penalties which are common in pay to play clauses. Generally, there is more than
one penalty.
32
Employee Stock Options
Employee stock options are a way to recruit management when a startup cannot
afford to pay market wages. It is important to remember that stock options are
after all only options, and are worth money only if the company performs well.
In our sample, the average pool size is 12.26%. Furthermore, the pool size is
generally increased as stages of financing go up.
Yes
Entire Sample
92 (81%)
Software & Dot-Com
27 (82%)
Biotechnology
17 (89%)
Communications
and 7 (70%)
Electronics
Life
Science
& 17 (89%)
Pharmaceuticals
Others
15 (88%)
No
22 (19%)
6 (18%)
2 (11%)
3 (30%)
2(11%)
2 (12%)
Table 3.13: Our questionnaire asked, does your company offer employee stock options? The results are
categorized by sectors.
Entire Sample
Software & Dot-Com
Biotechnology
Communications and Electronics
Life Science & Pharmaceuticals
Others
Employee Stock Option Pool Percentage
12.26%
12.5%
10.8%
15.6%
12.3%
11.6%
Table 3.14: Employee stock option pool as a percentage of total equity (not including founder shares).
Series I
Series III and up
Employee Stock Option Pool
(Percentage of all equity)
10 %
13.7 %
Table 3.15: Shows that the employee stock option pool generally needs to be increased as more rounds of
financing are required.
33
IV. Control Provisions
Conflicts of interest between the VC and the entrepreneur can arise because the
VC wants some control provisions. For an entrepreneur, control is important for
maintaining a fast growing company. For a VC, control is important as insurance
for when the company is not performing well. The VC wants rights to eject
management if they believe that the company is not performing as it should.
There can be overlap to some extent between the best decisions for the
entrepreneur and the best decisions for the company. In contrast, what is best for
the company and entrepreneur may not always be what is best for the VC. For
example, if a VC sets a high liquidation multiple and the company is doing
poorly, it may make sense for the VC to try to dissolve the company while there
are plenty of assets left to liquidate. This chapter concerns the provisions which
give VCs control and the ability to extract value from the company they have
funded if they are failing.
Board Members
“A corporation is legally required to have a board of directors to protect the
interests of the corporation and the equity holders” (Bagley, 2003). As a condition
of investing, the VCs usually request membership in the company board. By
using the board, the VCs are able to provide constant guidance to management
by monitoring and maintaining control over the company. “The most effective
boards give independent, informed advice to management rather than act as a
rubber stamp” (Bagley, 2003). VCs are in the business of building businesses and
this unique job gives them knowledge of common problems that occur to young,
growing businesses. The board (including its members from VCs) provides
entrepreneurs with contacts, guidance, and acts as advisors. It is also the
responsibility of the board to monitor the progress of the management team. The
number of board seats is a point of negotiation between the VC and the
entrepreneur. As each VC is added, the board is usually expanded further. The
34
VCs can gain significant control of the company by granting their board
members special rights. Entrepreneurs should push to keep themselves in the
majority, but if not possible they should always push for an independent
industry expert board member who does not have any relations with either the
VC or the company (Campbell, 2002). Independent industry experts can balance
the board where the VCs may have a poor understanding of the industry.
Usually the VCs will ask for observer rights. Observer rights allow the investors
bring their lawyers and junior associates to meetings. Campbell (2003) quotes an
entrepreneur who states that observers are not really observers, “how often does
it come to a vote? If you start voting, you have a serious problem”. In our
questionnaire, the VCs controlled, on average, 47% of the board in startups and
seed stages. The median was 50%. Furthermore, 71% of startups had an
independent industry expert on the board.
Milestone Provision
The milestone provision is another common provision used by the VC to ensure
success and extract value. In this type of provision, milestones are set and the VC
usually will give or take something if the milestone is not met. In our
questionnaire, 30% of the VCs set milestone provisions upon a company. Typical
milestones include developing a prototype, getting a large customer, sales or
profit targets, among others. Penalties for not meeting milestones are often
structured. 53% in our questionnaire stated that the milestone had no penalties
attached to them.
Another common practice is to give a company a bridge loan until they meet the
milestones. In our study 23% of those that had milestone clauses were provided
funding in the form of bridge loans at least until one milestone was met before
the rest of the funding was given.
35
Develop Prototype
Get a Large Customer
Sales or Profit Targets
Additional Funding Target
Other Targets
Seed/Startup
43%
21%
7%
14%
79%
Expansion
30%
10%
30%
10%
50%
Table 4.1: Common milestone targets set in milestone agreement.
Penalties
VC gets more Board Seats
VC gets money back
VC get other rights
Percentages
8%
8%
33%
Table 4.2: Common penalties for not meeting milestones.
Voting Rights
Generally, the preferred classes vote as though they were converted into
common stock. Antoinette Schoar, a MIT Entrepreneurial Finance professor
writes, on average the “VCs control votes in 57% of deals, whereas entrepreneurs
control votes in 23% of deals. Neither has control in 20% of the deals” (Schoar
2002).
Class Veto Rights
VCs almost always request some standard class veto rights to which they have
veto powers. The objective is to ensure that the VC now part owner of the
company is being consulted for major decisions. The right to veto generally
includes mergers and acquisitions, restructuring, issuing of new shares, changes
to the company charter, amendments which will alter the rights of preference
shares which the VC owns, annual business plans, profit distribution and
employee stock options, borrowing more than a certain amount, buying assets
more than a certain amount, sale of major assets, and sale of copyrights,
36
trademarks, or intellectual property. These provisions are a constant reminder to
the company that the venture capitalist is looking for an exit opportunity.
Dividend Provision
VCs can request a dividend provision where the company has to pay the VCs
annual dividends. The dividends can be either cumulative or non-cumulative.
Usually, the value to the dividends is predetermined. If the dividends are noncumulative, and if the company does not have the resources to pay the
dividends, which is determined by the board or some members of the board,
then nothing will be owed to the VC for that year (Campbell, 2003). On the other
hand, cumulative dividends accrue even if the company does not have the
resources to pay it. Preferred stock dividends usually have preference to
common stock dividends (Wilmerding, 2003). In other words, no dividends can
be paid out to common stock unless the preferred stock obligations are first paid.
As a result, dividends add to the face value of the preferred stock. Although it
does not make sense for a high growth startup to start paying large dividends, it
does allow the VC to extract some of its money if growth is not quite what was
expected. Another common non-cumulative dividend structure takes a
percentage of the common stock dividends in addition to its entitled preference
share dividends.
Table 4.3 shows that majority of term sheets do not yet require dividends. But of
those that do, most require cumulative dividends.
Fees
Fees are another way to extract value in periods of low volatility in the market. In
the research phase of this study, we have primarily seen four major kinds of fees.
First is the Deal Fee. The logic behind a deal fee is that the entrepreneur is
charged for time spent negotiating the deal. In our entire sample, this type was
37
almost exclusively seen in the UK. In our study, the average value for the deal
fee when it was charged was £30,000.
Entire Sample
Software &
Dot-com
Biotechnology
Life Science &
Pharmaceutical
Preferred Shares
Convertible
Preferred Shares
Participating
Convertible
Preferred
No Dividends
68 (59%)
Cumulative
30 (26%)
Non-Cumulative
17 (15%)
25 (76%)
6 (18%)
2 (6%)
14 (58%)
6 (25%)
4 (17%)
13 (76%)
3 (18%)
1 (6%)
39 (58%)
17 (25%)
11 (16%)
5 (56%)
3 (33%)
1 (11%)
6 (43%)
5 (36%)
3 (21%)
Table 4.3: Percentages of dividend types required by VCs according to our questionnaire.
Some VCs even charge an annual Management Fee for providing assistance to the
entrepreneur in addition to reimbursement of his expenses. Usually these fees
are structured so that they go up each year the company is in existence. In our
study, the average first year management fee for those that had management fees
was £32,500. Removing cash from a high growth company can seem counterintuitive but in periods of low volatility and weak markets, it can be a useful
method for extracting value from a company. Used in combination with
redemption fees, management fees are useful in minimizing the risk accrued by
the VC. In our study, management fees were mostly found in the UK and mostly
of a much greater amount in the UK than elsewhere. In our sample out of 11
deals in the United Kingdom, 6 had some form of annual fees.
38
During the negotiation process, legal fees are generated. The VC can make the
entrepreneur pay for these fees. These fees are negotiated to decide whether the
entrepreneur, the VC, or both will pay for them.
Legal Fees
Company Pays
Investor Pays
Split
84 (74%)
5 (4%)
24 (21%)
Table 4.4: Payer of legal fees.
During the due diligence process, due diligence fees are generated. Due diligence
fees are another set of fees which need to be negotiated. These fees can grow to a
large sum and a wise entrepreneur would structure a cap on them.
Company Pays
Investor Pays
Split
Entire Sample
40 (37%)
45 (41%)
24 (22%)
Startup
12 (38%)
10 (31%)
10 (31%)
Expansion
26 (47%)
19 (35%)
10 (18%)
Table 4.5: Payer of Due Diligence fees.
Lockup Provision
Lockup provisions specify how long after IPO can the VCs and the founders sell
their stocks. These points are negotiated with the Investment Banks who want to
ensure that the market is confident that the owners of the company are not in a
hurry to sell their stocks. Lockup provisions can be seen a good thing especially
for large investors. “In practice, founders and management would normally be
locked up for a year in Europe” (Campbell, 2003).
39
Lockup
Time
Entrepreneurs (USA)
7.2 months
Venture Capitalists (USA)
6.5 months
Entrepreneurs (Europe)
20.3 months
Venture Capitalists (Europe)
9.2 months
Table 4.6: Duration of lockup provisions for entrepreneurs and VCs in USA and Europe.
Founder Shares Vesting
VCs will usually require the founder to vest their shares. This means that the
founder has to give his shares to the company and the company will essentially
give the founder’s shares back to the founder over a period of time. This assures
the VCs that the founders will not leave the company after the VCs invest. The
structure of how the companies give their shares back varies quite a bit, so in our
survey we asked how long would does it take for the founder to get back all their
shares.
Criteria
USA
Average
Founder Median
Maximum
Vested Time
Founder Vested Founder Vested
Time
Time in Data
Sample
2.44 years
4
5
Europe
2.55 years
3
5
Table 4.7: Vesting time by location at Startup Stage.
Drag Along Provisions
Drag along provisions give the majority of the shareholders in a particular class
the right to sell the company and force the rest of the investors to sell under the
same conditions offered to them. They are designed to inhibit a situation where a
minority of shareholders holds a company hostage by refusing to sell. Our
40
survey indicates that the percentage of shareholders needed is increased in later
stages probably to account for the greater number of investors now involved.
Startup Phase
Drag Along Percentage 50.1%
Needed
Expansion Phase
60.3%
Table 4.8: Drag along percentages in the startup and expansion phases.
Tag Along Provisions
The tag along provision ensures that if the entrepreneur gets someone to buy his
shares, all the shareholders holding those rights can sell their shares to the same
shareholder under the same conditions offered to the entrepreneur in proportion
to their holdings. This clause is rarely negotiated and assures the VCs that the
entrepreneur is less likely to sell his shares and run off.
The provisions discussed above are concerned with control of the company. VCs
utilize these provisions to have greater control over the inner workings of the
company in which it has invested. VCs use their control to minimize the risk of
their investment by protecting against the failure of the company. Of course it
may not be in the best interest of the entrepreneur to relinquish control of the
company to the VC because often the goals of each are distinct or even in
contradiction to each other. Thus there is a conflict of interest between the VC
and the entrepreneur over control of the company.
41
V. Findings and Conclusion
Conflicts of interest between the venture capitalists (VCs) and entrepreneurs
exist in the areas of financial split of returns, liquidation, and the control of the
company. To address these conflicts of interest, the VC seeks provisions that
align the interests of the entrepreneur with those of the VC. This dissertation
finds that the variances in these provisions are in part due to the sector of the
company, the desperation of the CEO, the competition for the deal, and the stage
of the company.
This dissertation finds that the companies that received funding in the venture
capital world did so with little difficulty. It also finds that VC funding is easier to
find in the United States than in Europe probably due to the larger scale of the
United States market. Those entrepreneurs that did find VC funding reported
that funding was more easily found for the software sector than for other sectors.
This study suggests that different sectors have different average liquidation
multiples, although this is not conclusive due to a small sample size.
Furthermore, the average liquidation multiples for those companies with more
than one term sheet from different VCs are much lower than those companies
with only one term sheet. Companies which were offered only one term sheet
were also more likely to have participating convertible preference shares than
those with more than one term sheet.
The weighted anti-dilution clause is more than twice as popular as full ratchet.
Although after the bubble burst, VCs are now more likely to ask for full ratchets.
Of the contracts containing anti-dilution provisions, 37% had set a pay to play
provision.
42
The average employee stock option pool is 12.26%. This number is slightly
higher for higher rounds of financing. This validates the intuition that the
employee stock option pool needs to be increased with later round of financing.
Cumulative dividends are more popular than non-cumulative dividends;
although, 59% of all contracts did not have any dividend provision.
In our sample, deal and management annual fees are seen almost exclusively in
the UK. The average value for a deal fee is about £30,000. Management annual
fees are usually structured to go up in value as the company ages. The average
value for the first year annual fee was £32,500. Legal fees are more often paid by
the company. Due Diligence fees can be paid by the company (37%) 41% 22%
There are many areas for future research on this topic. For instance, there are
other factors affecting variation in the value of deal structures besides those
analyzed in this study. Among these factors are emotional climate of the
investing community, the management team, the integrity of the VC firm, the
philosophy of the fund, the stage of the fund, and the personal view of the
investor. There are a multitude of factors which contribute to the variation in
terms sheets, those discussed in this study were limited by the constraints of the
dataset used; however, they do possess a strong influence over the structure of
deal terms. Term sheet are greatly varied, though we believe that there are
trends in their variation and that these trends are the result of the above named
factors. Future research on this topic should aim at getting the term sheets
themselves rather than interview management of the companies. Other research
topics include the “option”ality of term sheets. The findings of this study are
encouraging and future research on this topic is greatly needed as there is a
dearth of knowledge on terms sheet structuring in the venture capital world.
43
Work Cited
“The Arithmetic Of Deals”. Demmler, Frank. (reprint from Techvest).
http://www.andrew.cmu.edu/user/fd0n/articles.htm
Bagley, Constance E & Dauchy, Craig E. The Entrepreneur’s guide to business
law (2nd Edition). 2003. Thompson South-Western West.
“Building Your Board: A corporate governance guide for entrepreneurs”.
Telecommunications Development Fund. 2002.
“Bury the Ratchet”. Blaydon, Colin & Horvath, Michael. Venture Capital Journal.
Jan 2002.
Campbell, Katharine. Smarter Ventures: A survivor’s guide to venture capital
through the new cycle. 2003. Prentice Hall.
“East vs. West: Observations for the trenches”. Papier, David & Boyajian, Victor.
New Jersey Tech News. March 2003. Volume 7 . Issue 2.
Gladstone, David & Gladstone, Laura. Venture Capital Handbook: an
entrepreneur’s guide to raising venture capital. 2002. Prentice Hall.
Mullins, John W. The New Business Road Test. 2003. Prentice Hall
“Pay-to-play provisions - traps for the unwary”. Kimball, Richard. Alternative
Assets Network. http://www.altassets.com/casefor/countries/2002/nz2908.php .
2002
“Recent Developments in Venture Capital Terms, The Fenwick & West Survey”.
Kramer, Barry & Patrick, Michael. Venture Capital Review. Issue 12. Summer
2003.
Smith, Janet & Smith, Richard. Entrepreneurial Finance (2nd Edition). 2004. Wiley
& Sons.
“Trends in Deal Terms of Venture Financing”. Fenwick and West. 2005.
http://www.fenwick.com/vctrends.htm .
“Venture Capital on the Downside: Preferred Stock and Corporate Control”.
Bratton, William. Michigan Law Review. Volume 100, issue 5. March 2002.
44
Wilmerding, Alex. Deal Terms, The finer Points of Venture Capital Deal
Structures, Valuations, Term Sheets, Stock Options, and Getting Deals Done.
2003. Aspatore Inc.
Wilmerding, Alex. Term Sheets and Valuations: A line by line look at the
intricacies of term sheets & valuations. 2005. Aspatore Inc.
45
Appendix A: Effects of VC Investment on Allocations of Equity
Assumptions:
1) Pre-Money Valuation
=
2) Round 1 Venture Capital needed =
3) Round 2 Venture Capital needed =
4) Stock Price offered by Round 1 VC =
5) Stock Price offered by Round 2 VC =
6) Employee Stock Option Pool(ESOP) =
(% of Founder & VC shares)
£2M
£5M
£1.5M
£1.25
£3.00
7.14%
ROUND 1:
Founding Team # of shares: (£2M/£1.25) = 1.6M shares
Value of Founder shares: (1.6M * £1.25) = £2M
VC 1 # of shares: (£5M/£1.25) = 4M shares
Value of VC 1 shares: (4M*£1.25) = 5M shares
Subtotal # of shares: (1.6M + 4M) = 5.6M shares
ESOP # of shares: (7.14% * 5.6M) = 0.4M shares
Post-Money # of shares: (5.6M + 0.4M) = 6M shares
Post-Money Value: (6M*£1.25) = £7.5M
Founder Percentage of Equity(w/o options): (1.6M/5.6M) = 28.57%
VCs 1 Percentage of Equity(w/o options): (4M/5.6M) = 71.43%
Founder Percentage of Equity (with options): (1.6M/6M) = 26.67%
VCs 1 Percentage of Equity(with options): (4M/6M) = 66.67%
Employee Percentage of Equity: (0.4M/6M) = 6.67%
ROUND 2:
Founding Team # of shares: (from round 1) = 1.6M shares
Value of Founder shares: (1.6M*3.00)= £4.8M
VC 1 # of shares: (from round 1) = 4M shares
Value of VC 1 shares: (4M*£3.00) = £12M
VC 2 # of shares: (£1.5M/£3.00) = 0.5M shares
Value of VC 2 shares: (0.5*3)= £1.5M
Subtotal # of shares: (1.6M + 4M) = 6.1M shares
ESOP # of shares: (from round 1) = 0.4M shares
Post-Money # of shares: (6.1M + 0.4M) = 6.5M shares
Value of Post-Money: (6.5M*£3.00) = £19.5M
46
Founder Percentage of Equity(w/o options): (1.6M/6.1M) = 26.23%
VC 1 Percentage of Equity(w/o options): (4M/6.1M) = 65.57%
VC 2 Percentage of Equity(w/o options): (0.5M/6.1M) = 8.20%
Founder Percentage of Equity (with options): (1.6M/6.5M) = 24.62%
VC 1 Percentage of Equity(with options): (4M/6.5M) = 61.54%
VC 2 Percentage of Equity(with options): (0.5M/6.5M) = 7.69%
Employee Percentage of Equity: (0.4M/6.5M) = 6.15%
EXIT:
Assume Market Capitalization in Year 5: £100M
IRR Calculations
Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4
VC 1
VC 2
-£5M
Year 5
0
0
0
0
61.54%*£100= £61.54M
-£1.5M
0
0
0
7.69%*£100= £7.69M
VC 1 Return Multiple: (£61.54M/£5M) = 12.308
IRR = 65%
VC 2 Return Multiple: (£7.69M/£1.5M) = 5.127
IRR = 50%
47
Appendix B: Online Questionnaire
Section 1/3: Company Background
1)
2)
3)
4)
5)
6)
7)
8)
First Name:
Last Name:
Electronic Address:
Company Name:
Title/Position:
Contact Number:
Investment Location(*):
Company Industry Sector(*):
- Dot-com
- Electronics-Semiconductors
- Software
- Media
- Nanotechnology
- Pharmaceutical
- Real Estate
- Communications
- Biotechnology
- Energy
- Chemical
- Industrial Products
- Automation
- Financial Services
- Transportation
- Communication
- Leisure
- Life Science
- Other Engineering
- Other
9) Amount of years your company has been incorporated(*):
10) Total Rounds of Venture Capital / Private Equity financing received so far(*):
11) Stage of Investment in Most recent round of financing(*):
- Seed
- Start up
- Expansion
- Bridge
- Rescue or turnaround
- Management Buy-Out (MBO)
- Management But-In (MBI)
- Mezzanine
- Public to Private
- IPO
- Roll out
48
Section 2/3: ALL the questions in this survey are about the last round of financing with
the VC.
1) When did your company get the financing for the most recent round? Please
specify in (year/quartet) format (*): year____, quartet_____.
2) Type of investors(*):
-
Venture Capital
Incubators
Corporate VC Investors
Others
Do not know
3) Last Round Series(*):
-
Series A
Series B
Series C
Series D
Series E
Series F
Series G
Series H
Series I
Even Later Financing Round
Do not know
4) Difficulty in raising funds in round(*):
-
not difficult at all
somewhat difficult
moderately difficult
very difficult
extremely difficult
do not know
refused
5) Time taken to negotiate and close deal after first contact with financer in this last
round(*):
-
1 month
2 months
49
-
3 months
4 months
5 months
6 months
7 months
8 months
9 months
10 months
11 months
1 year
1.5 years
2 years and over
Do not know
6) About how many potential investors did you approach for financing this last
round? (*):
7) How many term sheets from different investors did you receive for this last round
of financing? (*):
8) What was the exit strategy at this last round of financing? (*):
-
IPO as market leader
IPO as number two in segment
Sale to a vale chain partner – acquisition
Acquisition by established player entering segment
Others
Do not know
9) How much money was raised in this last round of financing (Optional): ______
($/€/ Euro).
10) Pre-Money Valuation (Optional): _______($/€/Euro).
11) Please state the type of shares issued(*):
-
Ordinary Shares
Preferred Shares
Convertible Preferred Shares
Participating Convertible Preferred
Others
Do not know
Liquidation Preference
12) State the liquidation preference granted to preferred stock(*):
Please select one of the below options
•
[] Don’t Know
50
•
•
•
[] No liquidation preference above common stock
[] Return entire investment before anything is returned [] to
common stock holder
[] Return a multiple of entire investment before anything is
returned to common stockholder
12a) if multiple, what was the multiple ?
_________X original investment.
Warrants Clause
13) Were warrants required to be issue by the company to the Investor this last
round(*) : (Yes/No/ Don’t know)
13a) If warrants were issued, at what value?:
14) Dividends
Were there any dividends owed to the Preferred Stock? (*):
-
Yes - Cumulative Dividends
Yes – Non Cumulative Dividends
No Dividends
Do not know
Section 3/3: The following questions are regarding the last round of financing round
with the VC.
Milestone Clauses
14a) Were there any milestone clauses which upon completion granted more money? (*):
( Yes/No/ Don’t know)
If yes, please select the objective of mile stone
-
Develop prototype
Find a large customer
Sales target
Profit target
Get additional funding elsewhere
Other milestones
51
-
Do not know
14b) Were there any sort of bridge loans given to achieve the first milestone before the
investor invested? (*): (Yes/No/ Don’t know)
14c) If the milestones were not met, were there any penalties?
-
No penalties
Investor gets more rights
Investor gets his money back
Investor gets more board seats
Investor gets some of his money back
Do not know
Redemption Provision
15) Was there any sort of redemption clause which required a return of investment to
investor in X years if no exit opportunity was generated? (*):
- No
- Yes, it required the return of entire investment
- Yes, it required the return of a multiple of investment
-Yes, it required the return of some of investment
- Do not know
15a) If yes, after how much time did the redemption clause first start to kick in?
__________ years
15b) If yes, what penalties did the redemption clause have?
-
Pay unpaid dividends
Pay back initial investment
Pay back multiple of initial investment
Appoint committee to look for exit opportunities
Investors get more members on board
Preferred stock holder gets more rights
Employee Stock Option
16) Was there an employee stock option plan for the company in this round? (*):
(Yes/No/ Don’t know)
52
16a) If yes, what percentage of the company's total shares were issued as
employee stock options after this round of financing ? (Not including founder
shares)
___________ %
16b) If yes, over what period will the shares be vested?
_______ years.
17) Was there Anti-Dilution Clause? (*):
- Yes - Full Ratchet
- Yes -Weighted Average Anti-Dilution
- Yes- Others
- Yes – Do not know which kind
- No
- Do not know
18) Was there a Pay to Play clause which required the investor to invest in subsequent
rounds to keep their Preferred Stock privileges? (*): (Yes/ No/ Don’t know)
If yes, which privileges did they lose?
-
All Preferred Stock converted to common
Lose board seats
Lose anti-dilution provision
Lose future investment rights
Lose other rights
Do Not Know
19) How long was it before your founder shares completely vested?
________years.
20) Was there a Drag Along clause which let shareholders who have a certain percentage
have a right to force a liquidation event? (*): (Yes/No/Don’t know)
If yes, what was the percentage?
_________ %.
53
Buy Sell Agreement
21) Was there a Buy Sell Agreement between an investor and founders which let
shareholder X force shareholder Y to sell their share at a price chosen by the party X but
only by first giving the option to shareholder Y to buy the shares at the same price? (*):
(Yes/No/Don’t know)
Lock-up Period
22) Was there a Lock-up provision where after IPO, you or the investor were not allowed
to sell your shares for a certain amount of time (*)? (Yes/No/Don’t know)
Lock-up Period for Management / Entrepreneurs
_______ months.
Lock-up Period for Investors
_______ months.
23) Board Representation
_____ Number of board members from investor's side
_____ Number of observers on board from investor's side
_____ Number of board members from management/entrepreneur's side
_____ Number of observers from management/entrepreneur's side
_____ Number of independent board members
_____ Number of other board members
_____ Average number of board meetings per year
Fees
24a) Who paid the due diligence fees ? (*):
-
Investor
Company
Split Between Investor and Company
Do not know
24b) Who paid the legal fees? (*):
-
Investor
54
-
Company
Split Between Investor and Company
Do not know
24c) Was there any Deal Fee charged by investor for signing the deal? (*):
(Yes/No/Don’t know)
If yes, what was the amount?
______________.
24d) Was there an Annual Fee for the "services" provided by the investor? (*):
(Yes/No/Don’t know)
If yes, what was the average amount?
______________.
24e) Was there any Performance Fee charged which was a percentage of sales or profit?
(*): (Yes/No/Don’t know)
If yes, what was the maximum percentage amount?
_________ %.
25) Survival
Would the company have existed in 1 year if funds had not been raised? (*):
(Yes/No/ Don’t know)
26) Syndicate of Investors
Was there more than one investor that invested this round? (*) : (Yes/No/
Don’t know)
55