Report to the Department of Health
National Evaluation of Payment by
Results
November 2007
Shelley Farrar1, Jon Sussex2, Deokhee Yi1, Matt Sutton1, Martin
Chalkley3, Tony Scott4, Ada Ma1
1. Health Economics Research Unit, University of Aberdeen
2. Office of Health Economics, London
3. Department of Economic Studies, University of Dundee
4. University of Melbourne
Contents Page
Contents Page.................................................................................................................2
Acknowledgement .........................................................................................................4
Chapter 1. Short report...................................................................................................5
1.1
Introduction.....................................................................................................5
1.2
The Payment by Results Policy ......................................................................7
1.3
The link between Payment by Results and outcomes – theoretical
considerations ...............................................................................................11
1.4
Qualitative analysis of Payment by Results..................................................14
1.5
Quantitative analysis of Payment by Results................................................16
1.6
Conclusion ....................................................................................................22
Chapter 2. Payment by Results Policy........................................................................24
2.1
Hospital financing prior to PbR ....................................................................24
2.2
The details of PbR.........................................................................................25
2.3
The broader context of reform ......................................................................28
2.4
A Comparator – Hospital Financing in Scotland..........................................32
2.5
Objectives of PbR .........................................................................................33
Chapter 3. The link between Payment by Results and outcomes – theoretical
considerations ..............................................................................................................36
3.1
Background ...................................................................................................36
3.2
Three aspects of PbR ....................................................................................38
3.3
The Basic Theoretical Framework - Quality and Cost of Care ....................40
3.4
The impact of cost sensitivity .......................................................................41
3.5
The impact of volume sensitivity..................................................................44
3.5.1
A model of volume choice in the presence of constraints ...................45
3.6
Implications of increasing case-mix dependence .........................................53
3.7
Summary - linking theory to qualitative and quantitative evaluations .........54
Chapter 4. Qualitative analysis of Payment by Results ...............................................57
4.1
Objectives .....................................................................................................57
4.2
Methods.........................................................................................................58
4.2.1
1st round of interviews .........................................................................59
4.2.2
2nd round of interviews.........................................................................60
4.2.3
3rd round of interviews .........................................................................60
4.3
Understanding the process of PbR................................................................61
4.3.1
Overview of PbR policy.......................................................................61
4.3.2
Incentives and Disincentives................................................................67
4.3.3
Competition..........................................................................................70
4.4
Perceptions implementation and the outcomes of PbR.................................73
4.4.1
Cost Efficiency.....................................................................................74
4.4.2
Activity and volumes ...........................................................................74
4.4.3
Quality of care......................................................................................75
Chapter 5. Quantitative analysis of Payment by Results .............................................77
5.1
Objectives .....................................................................................................77
5.2
International experience................................................................................77
5.3
Key outcome measures .................................................................................80
5.3.1
Unit cost, length of stay (LOS) and incidence of day cases and
outpatient measures of efficiency ........................................................81
5.3.2
Volume of care.....................................................................................81
2
5.3.3
5.4
5.5
5.6
5.7
5.7.1
5.7.2
5.7.3
5.7.4
5.7.5
5.8
5.8.1
5.8.2
5.8.3
5.8.4
Quality of care......................................................................................82
Method ..........................................................................................................83
Econometric analysis ....................................................................................85
Results...........................................................................................................86
Impact on unit costs ......................................................................................87
Length of Stay: general trends .............................................................87
Length of stay: difference in differences analysis ...............................89
Day case rates: trends...........................................................................93
Day case rates: difference in differences analysis ...............................94
Summary of effects on unit costs.........................................................96
Effects on volume and pattern of care ..........................................................99
Volume of output: general trends ........................................................99
Volume of output: difference-in-difference analyses ........................100
Non-elective admissions: general trends ...........................................104
Impact on non-elective admissions: difference-in-difference
analyses ..............................................................................................105
5.8.5
Summary of effects on volume and pattern of care ...........................107
5.9
Effects on the Quality of Care ....................................................................110
5.9.1
Hospital mortality: general trends......................................................110
5.9.2
Hospital mortality: difference-in-difference analyses .......................112
5.9.3
30-day mortality: general trends ........................................................116
5.9.4
30-day surgical mortality: difference-in-difference analyses ............117
5.9.5
Emergency re-admission following hip fracture: general trends.......120
5.9.6
Emergency readmission following treatment for hip fracture:
difference-in-difference analyses.......................................................121
5.9.7
Hospital level measures of quality of care.........................................123
5.9.8
Summary of effects on quality...........................................................123
5.10
Outpatients ..................................................................................................125
5.11
Specific HRG investigations.......................................................................126
5.11.1
Primary hip replacement ....................................................................126
5.11.2
Maternity care ....................................................................................129
5.11.3
Treatment for head injury ..................................................................134
5.11.4
Cardiology and general medicine outpatients....................................136
5.11.5
Summary of results on up-coding .....................................................137
References..................................................................................................................138
Appendices are available in a separate document
Appendix A - Data Management
Appendix B - Econometric Methods
Appendix C - Detailed Results
Appendix D - Exclusions from the Tariff
Appendix E - Qualitative Analysis and Interview Schedules
3
Acknowledgement
The research reported here is funded by a research grant from the Department of
Health, England. The Health Economics Research Unit is supported by the Chief
Scientist Office of the Scottish Government Health Directorates. The views expressed
here are the responsibility of the authors alone.
We would like to thank the members of our project advisory group for their helpful
guidance and comments throughout the project, to staff at Northgate in England and
David Bailey and Mary-Jane Anderson at ISD Scotland for providing the quantitative
data. We would like to thank Peter Yuen (formally Office of Health Economics) for
advice on HES data. We also extend thanks to the NHS managers who participated in
the interviews and to Heather Mackintosh, project secretary, for her efforts to secure
and arrange those interviews.
4
Chapter 1. Short report
1.1
Introduction
In April 2002 the Department of Health (DH) in England outlined its plans to
introduce a new system of financing hospitals called ‘Payment by Results’ (PbR). The
new payment system uses a nationally fixed case-mix based tariff, which reimburses
hospitals for the amount and type of care they provide. The introduction of PbR
marks a fundamental change in the way in which hospitals in England are financed. It
was motivated by a desire to effect changes in the decision making processes and
ultimately the outcomes of decisions in respect of the efficiency, volume of activity
and appropriateness / quality of care in English NHS hospitals.
This report provides details of an evaluation of the process and effects of the
introduction of PbR. The analysis that we report covers the period from 2002/3 to
2005/6.
Key objectives for this study were agreed with the DH. These were to:
a) Examine the process of policy implementation
b) Examine the impact of the policy on a number of key outcomes.
We present our report in two parts; in this chapter we provide a short version of our
report, whilst chapters 2, 3, 4 and 5 provide the details of the analysis that was
undertaken and provide the evidence in support of our findings.
We approached our task in a structured manner that is reflected in the ordering of
material in this report.
We started by gathering information on the nature of the PbR policy, the timing of its
introduction and the system that it was replacing. This material is presented in Section
1.2 of this chapter and Chapter 2. Also in those sections we briefly describe the
financing system for NHS hospitals in Scotland because our subsequent quantitative
analysis relies on making comparisons which enable us to isolate the impact of the
changing payment system from the many other changes impacting on hospitals – the
5
Scottish NHS provides a powerful comparator for that purpose. PbR was introduced
with the intention of achieving a broad range of objectives relating to hospital and
health care system performance; we also identify these in Section 1.2 and Chapter 2.
A conceptual framework is necessary in order to understand how changing the
payment system can impact upon decisions and outcomes and whether it can be
expected to achieve its objectives. For this purpose we used, and subsequently
developed, an economic framework which considers the incentives for decision
makers when faced with different financing systems. This is the material set out in
Section 1.3 and Chapter 3. Contract theory, as this branch of economics is referred to,
is very extensive and our purpose in this phase of the analysis was not to attempt to
review the literature but rather to distil its key conclusions as they might apply to PbR.
However in one important regard – the link between the PbR system and incentives to
expand activity – we could not find any strictly relevant economic models and so
developed a simple extension of an existing model in order to better understand the
issue.
The empirical phase of our research is described in two sections and chapters.
In Section 1.4 and Chapter 4 we present the details and findings of interviews that
were conducted with decision makers in the NHS. This part of our research has two
key objectives. First, because we accept that our economic framework can only be
valid if the circumstances it seeks to analyse come into existence and if the
preconditions or assumptions upon which it is based are valid, our qualitative analysis
was used to assess these preconditions. Second, the qualitative analysis provides
insight into whether there are features of the PbR system that we have failed to
incorporate into our analysis that are nevertheless relevant to decision makers.
The longest and most substantial part of the evaluation is a quantitative / econometric
analysis of the linkages between the introduction of PbR and observable changes in
key aspects of performance of the hospital care system, specifically efficiency (cost
per treatment), volume of activity and appropriateness / quality of care. This is
contained in Section 1.5 and Chapter 5. Ultimately evaluation rests upon establishing
whether or not PbR achieved what it set out to achieve and in this section (chapter) we
6
focus on the observable aspects, or analogues of, those goals. Our quantitative
analysis is substantial both because it is central to evaluation and because the issues
involved in attempting to isolate the impact of policy from the myriad of other
influences on performance are extremely complex. We have approached this
empirically by (i) developing a unique data resource, constructed using the large and
growing administrative data sets being generated by the NHS and (ii) applying
multiple difference in difference methodology in order to infer the impact of PbR on
the key outcomes. We believe that the tools that we have developed will be of value
to the DH and other researchers concerned with the operation of the NHS beyond
their application to our evaluation.
Section 1.6 of the short report does not have a supporting chapter as it is concerned
simply with summarising the results of our evaluation as a whole.
1.2
The Payment by Results Policy
Under PbR hospitals are paid according to the number and type of patients that they
treat through a system in which prices are determined in advance. In common with
many other health care systems PbR ensures that the provision of hospital services is
financed using a mechanism that makes a direct link between volume and case-mix of
output and hospital income (Sussex and Street, 2005).
Prior to PbR a range of purchasing arrangements were used in the English NHS.
These were called, variously, block contracts, sophisticated block contracts, cost and
volume contracts and cost per case contracts. These contracts specify in one form or
another, a payment for a broad range of health services and treatments. The more
commonly used ‘sophisticated’ block contract, introduced pre-defined maximum and
minimum levels of provision. Output levels outside of these targets triggered
predefined actions; these could be renegotiations or data validation procedures
(Raftery et al, 1996).
Under PbR, prices are defined in terms of Healthcare Resource Group (HRG) spells
of stay in hospital. A spell of activity is a hospital stay from admission to discharge
and is a measure of hospital output. A spell might cover one or more episodes. An
7
HRG code is assigned to each spell of activity and where that spell consists of
multiple episodes, the dominant episode determines the HRG code. There were 550
tariffed HRGs for admitted care under the HRG Version 3.5 (DH, 2003a, 2003b,
2003c, 2004a).
There are various characteristics of the tariff system which are pertinent to our study
and which shape the incentives of the system. The payment the hospitals receives for
providing an HRG spell is determined by whether that spell is pre-planned (elective)
or not (non-elective) and reflects the difference in costs associated with the two types
of patients (DH, 2004b). A single tariff exists to reimburse trusts for each HRG for
daycase and inpatient elective care (DH, 2002a). Tariffs have also been introduced to
reimburse hospitals for the provision of outpatient services. The tariff for these is
defined by speciality and, in the main, is paid per attendance (DH 2005). In 2005/06,
an attendance-based tariff (for three categories of patient) was also introduced for
accident and emergency care (DH, 2004c).
There are a number of key steps in the construction of the tariff. Reference costs are
used to calculate the national average cost. These are then adjusted equally for all
providers in various ways to reflect changes in costs over time associated with
inflation, technology and efficiency improvements. In addition some tariffs are
adjusted to take into account National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence
guidelines. At a separate stage in the reimbursement process the tariff is then adjusted
using the Market Forces Factor (MFF) to give a local price for each Trust reflecting
unavoidable local differences in costs (DH, 2004b).
PbR has been introduced in a phased fashion. It was first applied to marginal changes
in output for 15 HRGs in 2003/4 (DH, 2002a) and extended to a further 33 HRGs in
2004/5 (DH, 2004b, Appendix 7). The tariff was used to commission activity growth
above the baseline of Service Level Agreements. For Trusts which did not deliver the
agreed level of elective activity, funds were withdrawn at the rate of the tariff. The 15
and 33 HRGs are listed in Table 1 of Appendix G. For a subset of NHS Trusts,
8
Foundation Trusts (FTs), it was applied to most inpatient (with some exceptions1),
day case and outpatient output (again with exceptions) in 2004/5. For the remaining
Trusts, it was applied to most elective admissions in 2005/6 (again with exceptions)
and then to outpatients in 2006/07 (DH, 2004c).
Transitional arrangements for the tariff have been implemented which offer Trusts
some protection from the financial penalties of having costs above tariff. Further
refinements and development of PbR, beyond the scope and timetable of this project,
and
details
of
the
tariffs
are
published
on
the
DH
website
at
http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Policyandguidance/Organisationpolicy/Financeandplanning/
NHSFinancialReforms/index.htm.
PbR represents one component of the modernisation and reform programme
announced in the NHS Plan (DH, 2000a). These other reform instruments have been
introduced throughout the period covered by this study and have the potential to
interact with PbR and affect its impact. The main changes in health care policy
applying in the period from 2002/03 onwards which might be expected to affect the
results of our analyses are:
•
Shorter waiting times targets;
•
introduction of an active policy of patient choice of provider for elective
hospital care;
•
creation of ‘Foundation Trusts’ with some devolved powers not available to
other NHS Trusts;
•
greater support of independent sector provision of hospital services to NHS
patients and;
•
introduction of practice based commissioning, i.e. giving all primary care
practices indicative budgets from which to buy health care for their registered
patients.
1
Some HRGs are excluded from tariff on the basis that they were low volume, had volatile costs and/or
were of a specialised nature. These are listed in Table 2 of Appendix D.
9
Because part of our analysis draws on a comparison of quantitative data in England
and Scotland, we identify important differences and similarities between the structure
and policy context of the NHS in England and the NHS in Scotland.
Patient choice, Foundation Trusts and Practice based Commissioning have not been
adopted in Scotland. Since devolution the Scottish Government has placed greater
emphasis on central planning. Although, like England, Scotland had used waiting
time targets to stimulate improved performance, generally, the regime in Scotland is
considered to be less ‘aggressive’ (Propper et al, 2007). In 2005/06 a national tariff
was introduced in Scotland but during the period of our study was essentially a
shadow system which did not affect the flow of funds (Scottish Executive Health
Department, 2005). As a result we are able to treat the funding of NHS Boards as
unchanged during our period of study.
Although it is possible to identify considerable differences in the details of the health
policy of the two countries, on an international setting, given the possibilities in health
care system design, there are considerable similarities between the Scottish and
English health care systems. The two countries have essentially shared the same
financing mechanisms and broad policy developments until The Scotland Act 1998.
Both systems are predominantly funded through general taxation and provide services
free at the point of consumption. They each use family doctors as gatekeepers to
secondary care services. They also have the same nationally agreed (UK) contracts for
consultants, nurses and GPs.
In a natural experiment the ideal control would be similar in all ways to the group
subject to policy change. Such situations are rare in public policy. However, the NHS
in Scotland does provide a structure similar to English NHS and importantly one
which has been relatively stable in its financing of hospitals at the time of the
implementation of PbR. As a result, we consider the NHS in Scotland to provide a
useful control in our analysis.
The key document introducing PbR policy was ‘Reforming NHS Financial Flows’
(Department of Health, 2002a). This document identified three main reasons for
introducing a standard price tariff (Page 13):
10
•
To ‘enable PCT commissioners to focus on the quality and volume of services
provided’
•
To ‘incentivise NHS Trusts to manage costs efficiently’.
•
To ‘create greater transparency and planning certainty in the system.’
These objectives suggest linkages between the adoption of PbR, change in the
behaviour of decision-makers and subsequent changes in the performance of the NHS
hospital system. The remainder of our evaluation is based upon exploring the nature
of these linkages. We do so first using the tools and concepts of economic theory
(Chapter 3) summarised in Section 1.3 and then empirically using both qualitative
(Chapter 4) and quantitative (Chapter 5) methods summarised in Sections 1.4 and 1.5,
respectively.
1.3
The link between Payment by Results and outcomes – theoretical
considerations
The economic analysis of the impact of payments systems on outcomes rests upon
what is called contract theory. In contract theory the concern is to determine how
particular payment mechanisms affect incentives which are required whenever the
purchaser cannot specify exactly the actions of the supplier. These kinds of incentive
issues pervade health care in respect of cost and quality of health care.
It is useful to characterise PbR as impacting upon three aspects of payment – the
extent to which that payment responds to or is sensitive to variations in cost, volume
and case-mix.
Relative to the financing arrangements in place prior to its adoption, PbR reduces the
extent to which hospitals can utilise their own cost circumstances to negotiate for
higher payment – either in the current period or in the future. This feature of fixed
price payment systems for health care has been very extensively discussed in the
contract theory literature. The argument that is made is that reduced cost sensitivity
gives rise to increased incentives to control costs.
11
Since one driver of costs is the quality of care delivered there has been a great deal of
attention given to the possibility that fixed price payment systems might compromise
quality of care. The implications are that PbR might be expected to reduce unit costs
but may compromise quality of care. There are a large number of refinements of this
argument and these are set out in detail in Chapter 3 but the central point is a fairly
robust one – reduced cost sensitivity of payments gives rise to incentives to reduce
costs.
The relationship between cost and efficiency needs, however, to be treated with care.
If unit costs could be observed and were to fall this might be either because of
efficiency savings or because or reductions in service quality. With that caveat, the
objective that DH set for PbR “To incentivise NHS Trusts to manage costs
efficiently” finds support from the economic theory of contracting.
PbR makes an explicit link between the number of patients treated and the payment to
a hospital whereas existing arrangements left this link poorly defined. Therefore, it is
reasonable to treat PbR as a more volume sensitive payment system. In various places
this it indicated as providing an incentive to increase volumes (i.e. the number of
treatments).
The logic of this seems clear: making an explicit payment for additional treatments
adds to the value of providing more of those treatments as far as the decision maker is
concerned. However, we find that when we examine this idea in the light of formal
(but simple) economic models of incentives it is less clear cut. The intuition is that a
rational decision maker needs to take into account both benefit (the payment) and cost
and it is the margin of benefit over cost that provides the incentive.
In a complex health care setting where there are capacity constraints, where some
forms of treatment are in excess demand and others are not and where the allocation
of costs across different treatments is unclear the impact of PbR on this margin will
vary across HRGs. Some may well be incentivised from the perspective of increased
treatment but other may exhibit the opposite incentive – a desire to reduce treatment
in one HRG in order to focus on another more remunerative one. Thus we do not find
12
that the theory supports a view that PbR will necessarily incentivise greater volume.
The details are again set out in Chapter 3.
Pre-PbR contracts tended to group together large numbers of services – or in the new
terminology they lumped together HRGs. In separating out HRGs for individual
payment, PbR allows for a greater sensitivity of payment to the precise mix of
patients that a hospital treats. There are two lessons in respect of case-mix sensitivity
from the economics framework that we have considered; one simple and one more
complex. In simple terms separating out different types of patients for different
treatments allows payments (prices) to be more closely aligned with the requirements
of treatment and thus obviates the need to build a payment cushion into a hospital’s
finances. Against this benefit the complexity, and thus one presumes cost, of
administering the payment system is increased.
More complex, are issues that arise when, as in any real world case-mix sensitive
system, hospitals have discretion over which HRG a patient might be allocated to.
The issue here is that separated payments may give rise to incentives to distort the
allocation of patients to different payment categories. These kinds of effects are
sometimes referred to generically as ‘gaming’2. The economic theory as to how to
optimally structure payment in such circumstances is complex but it suggests that it
may be important as PbR continues to develop to monitor the allocation of patients to
HRGs.
The theoretical framework thus provides a means of establishing the nature of the
expected linkages between the change to PbR and resulting behaviour of decision
makers and outcomes. Our analysis suggests that in terms of observable outcomes we
should examine:
2
•
the effect of PbR on the unit costs of treatment,
•
the effect on the quality of care and
•
the effect on volumes of treatments.
This refers to just one type of gaming behaviour, other types are possible.
13
These examinations constitute the substance of our quantitative analysis.
Our framework, as with any economic analysis, rests upon a number of assumptions
or pre-conditions. Most importantly, the PbR system needs to be implemented as
assumed and decision makers need to have an understanding of and the means to
respond to the incentives that we presume it to entail. These issues are examined as a
part of our qualitative analysis.
1.4
Qualitative analysis of Payment by Results
In the previous section the economic rationale for the linkages between PbR policy
and the expected outcomes with respect to NHS hospital performance was set out.
These linkages will work best when pre-conditions are met. Crucially the policy
should be implemented as intended and decision-makers should understand and be
able to respond to the incentives. Through a series of semi-structured interviews we
explored issues relating to the implementation of PbR and the perception and
experiences of decision-makers.
The qualitative analysis complements the quantitative analysis and has four
objectives:
1. To develop an understanding of how the PbR policy is perceived in the NHS
and whether those perceptions align with the assumptions of the theoretical
analysis,
2. To assess how PbR is being implemented in practice and whether it generates
the kinds of incentives that are suggested by the theoretical framework.
3. To identify perceived drivers of (and obstacles to) implementation, by drawing
on the experiences of key stakeholders in the implementation and application
of PbR policy.
4. To inform further development of the theoretical analysis of PbR and to
support and aid the interpretation of the quantitative analysis.
Data for the qualitative analysis were collected in three rounds of semi-structured
interviews with key stakeholders in the NHS. During the preparation stage of each
round of interviews, the scope of the questions and the categories of interviewees,
14
were agreed with the DH steering group for the project. Some of the same subject
areas are examined in more than one round but each round had a different emphasis
reflecting the embedding of the PbR in the NHS and the emerging findings in the
quantitative empirical work. The first round of interviews focussed on objectives (1)
and (2), the second on objectives (2) and (3), and the third round of interviews
focussed on objectives (1) and (4).
We endeavoured to elicit a range of views and experiences by targeting our
interviewees from organisations operating in different types of local conditions and
with different characteristics. For instance, we sought interviews with decisionmakers from organisations in rural and urban areas, from organisations providing
tertiary and secondary care and from organisations with different financial positions.
The material from the interviews suggests that the interviewees had a good
understanding of how PbR was intended to operate and the intended incentives with
respect to efficiency, volume and quality of care. However, there was some
scepticism as to whether the mechanism of PbR would act in the way intended by the
policy makers. Some of this related to the technical aspects of PbR such as the
credibility of the tariff in terms of how well it reflects average costs, how well or
otherwise HRGs capture the outputs of the hospitals, their lack of knowledge of their
own organisations cost structures and whether the PbR system, and specifically the
tariffs, will remain stable. Such scepticism was suggested as resulting in a reluctance
to change their existing pattern of service provision in response to the incentives
whilst there existed uncertainty about the sustainability of changes and the robustness
of the information used to inform changes.
In addition, issues of NHS culture and behavioural norms were raised by the
interviewees, as affecting their responses to the incentives of the new system. For
instance, a number of interviewees would not pursue greater revenues through
increased supply if this was an action considered detrimental to the financial status of
the commissioner and the local health economy as a whole.
We examine here how the interviewees considered their response to PbR would be in
terms of the specific objectives outlined in the policy documentation.
15
On the basis of the responses of those interviewees, it might be expected that PbR
would have added little further incentive to increase efficiency above those influences
that already existed: principally the elective waiting time targets – mentioned
frequently by interviewees – and the penalties for failure to achieve financial breakeven.
We asked interviewees in all three rounds of qualitative analysis about their
perceptions of whether and how PbR was affecting the volume of activity undertaken
in their local health economies. Most respondents identified increases in activity but
were inclined to attribute this to continuations of past trends and to the pressure to
reduce waiting times for elective care. They cited lack of demand and capacity as
constraints on their ability to increase volume.
From early interviews it was feared PbR might damage patient quality, or at least
deter improvements, in some places because of the need to keep costs below the
nationally fixed tariff level. One interviewee feared that because the PbR tariff is
based on national average costs it would produce “average quality services”. Others
expected no impact on quality. This last view was generally retained into later
interviews but we did hear occasional individual examples of both kinds of impact:
quality improvements and quality reductions.
In summary, our interviewees were broadly sceptical that PbR would have real effects
of the kind hoped for by policy-makers or predicted by economic analysis. Whether
their scepticism is justified can be assessed in the light of the quantitative analysis that
we report in Chapter 5.
1.5
Quantitative analysis of Payment by Results
In Chapter 5 we examine the linkages between PbR policy and measurable outcomes
using quantitative methods. The nature of the linkages is informed by the tools and
concepts of economic theory in section 1.3 (and in detail in Chapter 3). The
measurable outcomes are defined with reference to this theory and the objectives of
the PbR outlined in section 1.2 (Chapter 2 in more detail). Section 1.4 (Chapter 4) has
16
given potential insight into whether the linkages work as intended and what factors
contribute or hinder that which will be useful in interpreting and explaining the results.
We used the international literature, the objectives of the policy and the theoretical
analysis and discussions with the project advisory group to guide the choice of
appropriate outcome measures in the quantitative evaluation of PbR. We use length of
stay and the day case as a proportion of elective admissions as our two main measure
of unit costs or efficiency for hospital admissions. For outpatient services we use the
ratio of subsequent to first attendances and the ‘did not attend’ rate.
For volume of care we use the unit of reimbursement, i.e. the spell of care, for
admissions and attendances, for outpatient care.
For quality of care we follow convention and employ in-hospital mortality, 30-day
post surgical mortality and emergency readmission following treatment for hip
fracture.
We also investigate specific pairs and groups of HRGs for evidence of changes in
coding and/or treatment practice.
Method
Our evaluation challenge was to measure the effect of the introduction of PbR on
hospital behaviour. We seek to measure the effect of the policy on the targeted HRGs
and Trusts. We require estimates of what would have happened if the tariff had not
been introduced. We construct this control group using a ‘difference-in-difference’
(DiD) framework (Blundell and Costa Dias, 2000) and compare the changes over time
in the outcome variables for HRGs funded by tariff with the same outcome variables
in HRGs not funded by the tariff, before and after the tariff’s introduction.
The phased introduction of the policy represents a series of quasi-experiments. Since
there are several DiDs available, it is important to choose control groups that are most
appropriate for the research questions being answered. In the face of these choices, we
used two criteria for selecting the control group.
17
1.
The control group remains the same the year after the comparison
2.
The tariff is applied in full not just at the margin.
We use differences between the phasing in of PbR by FTs, non-FTs and Scotland
(which does not introduce tariffs during our study period in any meaningful way) to
estimate the effects of the introduction of the policy. We make comparisons between;
FTs and non-FTs in 2004/5; FTs and Scotland in 2004/5 and 2005/6; non-FTs and
Scotland in 2005/6; low cost and high cost non-FTs in 2005/6 and; Trusts in ‘indeficit’ and ‘in-surplus’ health economies in 2004/5 and 2005/6.
The majority of our analysis is undertaken at spell level. Details of the econometric
modelling are provided in Appendix B.
We use fixed effects to control for differences between the characteristics of HRGs
and Trusts that are unobserved but remain constant over time. Examples of such
Trust-level characteristics are management culture, teaching status, and local
population characteristics. HRG-level unobserved factors include specialty-specific
factors, patient demographics and case mix. We also control for age-sex composition.
Results
We present results on our analysis of admissions data, outpatient data and effects
within specific HRGs.
Impact on unit costs
The message on unit costs is consistent across most of the DiD analyses: unit costs
have fallen more quickly where PbR was implemented. Table 1.1 shows the DiD
results for the impact on length of stay and the proportion of daycases. For length of
stay the negative coefficients indicate that length of stay has fallen more quickly
where PbR has been implemented. Both FT and non-FTs appear to have responded in
the expected way to the incentives associated with PbR.
For day case proportions, the positive coefficients indicate that the proportion of
elective care provided as day cases has increased more quickly where PbR has been
18
implemented. Again this change is observed for both FTs and non-FTs. In addition,
high cost providers have increased the proportion of daycases more quickly than low
cost providers.
We demonstrate below that there has been little if any measurable change in the
quality of care. This suggests that the reductions in unit costs have been achieved
without detrimental impact on the quality of care measures used in our study. If these
adequately capture the quality of care, it is fair to suggest that the reductions in unit
costs have been achieved through improvements in the efficiency of the delivery of
care.
Table 1.1 Effects of tariff on unit costs: mean length of stay and daycase
proportion
Treatment
Control
Restriction
Year
Difference in
changes in
length of stay
Difference in
changes in
daycase
proportion
FTs
Non-FTs
04/05
+0.5%**
+0.4% pts**
FTs
Scotland
04/05
–2.3%**
+0.4% pts**
FTs
Scotland
–4.9%**
+1.5% pts**
Non-FTs
Scotland
03/0405/06
05/06
–1.2%**
+0.8% pts**
Non-FTs
Scotland
–3.9%**
N/A
**
N/A
Elective
High cost
non-FTs
High cost
non-FTs
Non-elective
Low cost
non-FTs
Low cost
non-FTs
Elective
Nonelective
05/06
05/06
Non-FTs
–0.7%
05/06
–0.02%‡
Elective
Nonelective
+0.25% pts**
05/06
N/A
N/A
Notes: After adjustment for age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects. ‡ not significant, * at 95
per cent, ** at 99 per cent
Impact on volume of spells
Using Scotland as the control group we found that that both FTs and non-FTs have
growth associated with the introduction of PbR. However, the one opportunity to
compare the response of FTs to non-FTs in 2004/5 shows that FTs under tariff that
year did not increase growth relative to the non-FTs. This last result is counter to what
we would expect and suggests that there may be changes in policies other than PbR,
e.g. waiting time targets, affecting the growth in the volume of care n England which
we have not been able to control for in our analysis.
19
The proportion of non-elective activity is not shown to have increased in response to
the introduction of the tariff.
Table 1.2 summarises the DiD results for the growth in volume of elective and nonelective spells and the proportion of non-elective spells.
Table 1.2 Effects of tariff on volume of care: all spells and non-elective
proportion
Difference in
changes in nonelective
proportion
Year
Difference in growth
in volume
Non-FTs
04/05
–0.25% pts‡
–0.1% pts*
FTs
Scotland
+1.33% pts*
+0.1% pts*
FTs
Scotland
04/05
03/0405/06
+4.95% pts**
Non-FTs
Scotland
Non-FTs
Scotland
Nonelective
Low cost
non-FTs
Low cost
non-FTs
Non-FTs in
deficit
Treatment
Control
FTs
Elective
High cost
non-FTs
High cost
non-FTs
Non-FTs in
surplus
Restriction
+0.02% pts‡
Elective
Nonelective
05/06
+2.57% pts**
N/A
05/06
+3.21% pts**
N/A
Non-FTs
05/06
+0.76% pts‡
N/A
Elective
Nonelective
05/06
+1.04% pts‡
N/A
05/06
+3.09% pts**
N/A
Elective
05/06
–3.27% pts**
N/A
Notes: After adjustment for age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects. ‡ not significant, * at 95
per cent, ** at 99 per cent
Impact on the quality of care
We found little evidence of an association between the introduction of the tariff and a
change in the quality of care. Table 1.3 shows the DiD results for the three variables
we used to measure quality: in-hospital mortality, 30-day post surgical mortality and
emergency readmission following treatment for hip fracture. The only result with
statistical significance is the difference in the change in in-hospital mortality for FTs
compared to Scotland. A difference emerges when we look at the longer term effects,
i.e. two years of impact of PbR. This provides one piece of evidence that the quality
of care for FTs has increased (represented by a reduction in the in-hospital mortality
20
rate) in association with the introduction of the tariff. There are no results supporting
the proposition that quality of care would suffer as a result of PbR.
Table 1.3 Effects of tariff on quality of care: in-hospital mortality, 30-day post
surgical mortality and emergency readmission following treatment for hip
fracture
Treatment
Control
Restriction
Year
Difference in
changes in
hospital
mortality
Difference in
changes in
30-day
mortality
Difference in
changes in
emergency
readmissions
FTs
Non-FTs
04/5
+0.01% pts‡
+0.01% pts ‡
–0.68% pts‡
FTs
Scotland
–0.05% pts‡
+0.03% pts ‡
+0.73% pts‡
FTs
Scotland
–0.28% pts**
–0.00% pts ‡
–1.20% pts‡
Non-FTs
Scotland
04/5
03/0405/06
05/6
–0.00% pts‡
–0.05% pts‡
0.00% pts‡
Non-FTs
Scotland
05/6
–0.23% pts**
N/A
N/A
05/6
+0.27% pts**
N/A
N/A
05/06
–0.06% pts**
–0.05% pts**
Elective
High cost
non-FTs
Nonelective
Low
cost
non-FTs
Elective
Nonelective
Non-FTs
–0.10% pts‡
Notes: After adjustment for age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects. ‡ not significant, * at 95
per cent, ** at 99 per cent
Outpatients
We undertook a series of analysis on seven variables measuring changes in the
patterns of outpatient services. Our results clearly demonstrate that there has been
only one statistically significant change in the pattern of outpatient provision which
can be associated with the introduction of the outpatient tariff under the PbR system.
These results are reported in full in Chapter 5.
HRG up-coding
There is evidence from the international literature that hospitals operating under a
case-mix based financing system such as PbR may respond to the incentives in ways
not intended by the policy makers. One such effect is up-coding whereby providers
code patients into HRGs which attract higher tariffs. For instance, where a treatment
has two different HRGs to which it can be assigned, one ‘with complications’ and one
‘without complications’, there is an incentive to up-code patients to the higher tariffed
‘with complications’. We have investigated six pairs or groups of HRGs for evidence
of such activity. We examined changes in the proportions of ‘with complications’ in
21
maternity care and instances elsewhere (in hip replacement and head injuries) where
such an unintended incentive, associated with differences in the tariffs, was perceived.
We found very limited evidence of a change in the pattern of coding or treatment of
patients associated with the introduction of tariff. Of the six investigations, we found
that only the coding (or perhaps practice) of caesarean section by FTs and normal
delivery by non-FTs had changed in the direction expected if up-coding is happening.
It should be noted that the introduction was expected to be accompanied by greater
transparency in the system and that the system encourages more accurate and
complete coding of patients. It is not possible from this analysis to determine whether
the very limited up-coding we identified was inappropriate or due to increased
accuracy.
1.6
Conclusion
Our evaluation of PbR has involved a number of substantive elements: an exploration
and extension of an appropriate theoretical framework, conducting an analysing semistructured interviews and econometric modelling. These three components fit together
to provide a means of assessing and understanding the impact of PbR on a number of
key performance measures in the NHS. Each element also provides important insights
in its own right.
The theoretical framework supports the view that a fixed national tariff will lead to
downward pressure on unit costs that at least potentially will result from efficiency
savings. Trusts with costs above tariff price levels have a clear incentive to reduce
costs so as to avoid financial losses; and Trusts with costs below tariff have an, albeit
probably weaker, incentive to continue to press for lower unit costs as resultant
surpluses can be spent in part or in whole on non-tariffed activities or aspects of
quality of care. The framework has further drawn attention to some weaknesses in
establishing an unambiguous link between a more volume sensitive payments system
such as PbR and activity levels. In complex health care systems such as the NHS there
may be many countervailing incentives – such as capacity constraints.
22
From the interviews we elicited a willingness to work with the PbR policy and a
general acceptance that it had been implemented successfully. But we encountered
scepticism as to whether it would achieve its objectives. We also identified reported
behaviours and attitudes which would not be conducive to achieving some of the
objectives. Some of these constraints on PbR may need to be addressed in the future.
Our substantive quantitative analysis of the effects of PbR on key outcomes provides
evidence that there have been reductions in unit costs of care which are associated
with the introduction on PbR in England in its early years of implementation. There is
less unequivocal evidence that PbR has stimulated increases in the volume of spells.
For volume of outpatients, there has been no discernible impact on the volume or
return ratio. With respect to quality of care the evidence needs to be treated with
caution because in common with other researchers we have been limited in our ability
to proxy the complexity that is ‘quality’ of health care. Nevertheless we have not
found any evidence that PbR has had a negative impact on the generally accepted
mortality measures. This suggests that the reductions in unit costs may have been
achieved without detrimental impact on the quality of care, at least in as far as these
are measured by our variables.
Taken together the analysis suggests that PbR is capable of achieving, and has in the
short time since its adoption actually achieved real changes in hospital health delivery
in England. Looking forward, our evaluation suggests a potentially rich set of further
research questions. Our approach has of necessity been a general one. There is much
still to learn about the impact of PbR at a more disaggregate level, for instance:
(1) Into the differential impact of PbR across different HRGs
(2) Into impact on different population groups (socio economic categories)
(3) Into the pattern of response by Trusts and whether this is associated with
observable differences in performance
23
Chapter 2. Payment by Results Policy
The focus of our study is the system of financing hospitals called ‘Payment by
Results’ (PbR). Under PbR hospitals are paid according to the number and type of
patients that they treat through a system in which prices are determined in advance.
Prices are defined in terms of Healthcare Resource Group (HRG) spells of stay in
hospital. The Department of Health for England (DH) outlined its plans to introduce
PbR in April 2002 (DH, 2002a). The system has been phased in from 2003/04 and for
acute care, the focus of our study, will be fully implemented by 2007/08. In common
with many other health care systems PbR ensures that the provision of hospital
services is financed using a mechanism that makes a direct link between volume and
casemix of output and hospital income (Sussex and Street, 2005).
2.1
Hospital financing prior to PbR
Prior to PbR the commissioners and providers of hospital care in the English NHS
used a range of different arrangements to fund hospitals. These were usually referred
to as different forms of contract. Thus, block contracts, sophisticated block contracts,
cost and volume contracts and cost per case contracts were terms used to describe
purchasing arrangements. In essence these arrangements defined a broad range of
services (e.g acute care) that a hospital was to provide and set a payment for those
services.
Block contracts were the simplest form of payment, whereby, in return for a lump
sum payment from the commissioner, the hospital Trust provides a defined range of
services to a specified population. The more commonly used ‘sophisticated’ block
contract, introduced pre-defined maximum and minimum levels of provision. Output
levels outside of these targets triggered predefined actions. These could be
renegotiations or data validation procedures (Raftery et al, 1996). Cost and volume
contracts are similar to the block contracts in that a lump sum is agreed. However,
under this contract form the volume of services to be provided is also pre-defined.
Cost per case contracts were rare and involved Trusts being reimbursed on a case by
case basis. They usually involved referrals not funded by other types of contracts
(Goddard et al, 1997).
24
Information was not systematically collected on the forms of contracts that were used
within the NHS. The most up to date information on the contract-type prior to the
introduction of PbR is from a study undertaken for 1994/95 (Raftery et al, 1996)
which showed sophisticated block contracts to be the most prevalent type, making up
around 69 per cent of all major contracts. Cost and volume contracts accounted for 25
per cent; simple block contracts made up five per cent and; cost per case were used in
only one per cent of major contracts.
2.2
The details of PbR
The prices (also termed the national tariff) developed and used under PbR financing
system in the English NHS are specified in terms of ‘spells’ of activity. A spell of
activity is a hospital stay from admission to discharge. The previous measure of
activity in the NHS was the Finished Consultant Episode (FCE), which generated
multiple records if a patient’s treatment was associated with more than one consultant.
Patients with complex medical conditions might thus give rise to multiple FCEs and a
spell might cover more than one finished consultant episode. For such a multipleepisode spell, the HRG code assigned is determined by the dominant episode. It is a
measure of the unit of output of hospitals. The appropriate price / tariff is defined by
the Healthcare Resource Group (HRG) into which the spell is coded. Spells which are
clinically similar and require similar levels of resource use are coded into the same
HRG. In this way the HRG is similar to the Diagnostic Related Group used in other
such systems (Department of Health, 2003a, 2003b, 2003c, 2004a).
In the English health care system there are just over 600 HRGs in the version
HRGV3.5 (which cover the period of the data used in our study) used to describe
admitted care and, of those, 550 have an HRG-specific tariff. The payment the
hospitals receives for a patient can be influenced by whether their spell is pre-planned
(elective) or not (non-elective), reflecting the difference in costs associated with the
two types of patients (Department of Health, 2004b). A single tariff exists to
reimburse trusts for each HRG for daycase and inpatient elective care (Department of
Health, 2002a).
25
Under PbR, tariffs have also been introduced to reimburse hospitals for the provision
of outpatient services. The tariff for these is defined by speciality. In 2004/05, the first
year of outpatient tariff, two types of tariffs were used. Most outpatient provision was
funded on a per attendance basis with a higher tariff for the first attendance compared
to subsequent attendances. A different type of tariff was applied to ten specialties:
these were funded on an episode basis, whereby a fixed payment was made for the
first and subsequent attendances which was not related to the number of total
attendances (Department of Health, 2004b, Appendix 8). This system of episode
based tariff for outpatients was not retained in subsequent years. As at 2005/06, there
were 39 outpatient specialty tariffs and separate outpatient tariffs apply for adults and
children (Department of Health 2005).
In 2005/06, an attendance-based tariff was introduced for accident and emergency
care (Department of Health, 2004c). Three tariffs were created to reimburse for high
cost, standard and minor injury unit attendances. Organisations are funded at tariff for
their planned activity. Additional attendances will also be funded at full tariff.
However, providers with activity below planned levels will have funds withdrawn at
20 per cent of tariff.
PbR tariffs are set at national average costs using reference cost returns of the
previous two years. For example, for 2004/05, data from 2002/03 was used to produce
an average cost for each HRG spell which would form the basis of the HRG spell
tariff. The average cost tariff is then adjusted in various ways. To reflect changes in
costs over time across all HRGs for all providers, the tariff is uplifted to account for
changes in the underlying costs of delivering care with some downward adjustment
for efficiency improvements. It is adjusted across some HRGs for all providers to
reflect changes in technology and to reflect National Institute for Health and Clinical
Excellence guidelines. At a separate stage in the reimbursement process the tariff is
then adjusted using the Market Forces Factor (MFF) to give a local price for each
Trust reflecting unavoidable local differences in costs (DH, 2004b). The aim of the
MFF is take into account unavoidable local differences in the cost of providing health
care services
26
PbR has been introduced in a phased fashion. It was first applied to marginal changes
in output for 15 HRGs in 2003/4 (Department of Health, 2002a) and extended to a
further 33 HRGs in 2004/5 (Department of Health, 2004b, Appendix 7). The tariff
was used to commission activity growth above the baseline of Service Level
Agreements. For Trusts which did not deliver the agreed level of elective activity,
funds were withdrawn at the rate of the tariff. For a subset of NHS Trusts, Foundation
Trusts3 (FTs), it was applied to most inpatient (with some exceptions4), day case and
outpatient output (again with exceptions) in 2004/5. In addition, three non-FTs were
‘early implementers’ of the tariff, following the same pathway as the FTs5. For the
remaining Trusts, it was applied to most elective admissions in 2005/6 (again with
exceptions) and then to outpatients in 2006/07 (Department of Health, 2004c).
Transitional arrangements for the tariff have been implemented. Under these
arrangements the NHS Trust is allowed to keep a percentage of the difference
between tariff price and local cost (Department of Health, 2003c). Providers with
local prices above tariff can retain the difference and those with local costs below the
tariff must give up the difference6. The transition paths vary according to whether and
when the Trust gained Foundation status.
The scope of the tariff for Non-FTs and FTs is illustrated in Table 2.1, whereby the
pale boxes (checkered) indicate that the tariff was introduced to spells at the margin
and the darker boxes (plain) where it was introduced to all spells (with the exceptions
explained above) in that group of HRGs.
3
The highest performing NHS Trusts were given the option to apply for Foundation Trust status. The
first wave of FTs were authorised in April 2004. Still part of the NHS, they have greater autonomy in
decision-making, greater freedom to make and re-invest surpluses and access to public and private
capital.
4
Some HRGs are excluded from tariff on the basis that they were low volume, had volatile costs and/or
were of a specialised nature. These are listed in Table 2 of Appendix G.
5
Communication with Project Advisory Group.
6
Communication with Project Advisory Group.
27
Table 2.1 Scope of Payment by Results
2003/04
2004/05
2005/06
2006/07
FTs
FTs
FTs
FTs
NonFTs
NonFTs
NonFTs
NonFTs
Elective spells: 15HRGs
Elective spells: 33 HRGs
Elective spells: other HRGs
Non-elective spells
Outpatients
Note: checkered boxes indicate marginal application of the tariff. Plain shaded boxes indicate
application of the tariff to all spells within the group of HRGs.
Details of the further refinement and development of PbR, beyond the scope and
timetable of this project, and the tariffs are published on the Department of Health
website
at
http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Policyandguidance/Organisationpolicy/Financeandplanning/
NHSFinancialReforms/index.htm.
2.3
The broader context of reform
PbR represents one component of the modernisation and reform programme
announced in the NHS Plan (DH, 2000a). These other reform instruments have been
introduced throughout the period covered by this study and have the potential to
interact with PbR and affect its impact. Below, we outline the other main changes in
health care policy applying in the period from 2002/03 onwards which might affect
the results of our analyses.
The major parallel policy reforms underway in the NHS in England which most affect
the objectives and impact of PbR were introduced in the NHS Plan (Department of
Health, 2000):
•
Shorter waiting times targets;
•
introduction of an active policy of patient choice of provider for elective
hospital care;
28
•
creation of ‘Foundation Trusts’ with some devolved powers not available to
other NHS Trusts;
•
greater support of independent sector provision of hospital services to NHS
patients;
•
introduction of practice based commissioning, i.e. giving all primary care
practices indicative budgets from which to buy health care for their registered
patients.
In the area of hospital elective care, a major feature of health care policy in England
has been the succession of ever more challenging targets imposed by the Government
to reduce patients’ maximum waiting times. For elective inpatients and day cases the
targets during the period of our study were:
•
March 2002 – no-one waiting more than 15 months after decision to admit
•
March 2003 – no-one waiting more than 12 months after decision to admit
•
March 2004 – no-one waiting more than 9 months after decision to admit
•
December 2005 – no-one waiting more than 6 months after decision to admit
These targets have been given very high priority, to the extent that failure to achieve
them has been seen by senior NHS managers as career threatening (Bevan and Hood,
2006, Propper et al, 2007, Alvarez-Rosete et al, 2005). An additional target, to be
achieved by the end of 2004, was a maximum 4-hour waiting time in A&E from
arrival to admission. Various strategies have been used to meet these targets and there
is evidence consistent with Trusts increasing emergency admissions as a way of
meeting the A&E target (BMA, 2005). Together, the waiting time targets have
provided a strong stimulus to Trusts to increase activity in order to achieve them.
A major policy theme in the NHS in England which PbR was intended to complement
is the extension of patient choice over the hospital in which they are treated for
elective procedures (Department of Health, 2000). The Department of Health
introduced the first pilot schemes in 2002, giving patients who would otherwise have
to wait more than six months for surgery the choice to go to an alternative provider
for faster treatment. Evaluation of this London Patient Choice Project demonstrated
29
that the project led to shorter waiting times for patients (Dawson et al, 2007). The
policy was launched throughout England in January 2006, since when most patients
had a choice of at least four providers when they are referred for planned hospital care
by their GP. PCTs are responsible for commissioning the menu of providers from
which people can choose.
NHS Foundation Trust status was created in the NHS in England to incentivise high
performing Trusts by permitting them some greater freedoms and flexibilities than
other NHS Trusts in the way they manage their affairs, e.g. more freedom from
Whitehall control and performance management by Strategic Health Authorities;
easier access to (limited) capital funding and freedom to invest surpluses in
developing new services (Department of Health, 2002b). The first Foundation Trusts
were established in April 2004 and their numbers have progressively increased,
reaching 73 by August 2007 (Monitor, 2007). As detailed in the previous section, in
2004/05 Foundation Trusts were subject to PbR arrangements in full, whereas other
Trusts were introduced to it later.
The Department of Health has also actively stimulated the development of increased
private sector provision of some elective hospital services (Department of Health,
2002c). In particular, starting in September 2003, the Department of Health has
signed a series of contracts for independent sector treatment centres (ISTCs) with the
aim of increasing capacity to treat NHS patients and providing a wider range of
potential providers in support of patient choice policy. By the end of 2006, nine
ISTCs were in operation. Nationally the ISTCs provide around one per cent of total
NHS elective activity in England. Despite this small scale activity, there is anecdotal
evidence that they have had a greater impact on the behaviour of adjacent NHS
providers (Timmins, 2005).
A major policy for the NHS in England with the potential for a long-term effect on the
impact of PbR on volumes of activity is practice based commissioning (PBC)
(Department of Health, 2006). By encouraging demand management by GPs, i.e.
closer consideration by them of the cost consequences of their referral decisions, this
may serve to dampen hospital activity levels. Since April 2005, GP practices in
England have had the right to hold an indicative PBC budget covering at a minimum:
30
•
all hospital-based care covered by PbR;
•
prescribing;
•
community services;
•
mental health services.
PCTs still retain statutory responsibility for the funds allocated to them, even though
GP practices hold indicative PBC budgets. PCTs are required to allow GP practices
that take on indicative PBC budgets to retain at least 70% of any savings against that
budget “for reinvestment in patient care” even if the local health economy is in deficit.
For the most part the impact of PBC is yet to be felt. Since the end of 2006 all 152
PCTs are reported to be putting in place the necessary arrangements to support PBC
and, as at the end of 2006/07, 96% of practices have taken the incentive payments
offered in the nGMS contract to start to engage in PBC (Department of Health,
2007a). A Department of Health press release on 26th January 2007 gives examples
of “early adopters” of PBC reducing their referral rates to hospital since they became
indicative budget holders (Department of Health, 2007b). But that aside it is very
early days for PBC and reliable evaluation of its impact will only emerge over the
coming years.
The English NHS has retained the separation between providers and purchasers/
commissioners of care which was introduced throughout the UK in 1991 but revoked
in Scotland in 2001. Thus in England 152 Primary Care Trusts (reduced from 304
until October 2006) are allocated budgets to buy care from provider Trusts and
primary care contractors. The provider organisations include over 200 acute hospital
Trusts. Many of the acute Trusts are based around general acute hospitals and provide
a wide range of the services that are now paid for under PbR; but a minority are
specialist Trusts supplying a narrow range of services such as elective orthopaedics,
or heart and lung treatment, or children’s services.
31
2.4
A Comparator – Hospital Financing in Scotland
Because part of our analysis draws on a comparison of quantitative data in England
and Scotland, we highlight in the following paragraphs important differences between
the structure and policy context of the NHS in England and the NHS in Scotland.
The Scottish health care system historically has had a different structure to that of
England, reflecting its separate administration (and, since 1998, separate Government)
from England and perhaps it population size and distribution (Ham, 1992).
Patient choice, Foundation Trusts and Practice based Commissioning have not been
adopted in Scotland. Since devolution the Scottish Government has placed greater
emphasis on central planning and has vertically reintegrated the commissioners and
providers of the internal market. Unified NHS Boards were introduced in 2001 and by
April 2004 NHS Trusts in Scotland ceased to exist. The structure of the NHS in
Scotland has since remained stable7 (Jervis and Plowden, 2003).
Although, like England, Scotland has used waiting time targets to stimulate improved
performance, the specifics of these targets in terms of the maximum number of
months patients should wait and the rewards (and penalties) associated with meeting
(or not meeting) these were different for England and Scotland (Scottish Executive
Health Department, 2001, 2004). Generally, the regime in England is considered to be
more ‘aggressive’ with tighter targets and stronger sanctions if these are not met
Propper et al, 2007).
In 2005/06 a ‘shadow’ national tariff was introduced in Scotland. This was limited to
cross boundary flows between the 14 NHS Boards and to two specialties (Scottish
Executive Health Department, 2005). Further, there were no changes in financial
flows associated with these in 2005/06. As a result we are able to treat the financing
of NHS Boards as unchanged during our period of study.
In international terms, there are considerable similarities between the Scottish and
English health care systems. The two countries have essentially shared the same
7
The exception is the movement from 15 to 14 NHS Boards in 2006.
32
financing mechanisms and broad policy developments until The Scotland Act 1998.
Both systems are predominantly funded through general taxation and provide services
free at the point of consumption. They each use family doctors as gatekeepers to
secondary care services. They also have the same nationally agreed (UK) contracts for
consultants, nurses and GPs.
We have been able to identify ways in which the NHS in Scotland differs from and is
similar to the NHS in England. In a natural experiment the ideal control group would
be similar in all ways to the group subject to policy change. However, as explained
earlier such situations are rare in public policy. However, the NHS in Scotland does
provide a structure similar to English NHS and importantly one which has been
relatively stable in its financing of hospitals at the time of the implementation of PbR.
As a result, we consider the NHS in Scotland to provide and useful control in our
analysis.
2.5
Objectives of PbR
The objectives and anticipated benefits of the introduction of PbR have been
articulated in a range of policy documents. When seeking to distinguish policy
objectives we have focussed on the early documentation. These identify a number of
objectives which are usually explicit and occasionally implicit in those documents. A
range of objectives are identifiable.
The key document introducing PbR policy was ‘Reforming NHS Financial Flows’
(Department of Health, 2002a). This document identified three main reasons for
introducing a standard price tariff are given (Page 13)
•
To ‘enable PCT commissioners to focus on the quality and volume of services
provided’
•
To ‘incentivise NHS Trusts to manage costs efficiently’.
•
To ‘create greater transparency and planning certainty in the system.’
These objectives are developed further elsewhere in the document.
33
The intended direction of change for quality of care is clear in the documentation.
‘Patients can have confidence that new funding arrangements will sustain
improving quality’ (Page 11).
This is expected to be achieved partly by shifting negotiating time away from price
and freeing up time to focus on the quality of care and by giving PCTs better ‘levers’
to achieve service improvement in combination with Patient Choice. Under Patient
Choice, patients are given the opportunity to
‘choose among providers on the basis of quality’ (page 25).
The complementary policy of increased patient choice was intended to produce more
informed patients. But even in the absence of this reform, commissioners of care
would be expected to choose between providers on the basis of quality, all else being
equal, as in a system of nationally fixed prices.
PbR, as with many other casemix-based prospective payment systems is given the
explicit incentive to increase efficiency in the provision of health care services. More
specifically, with respect to the justification for a case mix based payment:
‘Case-based payment has led to increased use of day surgery and reductions in
lengths of stay in hospital’. (Page13, Department of Health, 2002a).
With respect to the intended effect on volume, the direction of the incentives is less
unambiguous, reflecting the sophistication of the new system. On the one hand the
system is expected to control the volume of services:
‘Clearer arrangements for risk-sharing … will incentivise PCTs to manage
demand effectively’. (Page 11)
On the other hand, PbR is expected to:
‘Create direct incentives for increasing the volume of services where growth is
needed in order to improve access’. (Page 12)
34
These objectives suggest perceived linkages between the adoption of PbR and
changes in the attitudes and behaviour of decision makers and, thus, ultimately the
performance of the hospital system in the NHS.
The remainder of our evaluation is based upon exploring the nature of these linkages.
We do so first using the tools and concepts of economic theory (Chapter 3) and then
empirically, using both qualitative (Chapter 4) and quantitative (Chapter 5) methods.
35
Chapter 3. The link between Payment by Results and
outcomes – theoretical considerations
3.1
Background
As discussed in Chapter 2, PbR institutes a system where NHS hospitals in England
are paid a fixed price for each patient they treat within an HRG. From the perspective
of economic analysis this constitutes a specific form of contract and implies specific
incentives. The purpose of this section is to briefly review the economic theory in
relation to the incentives generated to providers of health care by such fixed price
contracts, and to suggest a specific model (and extensions to it) that aid an
understanding of the operation of PbR in practice.
There is a vast literature on contracting for health services and it is not the intention to
attempt to review it here: the focus will on key concepts. The approach we adopt
follows that provided by Chalkley and Malcomson (2000).
From the perspective of economic theory there are many elements of health care that
give rise to incentive issues.
In particular asymmetric information, wherein the
provider of a service knows much more about what is to be supplied than the
purchaser, is a pervasive feature of health care. To a considerable degree the
economics contracting literature has focused on how contracts can be used to regulate
the potentially damaging (either to society or to the purchasers of health care)
behaviour that can result when health care providers exploit their information
advantage. Hence, the terminology that is used is often suggestive of improper
behaviour by providers. In this section we follow that terminology but recognise that
impropriety is a matter of perspective: complex institutions such as health care
providers have obligations to many interest groups, for example, patients, their
employees, the local community etc. Our discussion is concerned with how in
balancing these obligations providers may in practice not fully reflect the concerns of
the purchasers of health care.
Before outlining the main concepts and ideas from economic models it is important to
consider specific institutional arrangements.
36
In the NHS the health services that we are concerned with in considering the impact
of PbR are predominantly provided by NHS Trusts and purchased by Primary Care
Trusts (PCTs). Whilst admitting the possibility of other organisations within the NHS
in what follows we will simply abbreviate these and refer to hospitals and PCTs
respectively. An important distinction in the NHS is between hospitals that have
achieved Foundation Trust status and those that have not. This is important from the
perspective of economic theory because it is usual to assume that decision-makers
have discretion over the use of any residual funds that they generate – indeed such
ownership over any surplus often defines the ownership of organisational unit for the
purposes of economic analysis.
Whilst Foundation Trusts are able to control their surpluses, hospitals that do not have
Foundation Trust status are not. A full consideration of the implications of these
different organisational arrangements is beyond the scope of this Chapter but is
nevertheless an important aspect of the operation of PbR. Consistent with existing
economic theory we simply consider in what follows that surpluses are to some
degree beneficial to the hospitals that generate them, perhaps through their ability to
negotiate better arrangements with PCTs. Similarly we assume that deficits are
generally to the detriment of the hospital even if they do not necessitate borrowing or,
more drastically, insolvency of the hospital as an organisation.
We suggest that future work might be targeted at considering the implications of these
different organisational arrangements and, in particular, of the existence of financial
deficits or surpluses for hospital decisions. For the purposes of our empirical work it
seems prudent to distinguish between Foundation Trusts and other providers and
consider empirically whether there are significant differences between them.
37
3.2
Three aspects of PbR
Cost sensitivity
In most economic analyses of fixed price payment the comparator (either explicit of
implicit) is defined as cost reimbursement. Under cost reimbursement the provider of
a service can be viewed as in effect submitting a bill for the resources used in
delivering services and having that bill paid. The arrangements in the NHS that PbR
replaces were, as with any real-world health care payment system, more complex and
less clear cut. As outlined in Chapter 2, a variety of contracts were used prior to PbR
described variously as block contracts, fixed budgets, cost and volume contracts and
sophisticated block contracts.
One key element of all of these arrangements was that they enabled hospitals to
negotiate prices with PCTs that were responsive to local conditions. Thus in setting a
hospital’s budget, or agreeing its cost and volume contract, a PCT would take into
account the likely expenditure of the hospital, allowing for expectations regarding
local conditions in terms of patient case-mix, salaries and wages, costs of capital
(depreciation) etc. For the purposes of drawing lessons from economic analysis this
sensitivity of contract value to those factors that drive cost is important. It suggests
that notwithstanding the institutional specific terminology that pre-PbR arrangement
were sensitive to cost to the extent that a hospital might influence the amount it was
paid, if not in the present accounting period then in future ones, by actions or
omissions that increased cost.
The Department of Health explicitly recognised this feature of the NHS financing
system when describing the anticipated impact of PbR, noting that the movement
from what it termed ‘local prices’ to a national tariff would increase incentives to
control costs. Further evidence of within period cost reimbursement in the NHS exists
in the specific case of sophisticated block contracts. The arrangements often explicitly
allowed hospitals to negotiate an increase in a given contractual price on account of
increased costs, most usually on account of adverse case-mix.
In summary, it seems to us useful to consider the movement to PbR as a shift from a
‘more or less’ cost sensitive payment system to an absolutely cost insensitive one. As
38
usual, in economic analysis the implications can be understood by abstracting from
the complex reality and considering the shift in its starkest terms as a move from cost
reimbursement to fixed prices.
Volume sensitivity
As described above the arrangements in place prior to PbR were varied. Under some
contracts hospitals were explicitly paid more for additional treatments under the terms
of their cost and volume contracts. Under other arrangements – sophisticated block
contracts – hospitals could negotiate for extra payments ex post on the basis of having
delivered more treatments than anticipated at the time the contract was agreed. Some
contracts – fixed budgets or ‘simple’ block contracts – if interpreted strictly made no
provision for payments to vary with the number of patients treated.
Under PbR there is a pre-defined and certain link between extra patients treated and
payment. Thus it seems reasonable to regard PbR as a more volume sensitive payment
system.
Case mix sensitivity
A third key aspect of PbR is in making payment HRG dependent, where HRGs serve
to categorise patients, and their treatments, into a large number of categories. As
compared with the pre-PbR arrangements where PCTs often contracted for a range of
services encompassing a great variety of medical conditions, diagnoses and treatments,
often very broadly defined, this makes payment more sensitive to the specific medical
conditions of the individuals being treated. Hence, along with reduced cost sensitivity
and increased volume sensitivity PbR moves payment to increased case-mix
sensitivity.
The plan of the remainder of this chapter is as follows. In Section 3.2 we outline a
basic theoretical framework which is useful for considering the incentive implications
of PbR. We consider separately the specific implications of cost, volume and casemix sensitivity in section 3.3, 3.4 and 3.5 respectively.
39
3.3
The Basic Theoretical Framework - Quality and Cost of Care
In terms of economic analysis a contract for health care, such as the agreement to
purchase health services at a fixed price as implied by PbR, signifies delegated
decision making because there are potentially many aspects of the treatment to be
delivered that the PCT would like to (but cannot) specify and delegates to the hospital.
Hence, the economic actor performing the task (usually called the agent) is doing so
on behalf of, or to the benefit of, another economic actor (usually called the principal)
who is then going to reward them and we can invoke principal-agent models. In the
context of health care the task is health care delivery and we can think of the principal
as the PCT and the agent as the hospital. Different methods of reward imply
potentially different incentives to perform the task.
Principal-agent analysis suggests two types of problems that may be encountered by
the principal when trying to align incentives. The first problem is easy to grasp --- the
task itself, or some aspects of it, may not be verifiable. This gives rise to what is
termed a ‘moral hazard’ or ‘hidden action’ problem. The real-world analogue of this
in the context of health care is a hospital that fails to control its costs or deliver an
adequate quality of service to its patients --- neither cost control nor quality are
verifiable aspects of health care delivery. Somewhat more subtle, is what is termed
the hidden information problem. This arises when some uncertainty affects the
performance of a task such that it would be desirable to condition payment on the
resolution of that uncertainty. The most usually discussed manifestation of this in
health care is variable case-mix. A hospital that receives a lot of difficult patients to
treat will legitimately require a larger budget to treat them. But the precise complexity
of treatments required (as distinct from delivered) is information that only the hospital
knows. There may be undesirable incentives to either exaggerate the severity of casemix or, when case mix can be affected by selecting which patients to treat, manipulate
case-mix.
There is a degree of consensus that in delivering health care, providers have discretion
that can impact upon either or both of the quality and cost of the care that is provided.
In the economics literature it is traditional to think about there being two decisions
40
that providers make in respect of, first, quality of care, henceforth
q
, and, second,
cost-reducing effort, henceforth e.
The first of these requires little comment save to say that, in practice, quality of health
care is considered to be multi-faceted. The second decision captures the idea that in
delivering health care there are things that can be done, or left undone, that impact
upon cost without necessarily affecting quality. For example, medical supplies can be
conserved or wasted. With two aspects to health care decisions, in the jargon of the
literature, there is a multi-task principal agent problem. In what follows it is assumed
that, whatever the means of payment, the hospital has to maintain quality of care
above some minimum q and effort above zero.
The key issues can be understood by initially restricting attention to the problem of
treating a single patient and assuming the two decisions combine to yield the hospital
a payoff of
P − v ( q , e ) − c ( q , e ),
the purchaser.
where
P
is the payment that will be received from
It is easiest to think about
c (.)
monetary costs of carrying out treatment whilst
v (.)
as constituting the observable
might be comprised of other
unobserved costs (or indeed benefits) expressed in monetary terms. With these
interpretations it is natural to assume that ve > 0 (effort is unpleasant to the provider),
ce < 0
(but works to reduce monetary costs) and
cq , vq > 0
(quality is in all senses of
the word costly to produce). Meanwhile the PCT can be initially assumed to have
some intrinsic concern about quality of care, captured by a payoff function
− (1 + α ) P
a dislike of paying captured by
b (q )
and
where α is some dis-benefit over and
above the transfer to the provider that may reflect, for example, dead-weight welfare
loss. In most of what follows it is assumed that the hospital can be viewed as
maximising
3.4
P − v(q , e) − c(q , e)
.
The impact of cost sensitivity
The conceptual framework of section 3.3 helps in understanding the some of the
incentive properties of different payment schemes and in particular of a transition to
PbR.
41
As argued in Section 3.2 it is simplest to contrast PbR with an arrangement in which
hospitals are simply reimbursed for their costs which can be captured by assuming
that
P = ( 1 + m ) c (.).
The `mark-up' m is included to ensure that the hospital is
compensated for their unobserved costs
v (.)
. This captures in essence the pre-PbR
arrangement under which hospitals are financed out of public funds according to a
budget that is set to reflect their expected costs. Maximising surplus under this
arrangement leads the hospital to want to set either mc e − v e = 0 or
mc q − v q = 0
or q = q. Under PbR the payment
P
e = 0
and either
is just a fixed sum --- a price per
patient treated, or prospective payment because it can be set in advance of treatment
occurring. In this case the hospital will want to balance the benefits and costs of
and e
on the margin which requires either − ve − c e = 0 or
− cq − vq = 0
e = 0
q
and either
or q = q.
Comparing the two sets of surplus maximising conditions as between cost
reimbursement and PbR is revealing. Under cost reimbursement, the fact that ce < 0
leads to the conclusion that
cq,vq < 0
e = 0
leads to the conclusion that
and q > q whereas under PbR the fact that
e > 0
and q = q.
This simple framework suggests that, other things equal, the greater cost sensitivity
aspect of PbR will increase incentives to control costs but may result in some
economising on quality of care. Of course in practice many factors may serve to
mitigate this latter effect. For example clinicians with a concern for their patients,
would work to increase quality of care. Nevertheless a first key idea from the
application of contracts and incentives to health care is that PbR arrangements provide
incentives to keep costs down but may compromise incentives to provide high quality
care and this guides both our subsequent qualitative and quantitative evaluation
methodology. Other things equal we expect the introduction of PbR to be associated
with greater cost control and reduced quality.
In respect of the latter it is notoriously difficult to establish reliable objective
indicators of quality of care. In Chapter 5, we follow much of the economics literature
and use length of stay (LOS) as one measure of the outcome of hospital choices. LOS
42
is generally regarded as well correlated with unit cost and as such will reflect both
and
e,
q
It is not obvious either whether greater lengths of stay are better or worse for
patients or whether LOS is a better indicator of quality of care or effort and it is
perhaps safest to regard it as simply indicative of unit costs. Other commonly adopted
measures of the outcome of quality and effort choices are various measures of
mortality rates and we also consider these in our empirical work in Chapter 5.
The implications of this approach may appear very obvious but they have been
generalised to settings which are much more complex. The central idea is enduring fixed prices for health care help contain costs - and a significant extension to this is
the notion that fixed prices might be consistent with achieving a socially appropriate
level of quality. This works by allowing for the fact that under fixed prices that pay a
surplus over costs, providers have an incentive to attract more patients. Enhanced
service quality is one way that they might endeavour to do that, so that high prices
become a driver of quality when patient demand reflects quality. The analysis above
can be modified to illustrate this idea by allowing for a probability that a patient will
arrive to be treated and that this probability depends on quality, hence
p (q )
multiplies the expression for the provider's objective. It is straightforward to show in
this case that the condition for choosing a positive level of quality can be satisfied.
Provided that the fixed price is set so as to ensure that
hospital's chosen levels of
q
P − v(q , e) − c(q , e)
(at the
and e ) there is an incentive to treat all patients that
come along as long as the hospital has the capacity to do that. In the next section we
consider the implications of limited treatment capacity but here it is worth noting that
the incentive to treat more patients is stronger the greater is the surplus over all costs
implied by the fixed price. This suggests that any reduction in quality associated with
the introduction of PbR will be greatest for those treatments where patients do not
perceive quality of care or do not exercise choice in response to any perceived quality
differences.
The theory set out above is generic in that the models have been developed to aid a
general understanding of the impact of prospective payment fixed price contracts
across a number of jurisdictions. The NHS constitutes a particular institutional setting,
and PbR a particular implementation of fixed price contracting, and there are
43
additional concerns or questions that arise in the NHS. There are too many specifics
to simultaneously incorporate into a fully articulated economic model. Indeed the
return to constructing more tailored models is probably slight. The results (and thus
questions) we have set out above are regarded as reasonably robust and they do not
depend in any major way upon the choice of functional form or even specifically upon
the assumed objectives of providers. More specialised models will, to a large extent,
exhibit results that depend on a host of assumptions that it would be necessary to
make in order to ensure that the model is tractable.
3.5
The impact of volume sensitivity
One particular feature of NHS health economies and the motivation for introducing
PbR merits special attention. In most jurisdictions the introduction of fixed prices has
occurred in circumstances where increasing the volume of health care activity has not
a specific aim. In the NHS however there was concern that, at least for high-priority
areas of health care, services should be expanded. Pre-existing arrangements for
payment of hospitals made some provision for incentivising greater volume but as we
have argued above it is reasonable to treat PbR as displaying greater volume
sensitivity.
As we considered the issues as they pertain to the introduction of PbR in the NHS we
could not find any existing analysis that appeared to capture the essential element of a
capacity constrained health care system. Therefore, in this section we summarise
some findings from a model that we developed to capture the idea that (in what has
traditionally been a cash-limited system) there is a degree of fixed capacity and that
the impact of this varies according to what kinds of treatments (distinguishing
between elective versus emergency HRGs) a hospital is considering. We consider in
such a setting the extent to which the greater volume sensitivity of payment under
PbR might have an impact on the volume of different activities. In particular we take
into account the fact that in practice PbR sets prices that reflect average costs.
Consideration of incentives in respect of how many patients to treat does not feature
greatly in traditional economic models of fixed price prospective payment systems.
From an economic perspective it is seemingly obvious that any payment system that
44
provides a surplus over marginal cost will provide an incentive to increase activity. In
many jurisdictions with an element of private provision market, imperfections that
give rise to excessive profits also generate strong incentives for investment in hospital
capacity, and so it is implicitly assumed that prices that provide a margin over cost
will provide an incentive to increased activity.
This idea of prices incentivising greater volume is clearly important in the context of
the NHS where waiting lists persist and it is one reason why PbR has been advocated.
It is tempting to conclude that PbR will incentivise activity across all HRGs because
prices are being set to reflect average costs and since those average costs include an
element of fixed cost recovery they will exceed marginal cost in most instances.
Hence, it might be argued, hospitals will wish to treat additional patients because the
benefit (price) will exceed the cost.
The formal model that we set out below demonstrates that the logic in the above
statement is flawed and thus suggests a number of further questions regarding PbR
and its impact upon volumes.
3.5.1 A model of volume choice in the presence of constraints
This section sets out a simple extension of existing theoretical models in order to
articulate the impact of PbR in the context of capacity constraints and choices
between supplying emergency or elective interventions.
The simplest case one in which the hospital faces, at least in the short run, a limitation
on capacity. The simple case ignores quality issues. When quality of service impacts
upon the likely demand for treatment, rational hospitals will wish to factor patients'
likely demand responses into their price cost margin calculations. Other things equal
this will increase the priority that hospitals place on HRGs where patients are
responsive to quality and may, therefore, reduce activity where patients are not
responsive.
45
The framework that we set out below is reasonably general and could be used to look
at other issues -- such as the incentive to allocate resources as between emergency and
elective HRGs, but we leave such extensions for future work.
We assume that the total costs that the hospital will incur in treating patients in two
HRGs can be written,
C ( x1 , x2 , q1 , q2 ) = c1 ( x1 , q1 ) + c2 ( x2 , q2 ) + F ,
(1)
where x1 , x2 denote the numbers of patients treated, q1, q2 denote the qualities of
service offered in each of HRGs 1 and 2 respectively and F is a fixed cost. The
functions c1 (.), c2 (.) are increasing in all arguments and convex. We assume that the
hospital has a fixed capacity X to treat patients so that it is required to ensure that
x1 + x2 ≤ X .
For subsequent analysis, it is useful to consider the definition and practical
measurement of average and marginal costs given C (.). The marginal cost of a
patient in HRG i is defined as
∂C ∂ci
≡
(which we abbreviate as cix ) and will
∂xi ∂xi
depend upon both the number of patients treated in that HRG and the quality of
service delivered i.e. qi . Because the hospital produces more than one type of output,
the definition of average cost is not so straightforward. On the assumption (embodied
in (1) of separability of variable costs between HRGs, the average variable cost of
HRG i is ci ( xi , qi ) / xi and is a function of the number of patients treated in this
HRG and the quality of service. A special case is where the function ci (.) is linear in
xi
-- here average variable cost equals marginal cost and is independent of the
number of patients treated (but both average and marginal cost remain functions of
quality). Average total cost cannot be defined without allocating the fixed cost, F ,
between HRGs. In preparation for PbR, hospitals have been required to produce such
an allocation and there are a number of plausible candidates (allocating fixed costs
according to the share in overall activity of each HRG; allocating fixed costs
according to the share in total variable costs of each HRG; allocating fixed costs by
reference to the value of central services that each speciality uses and distributing this
46
total to individual HRGs, and so on). Whatever the particular allocation of fixed costs
chosen, it breaks the link between average total and marginal costs, so that even in
the simplest case of linear functions ci (.) there is no obvious relationship between
average and marginal costs. The extent to which marginal and average costs will
differ will depend on numbers treated, quality of service and the specific convention
used in allocating fixed costs.
We consider a hospital that faces p1 and p2 for each patient that it treats in HRGs
1
and
2 . Henceforth, if HRG
i is an non-elective procedure8 we assume that the
hospital faces a fixed demand Di whilst if HRG i is an elective procedure the
hospital faces a demand function d i (qi ) which is increasing in qi . Finally, for the
purpose of examining the impact of the introduction of PbR we assume that prices are
set so as to be greater than marginal cost.
In the first instance, and for simplicity, we assume that the hospital is concerned with
maximising the surplus of its revenue over costs and thus the programme of the
hospital is,
max p1 x1 + p2 x2 − (c1 ( x1 , q1 ) + c2 ( x2 , q2 ) + F )
x1 , x2 , q1 , q 2
subject to
x1 ≤ d1 (q1 ) (or D1 ),
x2 ≤ d 2 (q2 ) (or D2 ),
X ≥ x1 + x2 .
It is perfectly possible to consider alternative specifications of objective for the
hospital but the surplus maximising formulation used here suffices to establish the
general point that choice of activity level under PbR depends in on the form of
constraint that the hospital faces. Indeed, a large number of cases can be considered
according to whether one or both HRGs are emergency or elective and according to
8
Here, and henceforth, emergency denotes only that patients are not considered to
respond to quality variations.
47
whether the demand and or capacity constraints bind. The essential flavour of the
results can, however be understood by reference to a small number of special cases.
Case 1: Emergency HRGs and excess demand
If we assume that both HRGs are emergency and that the hospital faces excess
demand in each HRG, it follows immediately that the hospital will wish to set the
minimal quality of service that it can. This is simply a consequence of quality being
costly and of there being no link between quality and revenue under our assumptions
regarding emergency HRGs. Hence the hospital’s programme simplifies to,
max p1 x1 + p2 x2 − (c1 ( x1 , q1 ) + c2 ( x2 , q2 ) + F )
x1 , x2
subject to
X ≥ x1 + x2 ,
where q1 , q2 denote the enforceable quality standards which are exogenous to the
hospital. Using λ to denote the Lagrange multiplier, the first order conditions for
this constrained optimization are either
p1 − c1x − λ = 0
p2 − c2 x − λ = 0
X = x1 + x2
or
p1 − c1x = 0
p2 − c2 x = 0,
depending upon whether the capacity constraint is binding or not.
It is suggested by Newhouse (2004) that the US Medicare system, at least at its
inception, was likely to be in the latter case, whereas there is some argument (the
existence of waiting lists) for assuming that the NHS is in the former case. There is an
important distinction between these two cases. In the capacity unconstrained setting,
PbR would constitute an incentive to expand activity across all HRGs because
whatever the allocation of fixed costs we might plausibly anticipate that prices
(reflecting average cost) will exceed marginal costs (at least in the special case of
linear variable cost functions). However, in the capacity constrained case, re-writing
the equation above to eliminate the Lagrange multiplier yields
48
p1 − c1x
= 1,
p 2 − c2 x
which indicates that hospitals will wish to equalise the margin of price over marginal
cost across different HRGs. This suggests that PbR will give an incentive to increase
activity in HRGs where the differential between price and marginal cost is initially
high and reduce activity in those HRGs where the differential between price and
marginal cost is initially low. As discussed above, since prices are set to reflect
average costs, the incentive towards either increasing or decreasing activity is a
function of the rule that was used by hospitals to allocate fixed costs. Suppose that for
whatever reason the rule adopted tended to over allocate fixed costs to HRG 1, then
by implication activity will be reduced in HRG 2 as a consequence.
This special case is potentially interesting but perhaps too simplistic. One expectation
of the PbR system is that it will cause hospitals to wish to attract more patients
through offering enhanced services. In such a setting it is not reasonable to treat
quality as reduced to its minimum. In the simple framework described in this section
we can understand the implications of variable quality by considering the case of
elective HRGs.
Case 2: Elective HRGs and satisfied demand
In the case where both HRGs are elective and where the number of patients to treated
equals the number presented for treatment (which we term satisfied demand in place
of excess demand) the hospital's programme can be simplified by explicitly replacing
numbers treated with demand and becomes,
max p1 x1 + p 2 x2 − (c1 ( x1 , d1−1 ( x1 )) + c2 ( x2 , d 2−1 ( x2 )) + F )
x1 , x 2
subject to
X ≥ x1 + x2 .
where d i−1 ( xi ) denotes the inverse of the function di (qi ), which gives the quality of
service that the hospital will have to provide in HRG i if it is to have xi patients to
treat. This programme is solved in terms of numbers treated and we have written the
programme in this way even though it might seem more natural to write it as a choice
of quality of service, in order to facilitate easier comparison with Case 1.
49
By analogy with the analysis for Case 1, there are two possible sets of conditions
characterising the solution to this programme depending upon whether the capacity
constraint is binding or not. These are,
p1 − c1x − c1q d1−x1 − λ = 0
p2 − c2 x − c2 q d 2−x1 − λ = 0
X = x1 + x2
or
p1 − c1x − c1q d1−x1 = 0
p2 − c2 x − c2 q d 2−x1 = 0,
The point to note about these conditions is the addition of the terms relating to the
derivatives of the inverse demand functions. They otherwise follow the conditions for
Case 1. The implication of these additional terms is that besides being concerned
about the margin of price over the marginal cost of treating an additional patient, the
hospital is now concerned about the margin over that cost plus the marginal cost of
the additional quality that will be required in order to attract that additional patient.
To understand the implication of these additional terms, it is instructive to consider
some alternative possibilities. If patients are better informed regarding the quality of
care on offer in HRG 1 than in HRG 2, they are likely to respond more vigorously to
quality variations in that HRG, this implies that the derivative of d1 (q1 ) with respect
to quality is likely to larger than that for d 2 (q2 ) and, thus, that the derivative of the
inverse demand d1−1 with respect to numbers treated is likely to be smaller than the
corresponding derivative of d 2−1. Other things equal, this suggests that PbR will give
an incentive for hospitals increase quality and activity in HRGs where patients are
responsive to quality and, at least where hospitals are capacity constrained, an
incentive for hospitals to reduce quality and activity in HRGs where patients are not
responsive to quality. Hence, we conclude that there is an incentive impact of PbR in
elective HRGs that depends purely on patient's responsiveness to quality variation --which may be quite different from a independent assessment of quality.
Case 3: A mixture of emergency and elective HRGs
We consider next the combination of HRG 1 being an emergency treatment for which
there is excess demand and HRG 2 being an elective procedure, which the hospital
50
can regulate demand for through its choice of quality of service. The hospital's
programme is now:
max p1 x1 + p2 x2 − (c1 ( x1 , q1 ) + c2 ( x2 , d 2−1 ( x2 )) + F )
x1 , x 2
subject to
X ≥ x1 + x2 .
The corresponding first order conditions are
p1 − c1x − λ = 0
p2 − c2 x − c2 q d 2−x1 − λ = 0
X = x1 + x2
or
p1 − c1x = 0
p2 − c2 x − c2 q d 2−x1 = 0.
Again the more interesting case is where the hospital is capacity constrained. The
conditions combine to give a requirement that
p1 − c1x
= 1.
p2 − c2 x − c2 q d 2−x1
Hence, consider the implications of consumers acquiring better information over time
regarding the quality of care offered in different hospital and thus becoming more
responsive to variations in demand. As discussed in Case 2, the implication of this is
cause the hospital to wish to increase the number of treatments in HRG 2 (by
increasing quality there) but to reduce the number of patients treated in the
emergency HRG 1.
The interdependency of treatment numbers across HRGs is a key element in the
analysis above. This combined with the fact the prices will be set to reflect average
costs, which in turn will reflect a possibly arbitrary allocation of fixed costs to
different HRGs, means that factors that impact on the incentives to increase or reduce
treatment numbers in a single HRG will have effects across all HRGs. The cross-HRG
incentive effect comes about in the framework above when an overall capacity
constraint binds --- which seems a reasonable starting point for describing a rationed
health care system which offers services that are free to users. However, it should be
noted that binding capacity constraints are sufficient but not necessary for this crossHRG effect. Any more general cost function that allows for the marginal cost of
treating a patient (or improving quality) in one HRG to depend upon the number of
patients treated (or the quality treatment) in other HRGs would have similar
51
implications. Given that production of hospital services is complex such
interdependence would seem generic. A restriction to just 2 HRGs is not restrictive
since the generalisation to many HRGs is obvious.
The presence of interdependency combined with prices that reflect average costs
rather than health care priorities suggests that purchasers of health care services who
wish to be pro-active in addressing health care concerns for their population will need
to approach the adoption of PbR with both caution and sophistication.
The simplest case to consider and describe is one in which hospitals `produce' many
treatments (HRGs) and face, at least in the short run, a limitation on capacity. In such
circumstances formal analysis suggests it is hard to avoid the conclusion that a
hospital will wish to reduce low value activities (those where price-cost margins are
comparatively small) in order to expand high value activities. The desire to maximise
surplus will lead to a tendency to wish to equate price costs margins. When, as under
PbR, prices are set to reflect average costs which include an allocation of fixed costs,
and there is no obviously correct way to allocate such costs, there is little reason to
suppose that the magnitude of price cost margins that will emerge under PbR will be
equalised by expanding all areas of activity. From the hospital’s perspective some
volumes will need to increase but other may need to decrease.
This theoretical model can be generalised to consider the role of quality of care and its
impact on demand. This adds another layer of complexity to the question of whether
PbR will provide incentives to increase or reduce volumes because the definition of
marginal cost needs to account for the quality of service that is necessary to sustain a
given volume of activity. For some HRGs (such as emergency treatments) it is
unlikely that this is a major consideration but for at least some elective procedures it
might be very important.
We thus conclude that economic theory suggest that the impact of PbR upon
treatment volumes across different HRGs is ambiguous and complex. Theory suggests
that for some HRGs there may be an incentive to increase the number of patients
treated, whereas for others there may be an incentive to reduce numbers.
52
3.6
Implications of increasing case-mix dependence
The basic framework of Section 3.2 can also be adapted to consider the role of greater
case-mix sensitivity. Once again fundamental issues can best be understood by
abstracting from the complexities of reality, where HRGs are used to separate
previous contracts into many separate payments, and here consider the implications of
separating the payment to a hospital into two HRGs (PbR) having started with a
single payment (pre-PbR).
The approach to this issue suggested by economic theory is to start by assuming that
the HRGs describe two different kinds of patients which for convenience we will
distinguish simply in terms of their cost of treatment i.e. high cost and low cost.
If we in addition, and again for simplicity, drop any consideration of quality the
expected (observable and unobserved) costs of treating, a randomly selected patient is
( βc h (e) + (1 − β )c l (e) + v(e)) where
β
is the proportion of patients in the population
that are the high cost type.
A first case to consider is where it is easy to distinguish between the two types of
patient. In such a setting there appears initially little difference between paying the
average price and separating out the price for high and low cost patients. Under both
systems the payer will have to cover the expected cost. But this assumes that the
hospital treats enough patients such that the average price covers its costs. If it is
unlucky in having a disproportionate number of high cost patients it will incur a
deficit and in order to prevent this the price may need to be set higher than
( βc h (e) + (1 − β )c l (e) + v(e)) . This suggests that one benefit of greater case-mix
sensitivity is that it facilitates lower prices overall. Those lower prices have to be
balanced again the greater complexity of payment and the necessity of determining a
greater number of prices.
Economists have been particularly interested in the further issues that arise when the
differences between high and low cost patients are not discernible to the purchaser.
This gives rise to hidden information and can be reflected in the assumption that only
the provider can determine whether a patient is going to be high or low cost.
53
Having a single price (PbR tariff) that covers the range of patients to be treated is still
perfectly feasible, but unless the price is set high enough the provider might choose
not to treat high cost patients at all. This is called dumping in the literature. Dumping
may not actually mean forcing people away but it may entail trying to persuade them
that they are better off seeking treatment elsewhere. Dumping can be avoided by
h
h
setting a price P = c (e) + v(e) and because this is a fixed price, there will be no
problem in terms of incentives for cost reducing effort. However, the purchaser will
be paying more than the actual costs that the provider incurs in treating patients h
l
when n patients are treated the excess payment will be n(1 − β )(c − c ). This sum
is a pure surplus for the provider.
This line of reasoning suggests that there may be a substantial benefit to greater casemix sensitivity but unfortunately from the perspective of practicality designing an
optimal payment system to account for hidden information is a complex task. Thus
whilst the benefits of greater case-mix sensitivity are increased by hidden information
so are the costs.
3.7
Summary - linking theory to qualitative and quantitative
evaluations
Quantitative evaluation
The discussion in Sections 3.2 – 3.5 has suggested a number of implications, based on
economic theory, of adopting PbR. In summary:
1. The reduced cost-sensitivity of payments implied by PbR is likely to be
associated with incentives to reduce unit costs. These unit cost reductions may
be either indicative of efficiency (increased cost reducing effort) or reduced
quality of care (or both).
2. Reduced cost sensitivity may give rise to incentives to reduce quality of care.
3. The increased volume sensitivity of payments implied by PbR has complex
and ambiguous effects upon incentives to increase or decrease volume /
54
activity. These effects depend upon the nature of treatments (emergency or
elective) and on the presence (or absence) of capacity constraints.
4. The increased case-mix sensitivity of payments under PbR may impact upon
the overall cost of service delivery but the effect is ambiguous – depending
upon how large the incentive under 1. above is and how large the
administrative costs of the PbR system.
Unit costs, quality and volume constitute potentially observable outcomes of health
care decisions, the first of these be proxied by LOS. Thus the theoretical framework
considered in this chapter provides a framework for considering the quantitative
impact of PbR in practice. As always the link between theoretical concepts and
observable anolgues is not perfect. We do not actually measure or observe quality of
care or even unit costs not at least in the sense that the theory defines them.
Nevertheless implications 2, 3 and 4 can be assessed in the light of quantitative
evaluation and the framework of this Chapter provides the conceptual basis for the
quantitative investigation that is described fully in Chapter 5.
This chapter also provides a conceptual basis for future quantitative work. A full and
detailed breakdown of the impact of PbR on an HRG-by-HRG basis is beyond the
scope of the present evaluation. It is, nevertheless suggested to be an important
element of a longer term evaluation because our theoretical framework suggests that
effects upon volume my vary HRG by HRG and there are a potentially rich set of
implications to be examined in this regard.
Possible future research would necessitate a consideration of the administrative costs
of different payments systems and an evaluation of the overall cost implications of
PbR. Given the time frame over which such overall costs might need to be measured,
this endeavour would present many challenges in terms of controlling for other
changes: controlling empirically for system change even over the short run is
problematic as the material in Chapter 5 makes clear.
55
Qualitative evaluation
Economic analysis rests on many assumptions. Some of these are discussed explicitly
but many are implicit. Thus almost all economic approaches presume that decision
makers are rational and perceive the environment in which they operate correctly and
that they have at their disposal the information necessary to make rational decision.
Economic analysis also mostly assumes that the objectives of decision makers are
exogenous to the system. Thus we have not considered the possibility that hospitals
change their objectives upon the introduction of PbR.
In considering a specific economic model of PbR we have further assumed that the
PbR as it is described in policy announcements is implemented as such: in particular
we have assumed that prices under PbR will be fixed in advance and not subject to ex
post negotiation.
There are further subtle assumptions that underpin analysis. Thus, for example, the
formal models assume that decisions are made in respect of a single time period. That
presumes that PbR is fully implemented at the time decisions are made and that
decision makers are not concerned about future changes or policy -- in the presence
of costs to changing their actions they may wish not to respond to perceived
temporary incentives.
The above may be considered as the preconditions for an economic analysis to be
valid and it is thus appropriate to consider the extent to which the economic
framework rests upon secure foundations. But these are not issues that are amenable
to a quantitative analysis, rather they are concerned with what economic agents think,
what they perceive and whether the policy has been implemented as planned and on
time. Thus, prior to subjecting the framework described in this chapter to quantitative
examination, in the next Chapter we summarise a survey-based qualitative
investigation that was designed to help place the theory described here in context and
further guide our quantitative approach.
56
Chapter 4. Qualitative analysis of Payment by Results
As discussed in Chapters 2 and 3, PbR constitutes a policy which is intended, through
a particular financing arrangement, to alter the decisions and outcomes of hospital
based health care in the NHS. In Chapter 3 the rationale for expecting PbR to
influence outcomes was set out in terms the impact of PbR on incentives. Economic
models make assumptions regarding the perceptions of decision makers, their
objectives, their understanding and beliefs about the payments system they are dealing
with and so on. A pre-requisite for the theoretical framework to be valid is that the
policy change is implemented as specified and that decision makers understand and
can respond to that. Thus, this part of our evaluation is concerned with describing the
implementation and perceptions of PbR as reported by the decision makers
themselves using an analysis based upon interviews of decision makers in the NHS.
In the remainder of this chapter we first consider the objectives of the interviews and
then outline the methods used and the development process for the interview
schedules. We then present the results of the interview analysis and relate them to
process of PbR implementation. We then draw on the analysis to revisit some issues
first raised in Chapter 3 and to illuminate issues that are subject to quantitative
analysis in Chapter 5.
4.1
Objectives
The qualitative analysis complements the quantitative analysis and has four
objectives:
1. To develop an understanding of how the PbR policy is perceived in the NHS
and whether those perceptions align with the assumptions of the theoretical
analysis,
2. To assess how PbR is being implemented in practice and whether it generates
the kinds of incentives that are suggested by the theoretical framework.
57
3. To identify perceived drivers of (and obstacles to) implementation, by drawing
on the experiences of key stakeholders in the implementation and application
of PbR policy.
4. To inform further development of the theoretical analysis of PbR and to
support and aid the interpretation of the quantitative analysis.
To achieve these broad objectives each round of interviews had specific objectives
relating to the developing policy and the adapting interests of the Advisory Group.
These are detailed in the methods section below.
4.2
Methods
Data for the qualitative analysis were collected in three rounds of semi-structured
interviews with key stakeholders in the NHS. Some of the same subject areas are
examined in more than one round but each round had a different emphasis reflecting
the embedding of the PbR in the NHS and the emerging findings in the quantitative
empirical work. The first round of interviews focussed on objectives (1) and (2), the
second on objectives (2) and (3), and the third round of interviews focussed on
objectives (1) and (3).
The purpose of the programme of interviews was, in each round, to try to elicit a
range of views existing among senior NHS staff – managers and clinicians, providers
and commissioners of care – rather than to determine the number of times particular
issues were raised by particular categories of interviewees in particular types of Trusts
or PCTs.
During the preparation stage of each round of interviews, the scope of the questions
and the categories of interviewees, were agreed with the DH advisory group for the
project. Ethical approval for the full programme of interviews was obtained in Spring
2005, on the basis that all interviews would be confidential and the individuals and
organisations contacted would be kept anonymous. In addition, the first round
interview instruments were piloted with a range of senior NHS managers to test the
practicality of the approach and the scope and format of questions to be adopted in all
three rounds.
58
Details of the objectives, sample of interviewees, method and results of each round of
interviews, are given in Appendix E. The following paragraphs provide an overview
of the method, and of how and why the three rounds of interviews differed from one
another and how they combine to cover the broad range of issues to be addressed.
4.2.1 1st round of interviews
For the first round of qualitative analysis, held during the summer of 2005, we sought
a total of 27 interviews with Directors of Finance at provider Trusts (‘First Wave’
Foundation Trusts and non-Foundation Trusts), PCTs and Strategic Health
Authorities (SHAs), Chief Executives at PCTs and SHAs, and Medical Directors at
Trusts. We were able to obtain interviews with 19 such individuals in total including
all of these categories and covering:
•
provision of secondary and tertiary care;
•
London, other urban areas and rural areas; and
•
Trusts with significant non-PbR income.
The questions asked in the round 1 interviews sought views from both commissioner
and provider perspectives on:
•
experience of the implementation of PbR up to summer 2005;
•
expectations and early experiences of PbR’s likely impact on activity,
efficiency and quality of care;
•
impact of PbR on relationships between NHS organisations within local health
economies; and
•
overall attitudes towards the PbR policy.
The results of the first round of qualitative analysis were reported to the Department
of Health in October 2005 (Farrar et al, 2005).
59
4.2.2
2nd round of interviews
The scope of the second round of interviews, to take place in 2006, was discussed and
agreed with the Department of Health in December 2005 and early 2006. In particular
it was agreed that it would be more useful to focus future interview rounds on
particular issues of interest.
It was agreed to concentrate the second round of interviews on the effects of PbR on
provider non-price competition and hence on the quality of care. Combined with
patient choice, PbR was intended to facilitate and stimulate quality-based competition
between providers and thereby yield improved quality. To avoid possible objection by
some NHS interviewees to the notion that they might be involved in competition, with
its implications of commercial practice that some in the NHS may consider to have no
place in health care, the questions were phrased in terms of attempts (successful or
otherwise) to expand or defend the scale and/or scope of activity at individual
providers.
Directors of Finance at provider Trusts (Foundation and non-Foundation) and
Directors of Commissioning at PCTs were asked about experience of the recent past
and expectations for the immediate future. At the Department of Health’s request,
particular attention was given to investigating the position of specialist hospital Trusts.
During summer 2006 a total of 28 interviews were sought and 18 were obtained,
covering 4 specialist and 12 general acute Trusts plus 2 PCTs.
The low PCT
representation was not surprising, due to the major reorganisation of PCTs that took
place in mid-2006, including a halving of their total number.
The results of the second round of qualitative analysis were reported to the
Department of Health in autumn 2006. They are described in Appendix E to this
report.
4.2.3 3rd round of interviews
In discussion with the Department of Health in early 2007, it was agreed to focus the
third round of qualitative analysis, in May and June 2007, on:
•
coding within Trusts – how it is being done, how it has progressed over time,
any difficulties remaining to be resolved;
60
•
use of PbR within Trusts to incentivise directorates and teams;
•
revisiting some of the questions asked in the first round, concerning the impact
of PbR on activity, efficiency, competition and quality, and on the local health
economy overall. The aim of this part of the interviews was to see whether a
different and/or more sophisticated response to the reforms was discernible.
As before, the organisations approached covered specialist and general Trusts, and the
PCTs that commission care from them, in three types of geographic area: London,
urban non-London, rural. We approached Directors of Finance, Clinical Directors and
Coding Managers in provider Trusts, and Directors of Commissioning and leading
practice-based commissioners (GPs) within PCTs. The response rate from Foundation
Trusts was very good but from other non-Foundation Trusts and PCTs was very low.
Consequently, the results of the third round of interviews, which are reported for the
first time at Appendix E of this report, are best seen as representing the experience
and views of NHS Foundation Trusts.
4.3
Understanding the process of PbR
4.3.1 Overview of PbR policy
When we undertook the first round of qualitative analysis, in the summer of 2005,
‘First Wave’ Foundation Trusts had a little over a year’s experience with PbR for
most of their elective and non-elective activity. Non-Foundation Trusts had just a few
months experience of PbR being applied to (much of) their elective inpatient and day
case activity, although more than a year’s exposure to the knowledge that PbR would
be applied to them and how that would be done. Given the newness of the policy,
some tentativeness might have been expected in NHS managers’ attitudes towards it.
Overall, we found evidence that attitudes range from support of the policy to
resignation with it as another task to be got on with, but there was no outright
opposition to the PbR policy. There were, however, numerous concerns with the
details of the mechanics of PbR and of its implementation. The overriding sense was
of coping with a new set of rules and processes.
61
By the time of our third round of interviews two years later, in early summer 2007,
the attitude of coping had developed more into one of familiarity. PbR was accepted
as a given fact of NHS life. No respondent expressed a desire to return to the previous
system of sophisticated block contracting.
Guidance
There was a mixed response in 2005 to the Department of Health’s role in providing
guidance and help with implementing PbR, ranging from the very positive to the very
negative. National guidance was generally found to be useful by respondents, though
considered to be a little slow in emerging in some cases. A recurring suggestion at
that point was that the Department of Health team responsible for implementing PbR
had been too small for the scale of its task. PbR was also seen in the NHS as largely a
finance management system, with little obvious medical input or relevance. Given the
fundamental nature of the PbR reform, the (centrally determined) pace of its
implementation was often, though not always, viewed as too fast by NHS managers.
Tariff
The national tariff for activity included within PbR has been a major focus of
discussion within NHS circles. The tariff is complex, covering 550 HRGs for
inpatient and day case activity with different elective and non-elective prices and per
diem rates for long stayers, plus 39 outpatient specialties, and several different A&E
attendance prices; all combined with Trust-specific market forces factors. Despite this
complexity, a common view heard in the 2005 interviews was that the tariff required
considerable improvement.
The tariff is based on estimates of national average costs of activity taken from the
NHS Reference Costs for England. Some first round interviewees identified the
quality of the cost data underlying the tariff as poor. Prior to the introduction of PbR,
respondents thought that Reference Costs data were not greatly used by individual
NHS organisations and that as a result they put correspondingly little effort into
ensuring the accuracy of the recorded cost data. However, respondents expected the
quality of the cost data to improve now that there was a stronger reason for Trusts to
commit effort to do so.
62
A criticism heard several times in the 2005 interviews was that the HRGs and their
prices presented in the tariff did not appear to correspond to the costs of what the
Trusts’ clinicians considered they were providing. Similar comments were heard
again, though only from two respondents, during the second round of interviews, in
2006. The Version 4.0 HRGs upon which the tariff is expected to be based from
2009/10 onwards are more disaggregated (increasing the number of HRGs from
around 700 to over 1000) and so may be expected to deal with at least some of such
complaints. The scope for unbundling tariffs, which has been made more explicit
since 2005 (Department of Health, 2005), may also help, as proposed by some round
1 interviewees.
The market forces factor came in for two broad criticisms during the 2005 interviews.
First, some thought it exaggerated labour cost differences across England as a result
of being based on private sector pay rates, whereas NHS pay rates are more uniform.
Second, the magnitude of the Market Forces Factor for an individual Trust could vary
significantly and unpredictably from year to year, making financial planning very
difficult. These may be misunderstandings of how the Market Forces Factor is
intended to work and its stability. However, what is important here are the
respondents’ perceptions and how that affects the way in which they respond to the
tariff.
The lack of credibility, for some, of the tariff as not truly reflecting in their view the
activity they were undertaking for patients, combined with fears about its volatility
from year to year, were found to undermine its usefulness as a basis for planning
service development (or disinvestment) decisions by Trusts.
A number of respondents in the first round of interviews suggested that an
independent body, not the Department of Health, should set the tariff. Sir Ian
Caruthers commissioned the Lawlor report (2006) into the process of setting the tariff
in 2006/07. The subsequent governance arrangements for the tariff setting process
may address some of the respondents’ concerns here through the proposal of a more
transparent
and
accountable
delivery
process.
http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Policyandguidance/Organisationpolicy/Financeandplanning/
NHSFinancialReforms/DH_072533.
63
Risk
Most respondents in 2005 spoke of dramatically increased financial risk being a
consequence of the introduction of PbR. This applied to Trusts but especially to PCTs
as their income is fixed. They expressed that did not have direct control of the volume
of activity. Methods for managing the extra risk seem to revolve around codes of
conduct agreed between Trusts and PCTs. We were given little evidence of the
development of comprehensive systems to effectively manage risk. Examining this
issue in isolation, Mannion and Street (2005) found evidence of several different
systems being implemented in South Yorkshire but no overall strategy for the region.
Such arrangements have since been supported by the publication of a code of conduct
following a public consultation in 2005 (Department of Health, 2006).
Coding
We asked high level questions about experience of coding activity during the first
(2005) round of interviews and then returned to the subject in more detail in the third
(2007) round – see Appendix E. In 2005 we found that, although Trusts have been
coding activity for many years, the introduction of PbR had made coding the focus of
rather more attention by Trust management than previously. The same point was
repeated by the coding managers we interviewed in 2007.
In the first round interviews we heard complaints that the quality of discharge
summaries – the basic raw material from which clinical coders have to work – was
sometimes poor and that more, senior, clinician attention to writing them was needed.
We did not hear such complaints two years later.
PbR had led to increased staffing in all the five coding departments where we
interviewed during round 3 of the qualitative analysis. Costs of coding had
consequently increased since the introduction of PbR, but not dramatically. The
average cost of coding per patient episode appears to be of the order of £3 currently,
which implies that across England as a whole, clinical coding is costing hospital
Trusts of the order of £45 million per year. (This excludes the costs of checking
coding incurred by commissioners of care).
64
All five coding managers interviewed in 2007 reported that their staff were coding
episodes more fully than pre-PbR; entering all relevant conditions and procedures
rather than just the main ones. Only one of the coding managers reported – in our
confidential interviews – being put under any pressure to adjust their coding practice
in order to favour the Trust financially, and they said they had resisted that pressure.
Another of the five said that in the rare cases of doubt about how to code they would
err in favour of the Trust, and another did consider it possible that occasional
“overcoding” might happen. All five referred to professional integrity among coders;
a determination to keep to the rules and not to risk the reputation and credibility of
their Trust’s coding of activity. Two of the Directors of Finance we interviewed also
volunteered that it would be counterproductive to risk ‘gaming’ and as a result be
thought of as untrustworthy.
External validation of activity data, principally by the PCTs who have to pay for the
work they are invoiced by provider Trusts, remains patchy. From the 2007 round of
interviews, external challenge to Trusts’ clinical coding seems rare. But validation of
the administrative aspects of coding is common: e.g. is that patient a resident of the
catchment area of the PCT being billed for their care, or on the list of the GP practice
being charged for it against their practice-based-commissioning indicative budget.
Administrative error rates of around 2-2.5% were reported by interviewees. This was
activity whose existence and nature were not being disputed, merely who was
responsible for paying for it.
As a result of an Audit Commission investigation in 2006, which found what they
considered to be “a relatively high level of clinical coding error”, an external audit
programme is being rolled out across the NHS in England from April 2007 (Audit
Commission, 2006).
Using PbR within Trusts
PbR operates at the level of Trusts and PCTs. As part of the third (2007) round of
qualitative analysis we sought information on the ways in which Trusts pass on the
activity, efficiency and quality incentives potentially implied by PbR to the clinicians
and others who actually see the patients. All the hospital Trusts where we interviewed
have an organisation structure that includes a number of separate Clinical Directorates,
65
each with their own budgets. In all of the Foundation Trusts where we could obtain
interviews these budgets include income and expenditure, so that the Directorate has a
particular net expenditure/income target for the year. In the one non-Foundation Trust
where we interviewed in 2007 the Directorates had budgets only for expenditure.
Where income is included in Directorates’ budgets, this includes both PbR and nonPbR revenues. Each Directorate has a planned level of activity and corresponding
planned income. If the Directorate’s outturn activity and hence the revenue it earns
the Trust, differ from plan then there is no automatic feed through of (all of) the
resultant excess/shortfall from the Trust as a whole to the Directorate. But there is a
presumption that a pre-set proportion of any surplus income may be retained and used
within the financial year by the Directorate that generated the income.
One respondent described the system used in his trust. Surpluses/deficits are not
allowed to be carried over by Directorates from one year to the next and the
proportion of any surplus revenue in-year that a Directorate may be allowed to retain
varied between Trusts from 40% to 70%. The interviewee explained that in each case
the remaining money goes into a central pot held by the Trust as a whole. A surplusearning Directorate will, however, not see any of the surplus it earns if the money is
needed to offset deficits in other parts of the Trust. For this Trust, therefore, there is
no automatic relationship between Directorate activity and income.
Within a Directorate there are numerous clinical teams at work. At no Trust where we
interviewed were individual teams being promised a proportion of any extra income
the Trust earns as a result of extra activity they do, to spend at their team’s discretion.
Thus we found no high powered financial incentives for clinical teams in Trusts to do
more work under PbR. However, the majority of Finance and Clinical Directorate
interviewees reported that PbR had contributed to a “more business like” attitude
among consultants and other Trust staff, with greater recognition of the link between
the work they do and the financial consequences for the Trust as a whole. This
reinforces a similar attitudinal change reported in the earlier rounds of interviews.
66
4.3.2
Incentives and Disincentives
The measured impact of PbR in the period up to and including 2005/06 on activity
levels, efficiency and quality of care, has been estimated quantitatively and is
presented in later sections of this report. Those sections also refer to findings from the
interview programme that concern PbR’s impact on hospital activity, efficiency or
quality. In addition, as part of our qualitative analysis, we also asked NHS managers
about the incentives and disincentives PbR was creating for their organisations,
including those whose effects (if any) would be hard to detect from the quantitative
analyses we have undertaken. These (dis)incentives concern: the care setting;
changing the mix of services provided; service developments; and patient selection.
Care setting and care pathways
Where such incentives and disincentives were discussed by interviewees, they
concerned effects on willingness to change the pattern of care provision. In the first
round of interviews (2005) and again in the third round (2007) we heard that while the
design of the tariff encourages hospitals to treat patients on a day case basis rather
than as inpatients (because the price is the same but day cases should cost provider
Trusts less), the tariff discourages moving patients from a day case to an outpatient
basis because the price per outpatient attendance is much lower than for a day case
admission. Similarly, at two different Trusts in the third round of interviews we heard
that creation of ‘one-stop shops’ for patient diagnosis and outpatient consultation was
considered by the Trusts’ managers to be disincentivised by the loss of tariff revenue
consequent on reducing the number of outpatient attendances.
A general disincentive for hospital Trusts to move care settings out of hospital and
nearer to patients’ homes – because of the consequent cut in revenues – was also
noted by a small number of interviewees. Although the corollary of this is that PCTs
have a clear incentive under PbR to encourage such changes in care setting, it is
usually the hospital Trust and not the PCT that employs the consultants who
determine how and where patients receive specialist health care.
Inflexibility over the care setting is particularly a problem for chronic, as opposed to
acute, care. One Medical Director we interviewed in 2005 described this potential
67
impact of PbR as “a retrograde step for chronic disease management”. However, such
concerns as were expressed seemed to be over the potential for problems arising
rather than the existence of problems already. Despite the confidential nature of the
interviews, no-one expressed the view, or cited any examples, that patient care was
being detrimentally affected by PbR in practice. Thus the first round of interviews
revealed a small number of concerns about the potential for PbR to have an
undesirable impact on long-term care pathways.
In the third round of interviews, two respondents identified the discouragement to
innovation that PbR causes where that innovation leads to an increase in costs in any
year, as the tariff price for the care will not vary according to whether or not the
innovation is used. There is scope for Trusts to try and negotiate with PCTs extra
payments to cover such extra costs but PCTs are not obliged to accede.
Service mix
It might be expected that provider Trusts would respond in some way to the price
signals given by the national PbR tariff even if their overall capacity were constrained
by difficulties in recruiting additional key staff or lags in investing in additional
physical capacity (buildings, plant and equipment). Trusts might be expected to
change the mix of services they provide with the limited resources they have
available: expanding activity in areas where their costs would be furthest below the
tariff price – i.e. where the financial surplus earned would be greatest – by switching
resources out of activities where their costs most exceed the tariff price or where the
surplus available is smaller. This incentive is discussed in the “Theoretical
Framework” section of the report.
In the first round of interviews (2005) we heard fears, but no evidence, from one PCT
manager that a local Foundation Trust might respond to the PbR in this way. No other
interviewee suggested it would happen. By the third round of interviews (2007) there
remained no Trust respondents who thought that their Trust had changed the mix of
its services by switching resources from less- to more-financially advantageous areas
of care. Reasons given in 2005 for this apparent lack of interest by Trusts in adjusting
their service mix to improve their financial position in response to the tariff’s price
signals included fears that prices were volatile and could change substantially from
68
year to year, and belief that the Trust’s cost information was too unreliable as a basis
for such decisions. Fears of price volatility were still being raised by interviewees as a
deterrent in the third (2007) round.
Service developments
The overriding response in the first interview round was that service developments
would only be considered by Trusts after discussion with the main PCT(s) affected.
Unilateral action by Trusts, even Foundation Trusts, was not generally expected. But
we heard from both PCT and provider Trust sides the belief that PbR made it simpler
to build business cases for new or expanded services, or for withdrawing patients
from existing services, because the revenue or expenditure-saving consequences of
doing so have become clearer, rather than being a matter for negotiation between
PCTs and Trusts.
The lack of action on service developments may partly be explained, as for the case of
changes to service mix, by fears that PbR tariff prices will change significantly in
future, reinforced by a feeling that the prices seem divorced from the costs of any
individual Trust’s actual costs for a particular activity. Unwillingness, on these
grounds, to make costly decisions on the basis of tariff prices was revealed in all three
rounds of interviews.
Relationships within local health economies
The prevailing attitude evident in 2005 and still apparent in 2007, shared by Trusts
and PCTs, was to maintain good relationships between providers and commissioners,
and recognise the implications of the finite nature of PCT resources. “We are all in
this together” was a common attitude. Bankruptcy of any party was deemed pointless
and something to be avoided to the extent that the prospect of bankruptcy for any
party was seen by other organisations as a constraint on their own actions. The
constraint on increasing activity that is imposed by limits in PCT funding was still
being highlighted by provider Trusts in the 2007 interviews. The view which could be
summarised as “there is no point bankrupting the local PCT” was still heard, although
there were greater signs than previously of one or two Trusts taking the initiative to
expand the scope of their services.
69
Patient selection
In 2005 we obtained a mixed response to questions of whether Trusts would focus on
lower cost patients within HRGs and try to avoid the more complex/costly cases. One
respondent considered such behaviour to be “counter-cultural” in the NHS, but
another thought their Trust might withdraw from complex joint-replacement revisions
if PCTs would not provide additional funding above the tariff price to cover the extra
costs of such cases. No patient selection was identified by any respondent as taking
place in practice.
4.3.3 Competition
We focused the second round of interviews, in 2006, specifically on whether
managers at Trusts and PCTs saw PbR as having influenced the degree of competition
among NHS providers and between NHS Trusts and independent sector providers.
We also asked more general questions in the 2005 and 2007 interview rounds about
experience and expectations of competition.
Prices are fixed. Hence policy makers had hoped to stimulate non-price competition
on the basis of service quality, given the scope for patient and referrer choice to result
in higher quality providers being able to attract more patients and so earn higher
revenues:
“We envisage that introducing a national tariff, which fixes prices for services,
should enable commissioners and providers to focus more sharply on quality
instead of time-consuming negotiations about price. This in turn should allow
providers to compete on the basis of quality to patients, which should have the
effect of improving quality of services across the system.” [Paragraph 51 of:
Department of Health (2003) ‘Response to Reforming NHS Financial Flows’
Department
of
Health:
London;
available
at:
http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Consultations/Responsestoconsultations/DH_401703
5]
In the 2005 interviews we found little expectation of PbR stimulating greater
competition between providers. Cooperation was emphasised by most respondents,
70
rather than competition. We found much the same in 2006, when just four out of 18
respondents identified active competition taking place for any of the services they
provide. An urban Foundation Trust and nearby PCT both identified active
competition generally in their locality; two other Foundation Trusts, one urban and
one rural, highlighted small numbers of specialised tertiary services for which they
felt they were actively competing with other NHS providers. However, no interviewee
mentioned any particular efforts by their Trusts to improve service quality so as to
attract more patients and hence revenue, although a small number referred to efforts to
reduce waiting times in order to defend existing services.
A number of reasons were offered by respondents in our 2006 qualitative analysis for
a lack of interest in competition. These confirmed the rationales put forward by
respondents the previous year. Four sets of reasons were each mentioned several
times:
•
planning – half of all respondents, from a wide mix of organisation types,
stated that service changes had to be planned together with local PCTs;
•
constrained demand – local PCTs were in some places seen as having
insufficient financial flexibility to pay for more PbR activity even if it were
done, combined with a wish by providers not to “bankrupt” PCTs;
•
geography – large distances between NHS hospitals was cited by all the nonspecialised rural Trusts, but by none of the urban Trusts, as a factor limiting or
preventing competition for secondary (i.e. not tertiary) services. A rural,
specialised Trust cited geography as preventing it for competing for routine
secondary work, but none of the specialised Trusts gave geography as a limit
to competing for tertiary work;
•
local NHS providers are at full capacity or there is excess demand – was given
as a reason a few times.
Other barriers to competition between NHS hospital Trusts were also mentioned in
one or two interviews in each case:
71
•
PbR tariff unstable – two respondents stated that their (urban, non-Foundation)
Trusts would not base investment or disinvestment decisions on the tariff
alone, relative to costs, as prices might change unpredictably in future;
•
risk aversion – two other interviewees, from urban Trusts (one Foundation,
one non-Foundation) considered that their Trust would not invest in increased
capacity in order to take on more work, because of the risk that the extra
investment costs (capital and staff) would not be justified by the additional
amount of activity that materialised;
•
unassailable reputation – respondents from two urban non-Foundation Trusts
(one of them specialised) and from a PCT local to the non-specialised Trust
stated that the local reputation of their hospitals and consultants was so high
that patients chose to come to them without any need for the Trusts actively to
compete to win work;
•
“the Department of Health does not want to let the market rip” – The Director
of Finance of an urban Foundation Trust stated that they did not believe that
the Department of Health wanted them to compete aggressively and that they
would be penalised if they did.
In the third round of interviews we were told for the first time of a clear example (but
only the one example) of quality-based competition stimulated by PbR. A Foundation
Trust had employed two specialist back surgeons with the intention of substantially
increasing their share of the regional market for back surgery, in which currently
much of the work is undertaken by non-specialist surgeons in a number of other
hospitals. The pitch to referring clinicians was thus along the lines: “send your
patients to a specialist, not a generalist”. Much more common, however, was a
continuing view that competition between NHS hospital Trusts was not particularly
active or large scale.
In all three rounds of interviews, the response of NHS managers to the issue of
competition between NHS Trusts and independent sector providers of hospital care
was that it did not occupy a great deal of their thoughts or time. To the extent that
independent sector competition existed the general NHS view was that independent
72
providers were specially favoured to such an extent that competition with them could
not be on a fair basis. The reasons cited for this perception of unfair competition were:
•
cherry picking – the independent sector is able to cream off the easier cases
within an HRG, leaving more costly to treat patients for the NHS;
•
higher prices – independent providers are paid at above-tariff rates;
•
take-or-pay contracts – PCTs are forced to pay for activity contracted from
independent sector treatment centres regardless of the number of patients
actually treated;
•
no disruption from emergency caseload as independent providers treat only
elective patients;
•
teaching and training costs – are borne by NHS Trusts but not by independent
providers.
4.4
Perceptions, implementation and the outcomes of PbR
The above section illustrates with examples how the cultural and market
characteristics of the NHS in England and technical aspects of PbR are shaping the
response of some of the key stakeholders to the introduction of the new financing
arrangements. Throughout, respondents make reference to a lack of certainty about
the pricing system and how prices might change in the medium and a lack of
information about their own Trusts cost structures. In addition, although the Trusts do
not explicitly discuss their objectives (and neither would we expect them to), there is
a concern for the broader local health economy. The PCTs appear to have limited
capacity to address issues around demand management and some provider Trusts
report that they experience both capital and labour constraints in their decisionmaking. These characteristics are likely to affect the key stakeholders’ ability and
motivation to respond to the incentives provided by PbR.
Nevertheless there would to appear to be an increasing understanding of the nature of
PbR as an incentive mechanism and an acceptance that it is an established part of
policy. Thus, in terms of the economic framework discussed in Chapter 3, the
preconditions for PbR to be able to affect outcomes through incentives appear to be
firmly in place.
73
In Chapter 3 we identified predictions on the basis of economic theory concerning
unit costs, volume of activity and quality of care. These outcomes are the subject of
our extensive quantitative analysis in Chapter 5. We conclude this chapter by
reviewing what respondents thought about the link between PbR and outcomes.
4.4.1 Cost Efficiency
Our economic framework identifies reductions in unit costs as one potential effect of
PbR. One mechanism for lowering cost is greater efficiency, a term which is common
in discussions about health care delivery. One of the policy intentions behind PbR was
to reward efficiency (Department of Health (2002) ‘Reforming NHS Financial Flows:
Payment by Results’. Department of Health: London – see for example paragraph 3 of
the Executive Summary). The idea that the NHS in England was ‘already efficient’
was made several times in each round of the qualitative analysis we undertook (see
Appendix E) suggesting that our subjects did not expect to see further cost reductions,
at least not through efficiency savings, as a consequence of PbR.
Indeed on the basis of the responses of those interviewees, it might be expected that
PbR would not change incentives relative to those that already existed: principally
through the elective waiting time targets – mentioned frequently by interviewees –
and the penalties for failure to achieve financial break-even.
4.4.2
Activity and volumes
We asked interviewees in all three rounds of qualitative analysis about their
perceptions of whether and how PbR was affecting the volume of activity undertaken
in their local health economies. Most respondents identified increases in activity but
were inclined to attribute this to continuations of past trends and to the pressure to
reduce waiting times for elective care. A few respondents took the view that, because
in their case the hospital’s capacity was already fully used or the ability of local PCTs
to pay for more work did not exist, they were trying to discourage rather than
encourage increased activity. Trusts and PCTs were discussing demand management
tools in some areas.
74
Overall there was little reporting of providers seeking unilaterally to boost their
activity in order to increase their PbR revenues.
4.4.3
Quality of care
When we first interviewed NHS managers, in summer 2005, their expectations with
respect to the impact of PbR on the quality of patient care were quite varied. Some
feared PbR might damage patient quality, or at least deter improvements, in some
places because of the need to keep costs below the nationally fixed tariff level. One
interviewee feared that because the PbR tariff is based on national average costs it
would produce “average quality services”. Others expected no impact on quality. But
none considered that PbR was at that early stage stimulating Trusts to compete on
quality. This view continued to predominate during our 2006 round of interviews.
We repeated our questions, although to a different set of interviewees, about the
impact of PbR on quality when we undertook the third round of qualitative analysis in
2007. We asked Trust and PCT managers, including clinicians, whether PbR appeared
to be affecting quality in either direction. No one thought that PbR was having an
overall impact on quality in either direction, but we did hear occasional individual
examples of both kinds of impact: quality improvements and quality reductions.
One Foundation Trust had employed two specialist back surgeons in the hope of
increasing their share of the regional market for back surgery, in which much of the
work was being undertaken by non-specialist surgeons in other hospitals. The pitch to
referring clinicians was thus to: “send your patients to a specialist, not a generalist”.
This was a recent innovation and it was not yet clear how successful it would be.
In the other direction, we were told by the Commissioning Director and a practice
based commissioning GP at one PCT of an acute hospital that had been using
specialist nurses to provide some diabetes, respiratory and TB care services in the
A&E department but that the PbR payments for A&E attendances were insufficient to
cover the costs, so the specialist nurses were being withdrawn.
In summary, our interviewees were broadly sceptical that PbR would have real effects
of the kind hoped for by policy-makers or predicted by economic analysis. Whether
75
their scepticism is justified can be assessed in the light of the quantitative analysis that
we report in the next chapter.
76
Chapter 5. Quantitative analysis of Payment by Results
In this chapter we present the quantitative analyses. We begin with the objectives and
a summary of international evidence followed by a description of the analytical
method. We then present the results of this extensive econometric analysis in five
sections. These are: the results on the admissions data relating to efficiency; the
results on the admissions data relating to volume changes, the results on the
admissions data relating to the quality of care; the results on outpatients data relating
to changes in volume and; the results on specific HRGs relating to volumes, casemix
and coding.
5.1
Objectives
The objective of the quantitative analysis is to estimate the effects of the introduction
of PbR on key outcome measures that relate to the policy objectives and test the
expected effects identified in Chapter 3, section 3.7. To this end, we use the most
appropriate outcome measures and an analytical framework appropriate for policy
evaluation.
In this section we outline our choice of variables and explain the analytical framework
and econometric techniques employed.
5.2
International experience
There is an empirical literature on the effects of prospective case mix based payment
systems on key outcome measures in the provision of health care services. These have
been reviewed and summarised in a number of journals and books. The reader
requiring a detailed account is directed to these 9 . The key messages from this
literature and those from the limited empirical evaluation of PbR are summarised in
this section.
9
See Sussex and Street (2005), Department of Health (2002) Annex 2, Chalkley and Malcomson
(2000) and Donaldson and Gerard (2004) chapter 8.
77
An activity-based finance system using Diagnostic Related Groups was first
developed in the US and used to pay hospitals as part of the publicly funded Medicare
program in 1983 (Newhouse and Byrne, 1988). Since then more than twenty health
care systems in Europe, Australia, Asia and Africa have adopted similar DRG based
financing mechanisms (Roger-France, 2003).
The dominant motivation for adopting the system was to control costs and introduce
incentives to increase efficiency though some systems were also targeting waiting
times and in turn the volume of care (Kjerstad, 2003).
Unit cost reductions, as proxied by reduced length of stay, are a commonly observed
effect of the systems and, on occasion, quite dramatic reductions have been observed,
especially when examining the short run. However, some investigations of how those
reductions in length of stay have been achieved have warned, and found evidence, of
cost-shifting to other payers or parts of the health care system (Newhouse and Byrne,
1988). For instance, in Sweden a large reduction in average length of stay for
orthopaedic patients was accompanied by the transfer of patients to long-term care
settings (Mikkola et al, 2002).
The overall policy context has been found to be important in determining the effects
of introducing case-mix-based activity funding. In particular, the existing
remunerations system will determine the extent of slack in the system and hence the
opportunities for increasing efficiency and the rigidity of budgetary caps will affect
the overall impact on health care expenditure (Rae, 2005).
One of the concerns accompanying the introduction of activity-based funding for
hospital services is whether the ways that hospitals attempt to reduce their unit costs
will have an adverse effect on quality. Therefore, many studies have focussed on the
effects of DRG funding on the quality of care (Rosenberg and Browne, 2001).
There is less agreement on the effects of DRG-based financing on the quality of care.
A common theme within the literature is the inadequacy of using variables from
administrative data as measures of quality. Despite this, and in the absence of other
measures, the main outcomes used to measure changes in the quality of care are
78
mortality rates (before and after discharge) and readmission rates extracted from such
routinely collected data. Less commonly, patient surveys have been used (Ljunggren
and Sjoden, 2001). Evidence from the USA suggesting a negative impact on quality
of care following the introduction of activity-based financing has not been reproduced
for European countries adopting similar systems (Dismuke and Guimeraes, 2002).
However, whether these findings reflect the effects of the policy, the role of context,
or the inadequacy of the proxies for quality remains a debated issue.
Emerging evidence in England
There has been much commentary on the likely effects of the introduction of PbR in
England (See, for instance, Dixon (2004), Street and Sawson (2004) and Appleby and
Renu (2004)) and a limited amount of analysis based on empirical findings. These
have examined the impact on demand management, administrative costs and “HRG
drift”, waiting times and the process of implementation.
Mannion et al (2006) examined the use of demand management methods following
the introduction of PbR and Patient Choice in South Yorkshire. They noted a rise in
acute elective and non-elective activity though the methods did not allow them to
attribute this to the introduction on PbR. The focus of the study drew on qualitative
data to conclude that there was no regional strategy for demand management. A range
of local initiatives for active demand management were identified and are being
monitored for their effectiveness. In the same paper the authors report increased
administrative costs associated with the new contracting process. Via interviews with
provider Trusts and Primary Care Trusts they estimated an increase in administrative
costs per organisation of £100,000 to £180,000 and £90,000 to £190,000, respectively.
Appleby et al (2005) used data from the first year of implementation of PbR
(2003/04) to examine whether there were increases in activity and associated
reductions in waiting times in the 15 HRGs subject to tariff. They also hypothesised
that low cost providers are more likely to respond to the incentive to increase activity.
They found that while there were increases in admissions in some of the 15 HRGs,
others experienced a fall; there was no association between waiting times and the use
of the tariff; and provider costs did not appear to affect their response to the incentives.
They did, however, attribute an increase in day case activity to the introduction of the
79
tariff. They point out in their paper a number of likely reasons for a lack of
association in most of their analysis: the small proportion of hospitals’ income
affected by tariffing the 15 HRGs at the margin; the effects of waiting time targets
‘swamping’ the PbR effects; and the lack of information on their own costs and
appropriate response to the financial incentives by the Trusts in this first year of the
tariff.
The Audit Commission (2005) drew mainly on qualitative analysis through interviews
with some additional basic analysis of 2004/05 activity data. Their three main
findings were that NHS organisations were broadly welcoming of the reforms, that
the reforms exposed existing weaknesses in organisations and local health economies
and that the costs of implementation were higher than expected (at around £100,000
per organisation), towards the lower end of the range reported by the respondents in
the study by Mannion et al (2006). They examined trends in the length of stay and
volumes of activity and found little impact other than a ‘marginal improvement in
length of stay’. However, they acknowledge that their methods make it difficult to
attribute the changes that they observe to PbR.
None of these existing studies have been able to isolate the impact of PbR from other
confounding causes of variation in health care outcomes. A key aspect of our
approach is to use the phased introduction of PbR and the Scottish hospital system as
controls for these other factors.
5.3
Key outcome measures
A range of outcome measures were chosen on two bases. First they were to relate to
the policy objectives identified in the Department of Health policy documentation and
technical guidelines. These related to the efficiency, volume and quality of care.
Second, they should include outcome measures that have been used in the DRG
evaluation literature to examine the experience of the introduction of similar policies
in other health care systems. The OHE review confirmed that the three broad outcome
measures (efficiency, volume and quality) were those most frequently analysed
elsewhere. Accordingly, we use a range of variables available in administrative data
sets.
80
5.3.1 Unit cost, length of stay (LOS) and incidence of day cases and outpatient
measures of efficiency
As noted in Chapter 3, LOS is generally considered to be well correlated with unit
costs and sensitive to changes in financing regimes (Donaldson et al, 2005). We note
that caution is needed in attributing any reduction in LOS to efficiency because it may
also be a reflection of reduced quality of care.
One limitation of using length of stay is that there may be unobservable differences in
resource use that relate more to the intensity of resource use during a patient’s stay
rather than its length (Chalkley and Malcomson, 2000). We use length of stay because
it allows us to control for variations in case-mix at patient level using Hospital
Episode Statistics10. The main alternative (Reference Costs) is potentially subject to
variations in accounting techniques and is not available on an individual spell basis.
In addition, we use the proportion of daycase activity as a measure of the unit cost of
care provision in the sense that an increase in the proportion of day cases is analogous
to reductions in LOS. This is also a measure of the change in the pattern of service
provision.
For outpatient activity we use measures of ‘did not attend’ and the return rate ratio
(the ratio of subsequent to first appointments) as measures of the efficiency of the
organisation of outpatient services.
5.3.2 Volume of care
We measure volume as the number of spells of care. This is the unit of reimbursement
under PbR.
We also use the change in the proportion of non-elective spells as a measure of a
change in the pattern of service provision.
We undertake work on the volume of outpatient attendances using first attendances,
all attendances and different sources of referral.
10
Detailed accounts of the derivation of all variables used in the analysis are given in Appendix A.
81
5.3.3 Quality of care
Finding an appropriate and sensitive measure of quality of care is a continual
challenge both for those wishing to regulate the supply of healthcare (Goddard et al,
2000) and for those attempting to evaluate the effects of policy on quality of care
(Chalkley and Malcomson, 2000). In the absence of direct measures of quality of care,
proxy measures are used. Two measures are most commonly used in hospital
financing research: mortality and readmissions.
We use two measures of mortality: in-hospital mortality, measured by proportion of
patients discharged as dead; and 30-day surgical mortality, measured by the
proportion of patients recorded as dying during the 30 days following a surgical
procedure in hospital. We anticipate that the 30-day mortality variable will be the
most robust: the level of in-hospital mortality can be affected by changes in the length
of stay which influences where a person dies rather than the quality of care they
receive.
We measure readmissions using the proportion of patients with an emergency
admission following treatment for hip fracture. This is an outcome measure that has
been used by regulatory bodies in the performance assessment of health care
providers (NHS Executive, 1998, Healthcare Commission, 2004, 2005). We use the
definition ‘Emergency readmissions to hospital within 28 days of discharge, as a
percentage of live discharges’ (Department of Health, 2002d). The rate of hospital
readmissions has been criticised as a measure of quality because a hospital finance
regime may provide incentives for providers of care to readmit patients and hence
increase revenue (Kjerstad, 2003). Although inconvenient to the patient, this would
not necessarily indicate that the first spell of care was of reduced quality. Furthermore,
for some patients, part of their care plan is to be discharged followed by a planned
readmission. Whilst we are unable to control fully for the potential for ‘supplierinduced’ readmissions, our use of emergency readmissions avoids counting planned
readmissions.
82
In addition to creating variables as proxies of quality from our patient level dataset,
we explored the possibility of using routinely collected provider-level information on
the quality of care. Data on performance measures are collated by the Department of
Health and Monitor as part of their monitoring and target setting activities. We chose
five diverse measures of performance which we might expect Trusts to try to improve
to attract patients. These were the rate of Methicillin Resistant Staphylococcus Aureus
(MRSA) as a proportion of bed days, the proportion of cancelled operations, the
number of emergency readmissions, hospital 30-day mortality following surgery and
proportion of inpatients waiting less than 6 months.
Details of the construction and source of all variables are given in Appendix A.
5.4
Method
Our evaluation challenge is to measure the effect of the introduction of PbR on
hospital behaviour. We seek to measure the effect of the policy on the targeted HRGs
and Trusts. We require estimates of what would have happened if the tariff had not
been introduced. We construct this control group using a ‘difference-in-difference’
framework (Blundell and Costa Dias, 2000). We compare the changes over time in
the outcome variables for HRGs funded by tariff with the HRGs not funded by the
tariff, before and after the tariff’s introduction.
This phased introduction of the policy represents a series of quasi-experiments. Since
there are several difference-in-differences available, it is important to choose control
groups that are most appropriate for the research questions being answered. If this
were an experiment, we would be interested in the effect of PbR on each outcome,
compared to a situation where PbR did not exist. This is the overall effect of PbR on
the whole ‘population’ of hospitals in England. Other effects of the policy might also
be of interest, such as the effect of PbR only for those hospitals where it was
introduced, or only for FTs, or only for those HRGs to which it was applied. These
are relevant in terms of the phasing in of PbR, and of the effects of PbR on particular
sub-groups, but less interesting in answering the main policy question of the overall
effect of PbR. In the face of these choices, we have used two criteria for selecting the
counterfactuals.
83
1.
The control group remains the same the year after the comparison
Work elsewhere (Croxson et al, 2001) has shown that providers of health care may
exhibit some form of anticipatory behaviour prior to the introduction of a policy.
Therefore, comparison with a group of HRGs that will become subject to the tariff in
the following year will not be an appropriate representation of what would have
occurred if the tariff had not been introduced. In general, it will underestimate the
effect of PbR as its impact on this potential comparator group may have begun in the
current year. Hence, to utilise the most robust difference in differences, where
possible we use controls which are ‘un-tariffed’ in previous years and the following
year.
2.
The tariff is applied in full not just at the margin.
In the first two years of the introduction of PbR policy, the tariff was applied only to
the subset of spells outside the Service Level Agreement (SLA) for small groups of
HRGs. The Hospital Episode Statistics do not identify whether spells were provided
outside the SLA. We anticipate that the effects of the tariff are weaker when applied
only at the margin. Further, effects on these ‘marginal’ spells will be diluted when
measured as part of all spells. Hence, we expect that the results of difference-indifferences that do not use these earliest applications of the tariff will provide a more
robust estimate of the policy’s effects.
We used these two criteria to select the most robust difference in difference analysis.
The opportunities for meeting both criteria lie with the later changes to policy, i.e.
when the tariff is applied to all spells provided by FTs in 2004/5 and to all elective
spells by NHS Trusts in 2005/6. For completeness, we also provide results of the
analyses of the earlier marginal applications of the tariff in Appendix C, Tables C5 to
C7.
The policy changes that we evaluate are:
a) In 2004/5 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions) provided by
Foundation Trusts. This included both elective and emergency spells.
84
We use this change in financing experienced by the FTs as the key to two DiD
analyses which meet the two criteria specified above. For each of the dependent
variables measuring volume, efficiency and quality of output we compare:
(i) tariffed output by FTs with non-tariffed output in the same HRGs by non-FTs
in England and
(ii) tariffed output by FTs with non-tariffed output in the same HRGs by providers
in Scotland.
We analyse changes between 2003/4 and 2004/5 to identify the effects in the first year
of the policy change. We also analyse changes between 2003/4 and 2005/6 to identify
longer-term effects for (ii).
b) In 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all (with some exceptions) elective spells but not
to non-elective spells by Non-FTs.
We use this change in financing experienced by the non-FTs as the key to two DiD
analyses which meet the two criteria specified above. For each of the dependent
variables measuring volume, efficiency and quality of output we compare:
(i) tariffed elective output by non-FTs with non-tariffed elective output in the
same HRGs by providers in Scotland and
(ii) tariffed elective output by non-FTs with non-tariffed non-elective output by
non-FTs.
We analyse changes between 2004/5 and 2005/6 to identify the effects in the first year
of the policy change.
We use the same DiD opportunities to analyse outpatients data and specific HRGs for
evidence of changes in coding or treatment patterns.
5.5
Econometric analysis
The majority of our analyses are undertaken at spell level. More details of the
econometric modelling for each variable are provided in Appendix B.
85
We use fixed effects to control for differences between the characteristics of HRGs
and Trusts that are unobserved but remain constant over time. Examples of such
Trust-level characteristics are management culture, teaching status, and local
population characteristics. HRG-level unobserved factors include specialty-specific
factors, patient demographics and case mix.
These unobserved factors are likely to vary both within Trust and within HRG. In
addition, particular Trusts may be more efficient at providing particular HRGs and
provide better outcomes and some HRGs will be highly specialised and will tend to be
provided by particular types of Trusts both before and after the policy change. Thus
we interact the two variables to create fixed effects for each combination of HRG and
Trust. There are 81,820 fixed effects in total. Inclusion of these effects ensures that
we model changes in efficiency and quality associated with PbR. Thus, we avoid the
attribution to PbR of differences between Trusts that determined whether they
received FT status. We also control for the characteristics of HRGs that determined
whether they were deemed suitable for inclusion in PbR.
5.6
Results
The results are divided into three sections. The first section presents evidence of the
effect that funding by tariff has had on unit costs by looking at trends in LOS and day
case incidence. The second section presents findings on revenue-raising activities
using changes in the volume of output and the proportion of non-elective admissions.
The third section presents the effect on the quality of care, using data on in-hospital
mortality, 30-day post surgical mortality and emergency readmissions for hip fracture.
We provide background context for the regression results by charting aggregate trends
for the Trusts that become Foundation Trusts (henceforth ‘FTs’) and the Trusts that
do not become FTs (henceforth ‘non-FTs’) by March 2006 and Scottish providers.
Following this, we present the econometric difference-in-difference (DiD) results.
We provide simple tables to illustrate the derivation of the DiD. The DiD values
adjusted for Trust and HRG fixed effects are generated from the econometrics models
86
described in Appendix B. Trusts in a DiD analysis are defined as FTs or non-FTs
according to their status in the final year of the specific DiD. Hence the results for
FTs in the forthcoming tables will differ across tables which show DiD with different
final years. At the end of each section we summarise the results and interpret our
findings using evidence from both the structured interviews and the econometric
analysis.
Within the main body of this report we have restricted the quantitative results to the
changes in policy which took place in 2004/5 and 2005/6. These provide the most
informative estimates of the effects of the policy. The results for the policy changes to
the 15 HRGs and 33 HRGs in 2003/4 and 2004/5 are in Tables C5 to C10 in
Appendix C.
5.7
Impact on unit costs
5.7.1 Length of Stay: general trends
Figure 5.1 shows trends in mean length of stay (LOS) for elective spells for non-FTs,
FTs and Scotland from 2001/2 to 2005/6. All Trusts in England have reduced LOS
during this period. FTs started at a lower LOS and the absolute reductions have been
smaller. Non-FTs have had steeper reductions in LOS each year with the exception of
2004/5 when LOS increased.
87
Figure 5.1
Trends in mean length of stay for elective spells in FTs, non-FTs
and Scotland
FT
Non-FT
Scotland
9
Mean length of stay (days)
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
The trend in mean LOS for non-elective spells has been downward for non-FTs and
FTs over the period 2001/2 to 2005/6 (Figure 5.2). By comparison, Scotland has
experienced a very small reduction. Mean LOS in Scotland is lower than both groups
of English Trusts at the start of the period. By the end of the period, mean LOS in FTs
is lower than in Scotland.
88
Figure 5.2
Trends in average length of stay for non-elective spells for NonFTs, FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
12
Mean length of stay (days)
10
8
6
4
2
0
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
5.7.2 Length of stay: difference in differences analysis
From the theoretical framework outlined in Chapter 3, we hypothesised that spells
which are funded by tariff would have greater reductions in unit cost and hence mean
length of stay. In this econometric analysis we model changes in the mean logged
length of stay to reduce the influence of large outliers.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts. This included both elective and non-elective spells.
Table 5.1 shows the mean logged length of stay in FTs and Non-FTs in 2003/4 and
2004/5. The third column of figures is the change in the mean logged length of stay.
On average, both types of Trust experienced a reduction in length of stay but, as the
difference-in-difference calculation shows, this was greater in the Non-FTs than the
FTs. This difference remains once we control for changes in the age-sex composition
of admitted patients and differences between Trusts and HRGs at baseline. The
89
difference in difference values are the difference in percentage changes in the mean
length of stay. The results are counter to the hypothesis that the tariff would be
associated with reductions in length of stay.
Table 5.1
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in mean logged length of stay (days),
2003/4-2004/5
2003/4
2004/5
Change in logged
Difference in change
LOS
in LOS
FTs
1.204
1.185
–0.019
Non-FTs 1.213
1.187
–0.026
Simple
Adjusted
+0.6%**
+0.5%**
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
In Table 5.2 we employ Scotland as the counterfactual. Here the reduction in mean
logged length of stay for the FTs is greater than for the providers in Scotland. This is
indicated by the negative DiD value. After controlling for changes in the age-sex
composition of admitted patients and differences between Trusts and HRGs at
baseline, the results show a reduction of 2.3 per cent in the average length of stay
associated with the application of the tariff.
Table 5.2
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in mean logged length of stay (days),
2003/4-2004/5
2003/4
2004/5
Change in logged LOS
Difference in change in
LOS
FTs
1.288
1.269
–0.019
Scotland
1.300
1.302
+0.002
–2.1%**
–2.3%**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes 15 HRGs.
Table 5.2 shows the change in length of stay for the first two years of tariff for FTs
and compares this with Scotland. FTs reduced length of stay more quickly. The DiD
is statistically significant whether or not we control for changes in age-sex
composition and differences between Trusts and HRGs.
90
Table 5.3
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in mean logged length of stay (days),
2003/4-2005/6
2003/4
2005/6
Change in logged
Difference in
LOS
change in LOS
FTs
1.294
1.257
–0.037
Scotland
1.305
1.299
–0.006
–3.2%**
–4.9%**
Difference in difference (simple)
Difference in difference (adjusted)
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes the elective 15 HRGs.
b) In 2005/6 the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some exceptions)
elective output provided by Non-FTs.
Table 5.4 shows changes in the length of stay for elective output compared to nonelective output (which was not covered by the tariff for Non-FTs in 2004/5). The
reduction was greatest in the non-elective output and this difference was statistically
significant in the unadjusted model. Once we control for changes in the age-sex
composition of admitted patients and differences between Trusts and HRGs, the result
is reversed: the negative and statistically significant DiD indicates that length of stay
fell faster for electives than non-electives for Non-FTs in 2005/6. Given that only
electives were being funded by the tariff this is what we would expect to see.
Table 5.4
Elective DiD with non-elective in mean logged length of stay (days)
for Non-FTs, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6
Change in
Difference in change in
logged LOS
LOS
Elective
0.944
0.919
–0.025
Non-elective
1.401
1.368
–0.033
+0.8%**
–0.7%**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes 15 and 33 HRGs.
Table 5.5 shows a smaller, though insignificant, unadjusted reduction in mean length
of stay for the Non-FTs in 2005/6 compared with Scotland. The DiD is negative and
significant once we allow for changes in the age-sex composition of admitted patients
and differences between Trusts and HRGs in the first year, 2004/5. The results
indicate that introduction of the tariff in 2005/6 for the Non-FTs was associated with
reductions in mean length of stay of 1.2 per cent.
91
Table 5.5
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in elective mean logged length of stay
(days), 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5
2005/6
Change in logged
Difference in
LOS
change in LOS
Non-FTs
0.944
0.919
–0.025
Scotland
1.371
1.338
–0.033
+0.8%‡
–1.2%**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes 15 and 33 HRGs.
We tested whether this change in length of stay of non-FTs differed by whether the
non-FTs reported Reference Cost Indices above or below 100 in 2004/511. We label
these ‘high-cost’ (>100) and ‘low-cost’ (<=100) Trusts. The results are shown in
Table 5.6. The high-cost Trusts have significantly higher mean logged length of stay
in 2004/5. Although the increase in length of stay was lower for the high-cost Trusts
than for the low-cost Trusts, the difference is not statistically significant. The model
that adjusts for changes in age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects shows no
significant difference between the high-cost and low-cost Trusts in the extent to which
average length of stay was reduced.
Table 5.6
High-cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low-cost Non-FTs elective mean
logged length of stay (days), 2004/5-2005/6
Difference in change in LOS, 2004/5-2005/6
Simple
Adjusted
–0.52%‡
–0.02%‡
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes 15 and 33 HRGs.
Table 5.7 shows non-FTs to have a reduction in length of stay in non-elective 2005/06
compared to an increase for Scotland. This difference remains once we have
controlled for changes in the age-sex composition of admitted patients and differences
between Trusts and HRGs at baseline and is statistically significant. The results
indicate that the introduction of the tariff in 2005/06 was associated with reductions in
non-elective length of stay for non-FTs of 3.9 per cent.
11
This analysis is restricted to non-FTs as this group of Trusts have sufficient variation in their
reported Reference Cost Index.
92
Table 5.7
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in non-elective mean logged length of
stay (days), 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5
2005/6
Change in logged
Difference in
LOS
change in LOS
Non-FTs
1.401
1.368
–0.033
Scotland
1.316
1.323
+0.007
–4.0%**
–3.9%**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes 15 and 33 HRGs
5.7.3 Day case rates: trends
Day case output by organisation
Throughout 2001/2 to 2005/6 the proportion of elective spells treated as daycases (the
daycase proportion) was higher in England than Scotland. Between the beginning and
end of the period the daycase proportion increased in all three types of organisation.
The increases in the daycase proportion for non-FTs occurred in the last two years of
the period. Increases were experienced in the first and the last two years in the FTs.
Figure 5.3
Trends in proportion of day cases by Non-FTs, FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
Daycase proportion of elective spells
72%
70%
68%
66%
64%
62%
60%
58%
56%
54%
52%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
93
2004/5
2005/6
5.7.4 Day case rates: difference in differences analysis
The tariff for inpatient and daycase spells for a given HRG are the same. However, it
is less costly for Trusts to provide care as a day case rather than keep a patient on the
ward overnight. The equality of the reimbursement for day case and inpatient
provision creates an incentive for Trusts to provide more day cases where possible
and appropriate. This was an explicit objective of PbR policy.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts.
In 2004/5 both FTs and in Scotland experienced an increase in the day case rate.
Using Scotland to represent the underlying trend, FTs had a larger increase in the
proportion of daycase activity by 0.5 percentage points, shown in Table 5.8. Once we
allow for changes in the age-sex composition of admitted patients and differences
between Trusts and HRGs in the first year, the difference remains statistically
significant and is 0.4 percentage points. The results indicate that introduction of the
tariff in 2004/05 for the FTs was associated with increases in the proportion of day
case provision of 0.4 percentage points.
Table 5.8
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in day case rates for all elective spells,
2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion
Difference in change in
of daycases
proportion of daycases
FTs
68.9% 70.3% +1.4 % points
Scotland 61.1% 62.1% +1.0 % points
+0.5 % points**
+0.4 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 HRGs.
Taking a two year view, Table 5.9 shows increases in day case rate for Scotland and
FTs from 2003/4 to 2005/6. The statistically significant results indicate that FTs
increased the day case rate more quickly over the period and that 1.5 percentage
points of that increase were associated with the introduction of the tariff.
94
Table 5.9
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in day case rates for all elective spells,
2003/4-2005/6
2003/4 2005/6 Change in proportion
Difference in change in
of daycases
proportion of daycases
FTs
70.2% 72.1% +1.9 % points
Scotland 59.2% 60.0% +0.8 % points
+1.1 % points **
+1.5 % points **
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant. ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 HRGs.
Table 5.10 shows the increase in daycase rates of FTs relative to non-FTs. Both types
of Trusts experienced growth in day case rates in 2004/5 of 1.4 percentage points.
Once we allow for changes in the age-sex composition of admitted patients and
differences between Trusts and HRGs in the first year, there is a difference of 0.4
percentage points which is statistically significant. The results indicate that
introduction of the tariff in 2004/5 for the FTs was associated with increases in the
day case rate.
Table 5.10
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in day case rates for all elective spells,
2003/4-2004/5
Difference in change
2003/4
2004/5
Change in
proportion of
in proportion of
daycases
daycases
FTs
70.9%
72.3%
+1.4 % points
Non-FTs 70.7%
72.1%
+1.4 % points
Simple
Adjusted
+0.0 % points‡
+0.4 % points**
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
b) In 2005/6 the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some exceptions)
elective output provided by Non-FTs.
The day case rate for Non-FTs grew more quickly than for providers in Scotland in
2005/6. After controlling for changes in the age-sex composition of admitted patients
and differences between Trusts and HRGs at baseline, the results show that growth in
the day case rate was 0.8 percentage points higher in Non-FTs compared to hospitals
in Scotland (Table 5.11). This higher growth in day care proportion for the Non-FTs
95
provides support for the hypothesis that Trusts will switch to day case provision to
save costs under the tariff scheme.
Table 5.11
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in day case rates for all elective spells,
2004/5-2005/6
2004/5
2005/6
Change in proportion Difference in changes in
of daycases
proportion of daycases
Non-FTs
71.0%
72.1%
+1.1 % points
Scotland
61.4%
61.6%
+0.2 % points
+0.9 % points**
+0.8 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs
Subgroup analysis
We tested whether this change in day case rate of non-FTs differed by whether the
non-FTs reported Reference Cost Indices above or below 100 in 2004/5. As before,
we label these ‘high-cost’ (>100) and ‘low-cost’ (<=100) Trusts. The results are
shown in Table 5.12. The high-cost Trusts have significantly higher day case rate. The
increase in day case rate was higher for high cost Trusts than for the low-cost Trusts
and the difference is statistically significant. The model that adjusts for changes in
age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects shows that high-cost Trusts increased
their day case rate by 0.25 percentage points more than low-cost Trusts in 2005/06.
Table 5.12
High-cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low-cost Non-FTs for day case rates,
2004/5-2005/6
Difference in changes in proportion of daycases
+0.22 % points**
+0.25 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
5.7.5 Summary of effects on unit costs
We have examined whether Trusts reduced unit costs, by reducing mean length of
stay or by increasing the proportion of elective spells treated as daycases, in response
to the introduction of the tariff in 2004/5 and 2005/6. We undertook six main tests on
mean LOS using non-FTs and Scotland as controls for FTs in 2004/5 and using
Scotland as the control group for FTs and non-FTs in 2005/6. We undertook a further
four tests of the effect on the proportion of day case activity. We also undertook
96
subgroup analysis to identify whether there were differences in changes in the unit
costs (LOS and daycase proportion) of high cost and low cost Trusts. A summary of
the results is presented in Table C1 of Appendix C.
Five out of the six tests on LOS, showed mean LOS to have fallen, compared with the
control group. These results support the anticipated effects of the PbR policy that unit
costs would be reduced as a result of the introduction of a fixed national tariff. This is
in line with effects observed in other health care systems. Reductions in unit costs
have been one of the most common findings of international research into the effects
of fixed price payment systems. Our findings suggest that PbR represented a stronger
incentive to unit cost reduction than those that existed within the financing system it
replaced.
Our analysis shows an increase in daycase rates associated with the introduction of
the tariff for all the tests undertaken. This result is consistent with the awareness we
found among interviewees of the unambiguous financial benefits of switching from
inpatient to daycase treatment. Increased daycase rates were stimulated by PbR
among both FTs and non-FTs, despite their already high daycase rates relative to
Scottish hospital trusts.
For the subgroup analysis, we found that high cost Trusts had higher increases in the
growth of daycase rates. However, there was no association between Trusts’ costs and
the effect on mean LOS.
One test, however, gave results counter to expectations. When we compared LOS for
FTs and non-FTs in 2004/5, we found that LOS fell more quickly for the non-FTs,
during a period when very little of their income was generated though the tariff. The
lack of support for the effect of tariff on length of stay in this test together with the
positive tests when Scotland is used as the control group suggests that there may be
other pressures on NHS Trusts in England to reduce unit costs. Reducing length of
stay has been implicit in the use of financial targets as part of performance
97
management in the NHS in its various guises 12 . (However it was not listed as a
specific target during the period of our analysis). Another explanation for this
exceptional finding could be that non-FTs in 2004/5 were working to reduce costs in
preparation for the known extended use of tariff in 2005/6.
These results from the quantitative analysis suggesting that PbR is having a
downward effect on unit costs may be seen as surprising for a number of reasons. Our
qualitative research revealed a majority view among the NHS managers we
interviewed that PbR was not adding significantly to the considerable incentives for
efficiency that already existed in England pre-PbR. The payment mechanism is being
applied within a health care system which has historically had fixed global budgets
and has previously implemented polices to reduce unit costs and increase efficiency
and meet financial targets in the form of nationally set performance indicators with
explicit rewards and penalties. Therefore, there may be less scope for significant
reductions in the unit costs of the provision of hospital care. Indeed drawing on the
qualitative results of this project, some interview respondents suggested that they
would be unable to cut unit costs in response to the tariff as there were no more
opportunities for cost-saving within the system.
Further, the PbR tariff is set using mean average costs and so around half of providers
will already have costs below the tariff. Although there is an incentive to keep prices
below the tariff, for these lower cost providers the incentive to reduce unit costs
further depends on the attractiveness of the arrangements for retaining surpluses or the
need to subsidise and help retain loss-making services elsewhere in the Trust. We
found evidence of such within-Trust cross-subsidisation from the interviews. In the
quantitative analysis we found that high cost non-FTs increased the proportion of
daycase activities more quickly than low cost non-FTs, but there was no difference
between the two control groups for change in length of stay. In addition, during the
period of phasing-in of the tariff, there are transition arrangements which protect
Trusts that are above tariff from the full financial implications of any difference
12
See
CHI
at
http://www.chi.nhs.uk/Ratings/
http://2007ratings.healthcarecommission.org.uk/homepage.cfm .
98
and
Healthcare
Commission
at
between pre-dating local prices and the national tariff price 13 . This temporary
protection reduces the incentive to find cost savings.
Despite evidence from the interviews and factors in the design of the tariff which
might be expected to temper its effects, we have observed reductions in unit costs in
daycase and inpatient activity in 2004/5 and 2005/6 which can be associated with the
introduction of the tariff-based financing system in England.
5.8
Effects on volume and pattern of care
5.8.1 Volume of output: general trends
Total spells by country
Figure 5.4 shows the trends in the total number of spells of care provided by NHS
hospitals in England and Scotland since 2001/2. Volumes are indexed on 2001/2
levels. Trusts that had become FTs by the end of the period experienced growth in
spells in all years. Over the period, the volume of spells in non Foundation Trusts
increased by 9%. In 2005/6, concurrent with the widespread application of PbR,
growth in England was 5.0 per cent compared to 2.2 per cent in Scotland.
13
As part of the these transition arrangements Trusts with costs above tariff must reduce these costs by
25% in 2005/6 to within 75% of tariff for Non-FTs in their first year of PbR and 25% in 2004/5 and
2005/6 to 50% of tariff in 2005/6 for FTs.
99
Figure 5.4
Trends in total number of spells by Non-FTs, FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
Volume of spells (2001/2 = 100)
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
5.8.2 Volume of output: difference-in-difference analyses
As outlined in Section 4, there is no clear prediction from the economic framework
that the volume of output will increase as a result of the introduction of the tariff.
However, there is a general expectation as identified from the policy documentation
in Section 2.1 that the tariff will encourage higher volumes of output. In this section
we present the results of a series of DiD analyses designed to investigate whether
there is evidence to support those expectations.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts. This included both elective and non-elective spells.
Table 5.13 shows a higher growth rate in spells for FTs than Scotland in 2004/5. This
difference in growth is statistically significant at the 5 per cent level when we control
for Trust and HRG effects. This presents weak evidence that there is an association
between growth in volume and the introduction of the tariff. When we extend the
period of analysis to examine the difference in growth from 2003/4 to 2005/6 (Table
100
5.14), we can see that looking at the longer term trends shows that the difference
between FTs and Scotland is statistically significant offering some support for the
hypothesis that the tariff has stimulated volume.
Table 5.13
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in spells growth rate (%), 2003/4-2004/5
Growth in spells, 2003/4-2004/5
Difference in Growth in spells
+2.01%
+0.57%
+1.44 % points*
+1.33 % points*
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 HRGs.
Table 5.14
2005/6
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in growth rate (%) in all spells, 2003/4Growth in spells, 2003/4-2005/6
+7.36%
+2.29%
Difference in Growth in spells
+5.07 % points**
+4.95 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 HRGs.
When we use non-FTs as the counterfactual, as shown in Table 5.15, the growth rate
is higher in the non-FTs. However, there is no statistically significant difference
between the two groups for both models.
Table 5.15
FTs
Non-FTs
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in spell growth rate (%), 2003/4-2004/5
Growth in spells, 2003/4-2004/5
Difference in Growth in spells
+2.80%
+2.83%
–0.03%pts‡
–0.25%pts‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
b) In 2005/6 the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some exceptions)
elective output provided by Non-FTs.
Table 5.16 shows that growth in both elective and non-elective spells for non-FTs in
2005/06 increased and that it was higher for elective spells. The difference between
101
the two types of spells is not statistically significant even after controlling for HRG
mix.
Table 5.16 Elective growth in volume DiD with non-FTs for non-elective spells,
2004/5-2005/6
Growth in spells, 2004/5-2005/6 Difference in Growth in spells
Elective
+6.26%
Non-elective
+5.69%
+0.57%pts‡
+0.76%pts‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
From the comparison of Scotland and English Non-FTs in 2005/6, shown in Table
5.17, we can see the change in growth in elective care in 2005/6 was higher for the
Non-FTs. This difference is statistically significant for both the adjusted and
unadjusted models. The results support the expectation of higher growth in the newly
tariffed elective spells. However, in Table 5.18 we can observe that activity on nonelective spells also grew more quickly in non-FTs than in Scotland. This is not what
we would expect given that these non-elective spells are not subject to tariff.
Table 5.17
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in growth in volume of elective spells,
2004/5-2005/6
Growth in spells, 2004/5-2005/6
Difference in Growth in spells
Non-FTs
+6.36%
Scotland
+3.02%
+3.34%pts**
+2.57%pts**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
102
Table 5.18
2005/6
Non-FTs
Scotland
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in volume of elective spells, 2004/5Growth in spells, 2004/5-2005/6
+3.98%
+0.75%
Difference in Growth in spells
+3.22%pts**
+3.21%pts**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes 15 and 33 HRGs.
Sub-group analysis
We interacted the difference in the growth rates with a binary variable indicating
whether the non-FTs had a Reference Cost Index value above 100 in 2004/5. Fortyfive percent of non-FTs had an RCI value above 100. The results adjusting for the
initial HRG mix are shown in Table 5.19 for elective spells and non-elective spells in
2005/6. We find no difference in elective spells growth between high-cost or low-cost
non-FTs. However, for non-elective spells the ‘high-cost’ non-FTs had growth rates
that were 3.09% greater than that for the ‘low-cost’ non-FTs. This difference is highly
significant (p<0.001).
Table 5.19
High-cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low-cost Non-FTs for growth in
spells, 2004/5-2005/6
Elective
Difference in growth of spells
Difference in difference (adjusted)
+1.04 % points‡
Non-elective
Difference in difference (adjusted)
+3.09 %points**
Notes: ‡ not significant , ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
We also interacted growth rates with a binary variable indicating whether the non-FT
was operating within a local health economy in surplus or deficit (where health
economy is defined as the Strategic Health Authority). The results are shown in Table
5.20. Trusts operating within a local health economy which is in surplus had lower
growth than those in a health economy in deficit. This difference is statistically
significant and counter to expectations.
103
Table 5.20
Non-FTs in SHAs in surplus DiD with Non-FTs in SHAs in deficit
for growth in spells, 2004/5-2005/6
Elective
Difference in growth of spells
–3.27 percentage points**
Difference in difference (adjusted)
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
5.8.3 Non-elective admissions: general trends
Non-elective admissions by country
Figure 5.5 presents trends in the proportion of spells admitted as non-electives in
Non-FTs, FTs and Scotland. It shows the trend for the English NHS Trusts has
diverged from that of Scotland. After an increase between 2001/2 and 2002/3, the
proportion of non-elective admissions has fallen each year in Scotland. For the
English NHS Trusts, after a fall in the proportion of non-elective admissions in
2002/3, there were two years of increases in the non-elective proportion. This increase
was driven by a larger increase in the number of non-elective spells compared to
elective spells, especially in 2003/4. There was a reduction in the proportion of nonelective admissions in 2005/6 when the increase in the number of non-elective spells
was more similar to that for elective spells.
104
Figure 5.5
Trends in the proportion of non-elective admissions by Non-FTs,
FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
Non-elective proportion of spells
47%
46%
45%
44%
43%
42%
41%
40%
39%
38%
37%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
2004/5
Financial Year
2005/6
Overall the non-elective proportion in England rose from 43.7 per cent in 2001/2 to
45.1 percent of admitted patient spells in 2005/6. It fell slightly in Scotland from 42.7
per cent to 42.0 per cent of output. This occurred during a period when non-elective
admissions were causing concern in England following the introduction of two policy
changes in the form of the maximum 4 hour A&E waiting target and the introduction
of the relatively higher tariff for non-elective admissions for FTs (BMA, 2005).
5.8.4 Impact on non-elective admissions: difference-in-difference analyses
FTs received a higher tariff for patients with the same HRG code but categorised as
non-elective admissions rather than elective admissions. As such, there may be an
incentive to admit more non-elective patients (e.g. relax admission thresholds) than
elective patients in order to increase revenue. We examine the evidence for such a
change in behaviour in this section.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts. This included both elective and non-elective spells.
105
In 2004/5 Non-FTs experienced higher growth in the proportion of non-elective
admissions than the FTs. Once we control for fixed effects the difference was very
small and not statistically significant as shown in Table 5.21.
Table 5.21
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in the proportion of non-elective
admissions for all spells, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4
2004/5
Change in proportion Difference in change in
of non-elective
proportion of non-elective
FTs
54.30%
54.80% +0.5 % points
Non-FTs 57.60%
59.00% +1.4 % points
–1.0 % points **
–0.1 % points *
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
In 2004/5 growth in the proportion of non-elective spells for FTs was small and
positive. Using Scotland to represent the underlying trend, as shown in Table 5.22
growth was slightly higher in the FTs. This DiD was statistically significant
suggesting an increase in non-elective admissions associated with the higher tariff.
Table 5.22
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in the proportion of non-elective
admissions for all spells, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4
2004/5
Change in proportion Difference in change in
of non-elective
proportion of non-elective
FTs
43.60%
44.00% +0.4 %pts
Scotland 45.80%
45.70% –0.1 %pts
+0.6 %pts **
+0.1 %pts *
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 HRGs.
Over the two years to 2005/6, FTs increased the proportion of non-elective
admissions and in Scotland they fell (Table 5.23). The difference is statistically
significant in the unadjusted model. However, once we have controlled for changes in
age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects, although still in the same direction,
the DiD is no longer statistically significant. This suggests that over the two year
period there was no increase in the proportion of non-elective activity associated with
the tariff.
106
Table 5.23
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in the proportion of non-elective
admissions for all spells, 2003/4-2005/6
2003/4
2005/6
Change in proportion Difference in change in
of non-elective
proportion of non-elective
FTs
37.84%
39.38% +1.54 % points
Scotland 48.08%
47.58% –0.50 % points
+2.5 % points **
+0.2 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05. Excludes the 15 HRGs.
5.8.5
Summary of effects on volume and pattern of care
We have examined whether the introduction of the tariff is associated with increases
in the volume of care and changes in the pattern of the provision of care in 2004/5 and
2005/6. We undertook five main tests of the effects on the volume of care and three
tests on the proportion of non-elective care. We analysed the results by subgroups of
Trusts in surplus and deficit local health economies. A summary of these results is
given in Table C2 of Appendix C.
Of the five main tests that we carried out on the volume of care, four provided support
for the expectation that the tariff is associated with growth in activity. When we
compare FTs and non-FTs with Scotland in 2004/5 and 2005/6, we see evidence of
higher activity growth rates where the tariff is applied. However, (as for length of
stay) when we use non-FTs as the control group for FTs in 2004/5, we observe no
difference between the growth rates of the tariffed and un-tariffed groups respectively.
Both FTs and non-FTs were subject to challenging waiting time targets in 2004/5 (at
March 2004, no one waiting more than 9 months after decision to admit and for
December 2005, no-one waiting more than 6 months). Given that one of the criteria
NHS Trusts had to meet to gain FT status in 2004 was low waiting times (see Chapter
2) it is feasible that FTs had already met the target and that non-FTs had to work
much harder than FTs to meet these targets in 2004/5. Hence Non-FTs and FTs both
had an incentive to increase volume but for the non-FTs it was more associated with
waiting time targets than PbR.
107
By rewarding hospitals more for treating non-elective patients than elective patients
coded as having the same spell HRG, an incentive to admit more non-elective patients
is created. Given that Trusts are unlikely to be able to manage or manipulate the
demand for non-elective admissions, changes in the proportion of non-elective
patients are likely to reflect changes in the patient admission process. Therefore we
have explored the data for evidence of increases in the volume of elective care for
non-FTs and FTs and for increases in the proportion of non-elective care for FTs only
in 2005/6. In the tests undertaken, we found no evidence of a disproportionate growth
in non-elective care associated with the introduction of the tariff.
In the interviews we undertook, the limited global budget of the local economy was
emphasised by respondents as a constraint on increasing capacity. Providers saw little
point in doing extra on-tariff work that their PCTs could not afford without cutting the
amounts paid for non-tariff work. Trusts were generally sensitive to the need to retain
a stable local health economy and that required the local PCTs to be in financial
balance. Some respondents considered the opportunity cost of increasing volume in
one area of service would be a reduction in available funds in another area. Although
the reductions could occur in another Trust’s output, there was a general feeling that it
could well appear in their own. There was also a sense of corporate responsibility
evident in many places, a common purpose in serving the local population, and a
consequent wish not to harm other providers and their patients.
For the subgroup analysis, we found that Trusts operating in a local health economy
which was in deficit the previous year were more likely to have higher growth rates in
the following year. We had anticipated that local health economies with a surplus
might be more likely to expand output as the local health economy would be less
constrained. However, this is not upheld by the results.
The higher growth has been observed despite the suggestions by the interviewees that
there was limited opportunity to increase volume for two main reasons. The first
relates to capacity constraints and the second relates to limited local budgets or lack of
excess demand. We asked interviewees in all three rounds of qualitative analysis
108
about their perceptions of whether and how PbR was affecting the volume of activity
undertaken in their local health economies. Most respondents identified increases in
activity but were inclined to attribute this to continuations of past trends and to the
pressure to reduce waiting times for elective care. A few respondents took the view
that, because their hospital’s capacity was already fully used or the ability of local
PCTs to pay for more work did not exist, they were trying to discourage rather than
encourage increased activity.
One of the objectives of the PbR system was to introduce ‘greater transparency and
planning certainty in the system’ (DH, 2002a). From the interviews, managers and
clinicians lacked confidence in the robustness of the costs on which the prices were
based, and had limited confidence in the stability of the tariff over time. This meant
that, although business plans to increase capacity were simpler to construct in a
system of guaranteed fixed prices than they had been pre-PbR, such plans were
thought to be vulnerable to unpredictable changes in those prices. Such uncertainty
would not be conducive to long term capacity increasing capital schemes.
The increases in volume observed in this study are short-term. Further investigations
should examine whether PbR has had an affect on the ability to increase capacity and
hence may also stimulated longer-term future increases in volume.
Within the period of our study, only the FTs were faced with a tariff-based incentive
to increase the proportion of non-elective admissions. The DiD was positive and
significant for the FTs when Scotland was used as the control in 2004/5 but not when
English non-FTs were used as the control. The 4-hour wait targets set for Accident
and Emergency departments during this period may have had an affect in the same
direction, thereby confounding the results. These targets applied to non-FTs as well as
FTs in England but not to Trusts in Scotland during 2004/5 and 2005/614. Given that a
DiD is only evident when measured against Scotland in 2004/5, this may strengthen
14
Policy guidance in Fair to All, Personal to Each: the next steps for NHSScotland introduced a
commitment that "from the end of 2007, patients will wait no longer than 4 hours between arriving at a
Unit and admission, discharge or transfer”. However, data for monitoring this were not collected
systematically until 2006.
109
the argument that increases in non-elective admissions were driven at least partly by
the A&E 4-hour wait target15.
There is consistent evidence of both non-FTs and FTs responding to the tariff by
increasing volumes of inpatient care and that some of the observed differences with
Scotland may be attributable to differences in the waiting time target regimes. There
is inconsistent evidence that FTs increased the proportion of non-elective admissions,
but again this may be attributable to other policy initiatives in England such as the 4hour A&E wait.
5.9
Effects on the Quality of Care
5.9.1 Hospital mortality: general trends
Hospital mortality for elective spells is lower in the English NHS Trusts than in
Scotland. From 2002/3 to 2005/6, FTs and Non-FTs have had reductions in hospital
mortality whereas in Scotland there was an increase from 2001/2 to 2003/4 followed
by reductions thereafter. Shown in Figure 5.6.
15
As described in Chapter 2 the NHS Plan 2000 set out an accident and emergency target of four hours
from arrival to admission, transfer or discharge to be achieved by 2004.
110
Figure 5.6
Trends in hospital mortality for elective spells in Non-FTs, FTs
and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
In-hospital mortality rate
1.50%
1.00%
0.50%
0.00%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
2004/5
Financial Year
2005/6
As shown in figure 5.7, all types of organisation have experienced reductions in nonelective hospital mortality since 2002/3. Generally, the reductions have been steeper
for the English NHS Trusts than Scotland.
111
Figure 5.7
Trends in hospital mortality for non-elective spells in Non-FTs.
FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
In-hospital mortality rate
6%
5%
4%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
5.9.2 Hospital mortality: difference-in-difference analyses
We identify in Chapter 3 that PbR is expected to have a positive effect on the quality
of care16. As outlined there, other things equal the introduction of PbR will increase
incentives to control unit costs but may result in some economising on quality of
care17. In this section we use DiD analyses to examine if there have been changes in
the quality of care and what direction those changes have taken.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by FTs. This included both elective and non-elective spells.
As shown in Table 5.24, in-hospital mortality fell by the same percentage points for
the FTs and for Scotland in 2004/5. Once we control for changes in the age-sex
16
These effects are likely to be strongest when PbR is combined with Patient Choice policy. However,
Patient Choice policy was not widely introduced in England until the last quarter of our data.
17
We also acknowledge in Section 4 that there may be factors which mitigate the quality reducing
effects of the tariff.
112
composition of admitted patients and differences between Trusts and HRGs a
difference emerges but this is not statistically significant. These results indicate that
the tariff had neither a beneficial or detrimental effect on the quality of care for FTs in
2004/5.
Table 5.24
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in hospital mortality, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in hospital Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
mortality rates
2.51% 2.42% –0.09 % points
2.94% 2.85% –0.09 % points
0.00 % points ‡
–0.05 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 HRGs.
Looking at a two year period in Table 5.25, in-hospital mortality fell by more
percentage points in Scotland than for the FTs from 2003/4 to 2005/6. However, when
we control for changes in age-sex composition and Trust and HRG effects, FTs are
shown to have greater reductions in in-hospital mortality over the period. This is a
statistically significant result showing that quality of care has improved in association
with the introduction of the tariff.
Table 5.25
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in hospital mortality, 2003/04-2005/6
2003/4 2005/6 Change in hospital Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
mortality rates
2.62% 2.27% –0.35 % points
3.06% 2.88% –0.18 % points
0.16 % points **
–0.28 % points **
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** significant at p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 HRGs.
If we use Non-FTs as the counterfactual, there is no statistically significant difference
between the two groups. Shown in Table 5.26.
113
Table 5.26
FTs
Non-FTs
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in hospital mortality, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in hospital Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
mortality rates
2.28% 2.19% –0.09 % points
2.45% 2.35% –0.10 % points
0.00 % points ‡
+0.01 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05. ** p<0.01; Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
b) In 2005/6 the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some exceptions)
elective output provided by Non-FTs
In 2005/6 Non-FTs had a greater absolute reduction in elective in-hospital mortality
compared with Scotland. However, the difference is not statistically significant as
shown in Table 5.27. The same comparison for non-elective activity shows a
reduction in non-elective in-hospital mortality associated with the introduction of the
tariff in 2005/6 for non-FTs (Table 5.28).
Table 5.27
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in hospital mortality elective care,
2004/5-2005/6
Non-FTs
Scotland
2004/5 2005/6 Change in hospital
mortality rates
0.23% 0.20% –0.03 % points
1.46% 1.43% –0.02 % points
Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
–0.010 % points ‡
–0.004 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
114
Table 5.28
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in hospital mortality non-elective
care, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in hospital Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
mortality rates
Non-FTs 5.34% 4.98% –0.36 % points
Scotland 4.81% 4.75% –0.06 % points
–0.29 % points **
–0.23 % points **
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
As shown in Table 5.29, the reduction in hospital mortality for Non-FTs is higher in
the non-tariffed non-elective output than in the tariffed elective output in 2005/6. This
statistically significant DiD, offers the only evidence that the tariff might slow
improvements in the quality of care.
Table 5.29
Elective output DiD with non-elective output in hospital mortality
Non-FTs, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in hospital Difference in change in hospital
mortality rates
mortality rates
Elective
0.23% 0.20% –0.03 % points
Non5.34% 4.98% –0.36 % points
elective
Simple
+0.33 % points **
Adjusted
+0.27 % points **
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
Subgroup analysis
We also tested whether the changes in the in-hospital mortality rates differed between
high-cost and low-cost non FTs. The high cost non-FTs experienced greater
reductions in hospital mortality than the low cost non-FTs. This result, presented in
Table 5.30 is statistically significant but is counter to expectations as we would expect
the providers with costs below the tariff to be better placed to use resources to
increase the quality of care and for high cost providers to be focussing on reducing
costs rather than increasing quality.
115
Table 5.30
High cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low cost Non-FTs for hospital
mortality, 2004/5-2005/6
Difference in change in hospital mortality rates
Simple
Adjusted
–0.06 % points **
–0.06 % points **
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
5.9.3 30-day mortality: general trends
Figure 5.8 presents the trends in 30-day post elective surgical mortality for Non-FTs,
FTs and Scotland for 2001/2 to 2005/6. The rate for Scotland is consistently higher
over the period. The Non-FTs and FTs have similar rates with the FTs being slightly
higher throughout. The rates in English NHS Trusts have been steady or falling during
the period 2001/2 to 2005/6. This contrasts with Scotland which saw increases in
mortality until 2004/5, followed by a fall in 2005/6.
Figure 5.8
Scotland
Trends in 30-day elective surgical mortality for Non-FTs, FTs and
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
1.0%
0.9%
30-day mortality rate
0.8%
0.7%
0.6%
0.5%
0.4%
0.3%
0.2%
0.1%
0.0%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
Figure 5.9 shows Scotland’s 30-day surgical mortality rate for non-elective spells to
be consistently higher then FTs and non-FTs for period 2001/2 to 2005/6. All three
116
groups had a lower rate in 2005/6 compared to 2001/2 with FTs ending the period
with the lowest 30-day mortality.
Figure 5.9
Trends in 30-day non-elective surgical mortality for Non-FTs, FTs
and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
30-day mortality rate
5.5%
4.5%
3.5%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
2004/5
2005/6
5.9.4 30-day surgical mortality: difference-in-difference analyses
In this section we use DiD analyses to test this hypothesis that the tariff may have had
a detrimental affect on the quality of care using 30-day surgical mortality as a
measure of quality of care.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts in 2004/5. This included both elective and nonelective spells.
There is no statistically significant difference in the change in post-surgical 30-day
mortality between FTs and non-FTs in 2004/5 (Table 5.31).
117
Table 5.31
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in 30-day post surgical mortality, 2003/42004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in 30-day post Difference in change in 30-day
surgical mortality rate post surgical mortality rate
FTs
1.26% 1.27% +0.01 % points
Non1.31% 1.29% –0.02 % points
FTs
Simple
+0.04 % points ‡
Adjusted
+0.01 % points ‡
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
Table 5.32 shows that FTs’ 30-day post surgical mortality fell more quickly than that
of Scotland in the two year period, 2003/4 to 2005/6. However, the difference is not
statistically significant even when we control for changes in age-sex composition and
Trust and HRG effects.
Table 5.32
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in 30-day post surgical mortality, 2003/4 to
2005/6
2003/4 2005/6 Change in 30-day post Difference in change in 30-day
surgical mortality rate post surgical mortality rate
FTs
1.18% 1.01% –0.17 % points
Scotland 2.07% 1.98% –0.09 % points
–0.08 % points ‡
–0.00 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05. Note: Excludes elective 15 HRGs
The comparison with Scotland shown in Table 5.33 again shows no statistically
significant results suggesting that there is no association between the introduction of
the tariff and 30-day post surgical mortality for FTs in 2004/5.
118
Table 5.33
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in 30-day post surgical mortality, 2003/42004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in 30-day post Difference in change in 30-day
surgical mortality rate post surgical mortality rate
FTs
1.22% 1.23% +0.01 % points
Scotland 2.12% 2.18% +0.06 % points
–0.05 % points ‡
+0.03 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 HRGs.
b) In 2005/6 when the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some
exceptions) elective output provided by Non-FTs
The DiD in Table 5.34 is generated using Scotland as the counterfactual for Non-FTs
in 2005/6. It shows that the reduction in mortality was greater in Non-FTs than in
Scotland but that this was not statistically significant.
Table 5.34
Non-FTs DiD with Scotland in 30-day post elective surgical
mortality, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/05 2005/06 Change in 30-day
Difference in change in 30post surgical
day post surgical mortality
mortality rate
rate
Non-FTs 0.45%
0.35%
–0.10 %pts
Scotland
1.18%
1.11%
–0.07 %pts
–0.02 %pts ‡
–0.05 %pts ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01; Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs
Subgroup analysis
We also tested whether the changes in the 30-day mortality rate differed between
high-cost and low-cost non FTs. Surgical mortality fell more quickly in high cost nonFTs than low cost non-FTs in 2005/6. The difference, shown in Table 5.35, was
significantly different but counter to the expected direction because we would expect
low cost providers to have greater opportunities to increase the quality of care.
119
Table 5.35
High cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low cost Non-FTs for 30-day post
surgical mortality, 2004/5-2005/6
Difference in change in 30-day post surgical mortality rate
Simple
Adjusted
–0.08 %pts **
–0.05 %pts **
Notes: ** p<0.01. Excludes elective 15 and 33 HRGs.
5.9.5 Emergency re-admission following hip fracture: general trends
Figure 5.10 presents the trends in emergency readmissions following hip fracture for
Non-FTs, FTs and Scotland for 2001/2 to 2005/6. The rate for Scotland is consistently
lower over the period. The Non-FTs have the highest rates. The rate in Non-FTs
declines in the first two years and increases from 2003/4 onwards. The rates in FTs
and Scotland are more variable as they are based on smaller numbers.
Figure 5.10 Trends in hip fracture emergency readmission rates for Non-FTs,
FTs and Scotland
Non-FT
FT
Scotland
Hip fracture emergency re-admission rate
14%
12%
10%
8%
6%
4%
2%
0%
2001/2
2002/3
2003/4
Financial Year
120
2004/5
2005/6
5.9.6 Emergency readmission following treatment for hip fracture: differencein-difference analyses
In this section we use DiD analyses to test this hypothesis that the tariff may have had
a detrimental affect on the quality of care using emergency readmission following
treatment for hip fracture as a measure of quality of care.
a) In 2004/5 and 2005/6 the tariff was applied to all spells (with some exceptions)
provided by Foundation Trusts. This included both elective and non-elective spells.
Emergency readmissions following treatment for hip fracture fell for FTs and grew
for non-FTs in 2004/5. However, the difference is not statistically significant. The
DiDs in Table 5.36 offers no support for the hypothesis that incentives to reduce unit
costs might adversely affect the quality of care.
Table 5.36
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in emergency readmissions following
treatment for hip fracture, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in rate of
Difference in change in rate
emergency readmissions of emergency readmissions
FTs
10.57% 10.49% –0.08 % points
Non-FTs 11.41% 11.96% +0.55 % points
Simple
–0.63 % points ‡
Adjusted
–0.68 % points ‡
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01. Excludes the 15 and 33 HRGs.
The comparison with Scotland shown in Table 5.37 shows that both FTs and Scotland
reduced emergency readmission following treatment for hip fracture and that the
reduction was greater in Scotland. However, the difference between the two groups is
not statistically significant and thus offers no support for the hypothesis that there is a
change in mortality associated with the introduction of the tariff.
121
Table 5.37
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in emergency readmissions following
treatment for hip fracture, 2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in rate of
Difference in change in
emergency readmissions rate of emergency
readmissions
FTs
10.57% 10.49% –0.08 % points
Scotland 8.77%
7.92%
–0.85 % points
+0.77 % points ‡
+0.73 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01.
As above there is not statistically significant difference between the non-FTs and
Scotland even when we extend the analysis to two years of data (Table 5.38).
Table 5.38
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in emergency readmissions following
treatment for hip fracture, 2003/4-2005/6
2003/04 2005/06 Change in rate of
Difference in change in
emergency readmissions rate of emergency
readmissions
FTs
12.0%
10.9%
–1.1 % points
Scotland 8.8%
8.5%
–0.3 % points
–0.9 % points ‡
–1.2 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05.
b) In 2005/6 when the application of the tariff was extended to all (with some
exceptions) elective output provided by Non-FTs
The DiD in Table 5.39 is generated using Scotland as the counterfactual for Non-FTs
in 2005/6. It shows that both groups had similar increases in the emergency
readmission rate following treatment for hip fracture.
122
Table 5.39
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in emergency readmissions following
treatment for hip fracture, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/05 2005/06 Change in rate of
Difference in change in
emergency readmissions rate of emergency
readmissions
Non12.0%
12.5%
FTs
+0.5 % points
Scotland 7.9%
8.5%
+0.6 % points
+0.0 % points ‡
+0.0 % points ‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01
Subgroup analysis
Subgroup analysis in Table 5.40 shows no difference in the change in emergency
readmissions following treatment for hip fracture between low- and high-cost nonFTs.
Table 5.40
High-cost Non-FTs’ DiD with low-cost Non-FTs in emergency
readmission following treatment for hip fracture, 2004/5-2005/6
Difference in change in rate of emergency readmissions
Simple
Adjusted
–0.1 %pts‡
–0.1 %pts ‡
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01
5.9.7 Hospital level measures of quality of care
We undertook preliminary analysis of the effects of the tariff on the rate of MRSA as
a proportion of bed days, the proportion of cancelled operations, the number of
emergency readmissions, hospital 30-day mortality following surgery and proportion
of inpatients waiting less than 6 months in 2003/04 and 2004/05. The results of this
were presented in the Interim Report produced for the Advisory Group in October
2006. We found no statistically significant effects. This is likely to reflect a lack of
statistical power of analysis at provider level. For completeness these results are
shown in Table C8 in Appendix C.
5.9.8
Summary of effects on quality
We have examined whether the introduction of the tariff is associated with changes in
the quality of care in 2004/5 and 2005/6 measured by in-hospital mortality, 30-day
123
post-surgical mortality and emergency readmissions following treatment for hip
fracture. We undertook five main tests of the effects on in-hospital mortality and four
main tests on the other two variables. We also analysed the results by subgroups of
low cost and high costs Trusts. A summary of these results is given in Table C3 of
Appendix C.
Overall, the quantitative evidence does not support the policy expectation that the
introduction of PbR would lead to increases in the quality of care. The results show no
association between 30-day mortality and emergency readmissions following hip
fracture and the introduction of tariff for FTs or non-FTs in 2004/5 and 2005/6. For
in-hospital mortality, we see greater reductions for non-FTs in 2005/6. For FTs this
difference is evident when we look at two years of data, 2003/4 to 2005/6.
Equally, there is no evidence to suggest that the quality of care (as measured in this
study) is being adversely affected by the introduction of the PbR in 2004/5 and 2005/6.
The subgroup analysis showed that high cost non-FTs had significantly larger
reductions in in-hospital mortality and 30-day post surgical mortality than low cost
non-FTs in 2005/6. It might have been expected that high cost providers would have
to work harder to reduce their costs below tariff and would be more likely to
experience reductions in the quality of care in the process. However, what appears to
be happening is that high cost providers are better maintaining the quality of care.
One explanation is that high costs are a consequence of higher quality and that higher
cost providers are maintaining their commitment to quality in spite of a less cost
sensitive payment system. Whether this is sustainable in the longer run is questionable.
When we first interviewed NHS managers, in summer 2005, their expectations with
respect to the impact of PbR on the quality of patient care were quite varied. Some
feared PbR might damage patient quality, or at least deter improvements, in some
places because of the need to keep costs below the nationally fixed tariff level. One
interviewee feared that because the PbR tariff is based on national average costs it
would produce “average quality services”. Others expected no impact on quality. But
124
none considered that PbR was at that early stage stimulating Trusts to compete on
quality. This view continued to predominate during our 2006 round of interviews.
In almost all Trusts where we interviewed, care quality was driven by clinical and not
financial considerations. Specialised Trusts, in particular, were confident that they
would retain their market position because of a reputation for quality provision but
did not have plans to enhance that quality in order to win patients away from other
providers.
In conclusion, the views expressed in the interviews with respect to PbR having
limited effect on the quality of care appear to be upheld by the quantitative analysis.
PbR appears so far neither to be enhancing nor damaging quality of care.
5.10
Outpatients
We undertook a series of analyses on changes in the patterns of outpatient services.
As with the admissions analysis above, we used measures of efficiency and volume.
For efficiency we used: the return ratio which measures the ratio between first
attendances and all subsequent attendances in outpatients and; the ‘did not attend’
(DNA) rate as a measure of hospitals’ ability to manage resources and patients
effectively.
To measure the changes in volume of outpatient care we used first admissions and all
admissions.
We also used volume of GP referred outpatients as an indicator of the effectiveness of
demand management or a shift towards the provision of outpatient services in the
community.
We used volume of other referrals as an indicator of Trust generated referral, both as
an absolute and proportion of total referral. This is the only indicator which showed a
statistically significant difference in growth. There was an increase in Trust generated
referrals associated with introduction of the outpatients tariff.
125
The extent to which we were able to use Scotland as a control varied with different
measures. The completeness and comparability of data over the period of analysis
(2002/3 to 2006/7) and between England and Scotland was different for different
variables. Our analysis was restricted by this lack of comparability and changes in the
definitions of variables. Table 5.41 below summarises the results of the outpatient
analysis. Table D2 in Appendix D shows the excluded specialties of outpatient service.
The results clearly show that there has been only one statistically significant change in
the pattern of outpatient provision which can be associated with the introduction of
the outpatient tariff under the PbR system.
5.11
Specific HRG investigations
In this section we investigate trends in specific HRGs for evidence of whether there
have been changes in the coding of patients and changes in the way patients are
treated as a result of differences in tariffs for pairs and groups of HRGs which are
similar in diagnosis and procedure. The HRGs analysed in this section and the
behaviours investigated have been informed through discussions with the project
advisory group.
5.11.1 Primary hip replacement
Primary hip replacement can be undertaken as uncemented (HRG code: H80) or
cemented (HRG code: H81). There is a general view 18 that the elective tariff for
uncemented should be higher than the cemented tariff. However, the tariff has been
set so that cemented is reimbursed at a higher rate. As a result the DH are considering
for 2008/09 to adjust the elective tariff for H81 so that it is higher than H80.
We investigate here whether the higher tariff for the cemented has had the effect of
shifting activity toward cemented and away from uncemented. We use elective
cemented activity as a proportion of cemented and uncemented activity. As our
dependent variable and examine charges in the growth of this proportion over time.
18
Information provided by the project advisory group.
126
Table 5.42 shows that the proportion of elective cemented hip replacement fell for
FTs in 2004/05. This compares with an increase in Scotland. This difference is
statistically significant and is counter to expectations.
Table 5.43 shows that the proportion of elective cemented hip replacement for nonFTs fell in 2005/06. As for FTs in the previous table, this compares with an increase
in Scotland and the difference is statistically significant.
127
Table 5.41
Treatment
FTs
Effects of tariff on key variables: size of effect and statistical significance
Control
Adjusted
DNA
Return
All
First
for
ratio
attendances attendances
specialty
mix
Year
04/05
Non-FTs
No
FTs
FTs
Non-FTs
Non-FTs
Yes
No
04/05
–0.015‡
0.023‡
0.0057‡
05/06
–0.013‡
0.041**
0.0082‡
FTs
Non-FTs
Yes
05/06
–0.016‡
0.041**
0.0087‡
Non-FTs
Non-FTs
Scotland
Scotland
No
Yes
06/07
06/07
0.11‡
0.11‡
0.0026‡
0.0024‡
–0.016‡
–0.0055‡
–0.0039‡
0.0045‡
FTs
FTs
FTs
FTs
Scotland
Scotland
Non-FTs
Non-FTs
No
Yes
No
Yes
06/07
0.26‡
0.11‡
0.011‡
–0.0027‡
06/07
06/07
0.25‡
0.15‡
06/07
0.13‡
0.080‡
0.082‡
0.077‡
0.016‡
0.027*
0.026*
0.0028‡
0.0012‡
0.0021‡
0.0062‡
0.0103‡
0.038‡
0.036‡
0.0076‡
0.0084‡
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05, * p<0.05; ** p<0.01
128
GP
referrals
Other
referrals
Other
referrals (%)
–0.016‡
0.023‡
0.0073‡
These results suggest that counter to expectations there has been no increase in the
proportion of elective cemented hip replacement as a result of the introduction of the
tariff.
Table 5.42
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of cemented spells in all
elective spells, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
cemented spells
proportion of cemented
spells
FTs
83.0%
80.9%
–2.1 % points
Scotland 96.9%
97.4%
+0.5 % points
–2.6 % points**
–1.4 % points*
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: * p<0.05 ** p<0.01
Table5.43
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of cemented spells in
all elective spells (cemented and uncemented), 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in proportion Difference in change in
of cemented spells
proportion of cemented spells
Non-FTs 79.4% 74.1% –5.3 % points
Scotland 97.4% 97.0% –0.4 % points
–4.9 % points**
–4.6 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
5.11.2 Maternity care
We undertake a series of investigations under the coding and tariff for maternity care.
N12. Antenatal Admissions not related to delivery event
The Department of Health have received feedback through consultation that Trusts
have an incentive to admit to HRG N12 for activity that could be carried out in an
outpatient clinic. Evidence to support this would be found in increases in the volume
of N12 and decreases in the average length of stay.
Tables 5.44 to 5.47 show the DiD analysis for FTs and non-FTs in 2004/5 and 2005/6
using the usual control groups. The dependent variable is the growth rate in elective
and non-elective spells coded as N12. We find no statistically significant growth in
activity in N12 which is counter to the expected pattern of provision.
129
Table 5.44
2004/5
FTs
Non-FTs
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in spell growth rate (%) in N12, 2003/4Change in proportion of ‘with
complications’, 2003/4-2004/5
12.86 % points
5.43 % points
Difference in change in proportion
of ‘with complications’
7.43 % points ‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
Table 5.45
2004/5
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in spells growth rate (%) in N12, 2003/4Change in proportion of ‘with
complications’, 2003/4-2004/5
12.86 % points
1.89 % points
Difference in change in proportion
of ‘with complications’
10.96 % points‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
Table 5.46
2005/6
Non-FTs
Scotland
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in growth rate (%) in N12, 2004/5Change in proportion of ‘with
complications’, 2004/5-2005/6
8.18 % points
1.47 % points
Difference in change in proportion
of ‘with complications’
6.72 % points*
Simple
Notes: * p<0.05
Table 5.47
2005/6
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in spells growth rate (%) in N12, 2004/5Change in proportion of ‘with
complications’, 2004/5-2005/6
6.25%pts
1.47%pts
Difference in change in proportion
of ‘with complications’
4.78% points‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
N06 normal delivery versus N07 normal delivery with complications.
There is scope for a case with no complications to be coded as with complications due
to the lack of definite guidelines as to what constitutes a ‘complication’ in maternity
care. Given that the tariff is higher for N07 with complications this provides Trusts
130
with an opportunity to gain more revenue at no extra cost by coding upwards from
N06 to N07.
There is some evidence of such ‘up-coding’ in our analysis. Compared to Scotland
non-FTs have a statistically significant higher growth in the proportion of normal
deliveries ‘with complications’ in 2005/6 (see Table 5.50). However, for 2004/5 when
we compare FTs to Scotland, there is no statistically significant difference (Table
5.49). Using non-FTs as the control for FTs in 2004/5, the difference is statistically
significant but in the opposite direction to what we would expect (Table 5.48).
Table 5.48
FTs’ DiD with non-FTs in proportion of ‘with complications’ spells
in all normal delivery spells, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
FTs
4.76%
4.72% –0.04 % points
Non-FTs 5.30%
6.05% +0.75 % points
–0.02 % points**
–0.03 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
Table 5.49
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all normal delivery spells in 2003/4 and 2004/5
FTs
Scotland
2003/4
2004/5 Change in proportion of
‘with complications’
4.76%
2.63%
4.72%
2.35%
Difference in change in
proportion of ‘with
complications’
–0.04 % points
–0.28 % points
+0.24 % points‡
+0.24 % points‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
131
Table 5.50
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all normal delivery spells, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
Non-FTs 5.26%
5.98% +0.72 % points
Scotland 2.35%
2.53% +0.18 % points
+0.54 % points**
+0.59 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
N08: Assisted delivery ‘with complication, versus N09: Assisted delivery ‘without
complication’
We investigated whether there was an increase in the proportion of assisted deliveries
‘with complication’. We found little evidence to support the expectation of increased
coding of deliveries with complications. As can be seen in Tables 5.51 to 5.53, the
‘with complications’ grew more slowly or fell more quickly than ‘without
complications’ in our treatment groups than in the controls. The statistically
significant result in Table 5.51 is in the opposite direction to our expectations.
Table 5.51
FTs’ DiD with non-FTs in proportion of ‘with complications’ spells
in all assisted delivery spells in, 2003/4-2004/5
Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
FTs
8.97%
8.35% –0.62 % points
Non-FTs 9.10%
9.08% –0.02 % points
–0.15 % points**
–0.22 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
132
Table 5.52
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all assisted delivery spells in 2003/4 and 2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
FTs
8.97%
8.35% –0.62 % points
Scotland 2.75%
2.37% –0.38 % points
–0.23 % points‡
–0.19 % points‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
Table 5.53
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all assisted delivery spells, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
Non-FTs 9.01%
9.15% +0.14 % points
Scotland 2.37%
2.79% +0.42 % points
–0.29 % points‡
–0.26 % points‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
N10: Caesarean section with complication versus N11: Caesarean section without
complication
We investigated whether there was an increase in the proportion of caesarean section
with complication. FTs had statistically significant increases in the proportion of
HRG N10 compared with Scotland but experienced decreases compared with non-FTs
in 2004/5. In 2005/6, the difference between non-FTs and Scotland is not statistically
significant. This indicates a change in the coding (or treatment) behaviour for
caesarean section by FTs (but not by non-FTs) associated with the introduction of the
tariff.
133
Table 5.54
FTs’ DiD with non-FTs in proportion of ‘with complications’ spells
in all delivery spells, 2003/4 to 2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
FTs
14.37% 15.46% +1.09 % points
Non-FTs 15.31% 15.37% +0.06 % points
-0.15 % points**
-0.20 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
Table 5.55
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all delivery spells, 2003/4 to 2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
FTs
14.37% 15.46% 0.09 % points
Scotland 4.71% 3.80% –0.91 % points
+2.00 % points**
+1.60 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
Table 5.56
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of ‘with complications’
spells in all delivery spells, 2004/5 to 2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
Non-FTs 15.28% 15.66% +0.38 percentage points
Scotland 3.80% 3.61% –0.19 percentage points
+0.56 percentage points‡
+0.31 percentage points‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
5.11.3 Treatment for head injury
A32 A33: Head injury without brain injury versus H63 H64: Head injury
There are two groups of HRGs that relate to head injury - some in chapter A of the
HRG classification system and some in chapter H. Tariffs for HRGs in chapter A are
higher than those in chapter H. There is concern that cases could be coded to generate
the higher chapter A HRGs rather than chapter H. We examined the proportion of
A32 and A33 relative to H63 and H64. We focus on non-elective activity and present
134
the trends in addition to the DiD. The trends in Table 5.57 show that the proportion of
Chapter A spells has been falling for non-FTs and FTs from 2003/4 to 2005/06.
Table 5.57
Trends in treatment of head injury: Proportion HRGs of A23 and
A24 and proportion of elective care
Year
2003/4
2004/5
2005/6
Non-FTs
No. of Spells
29,832
33,647
34,549
% of A chapter
16.47 %
14.59 %
13.64 %
% of elective
1.22 %
1.40 %
1.25 %
FTs
No. of Spells
6,846
6,885
6,866
% of A chapter
17.24 %
16.25 %
15.64 %
% of elective
1.04 %
1.55 %
1.45 %
Scotland
No. of Spells
8,171
7,244
7,058
% of A chapter
18.95 %
20.63 %
20.18 %
% of elective
5.82 %
7.38 %
5.41 %
The DiD in Tables 5.58 and 5.59, when we have adjusted for age-sex composition and
the Trust effects, confirms that there has been no increase in the proportion of Chapter
A coding (or activity) associated with the introduction of the tariff.
Table 5.58
FTs
Non-FTs
FTs’ DiD with Non-FTs in proportion of Chapter A, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
5.39% 4.92% –0.47 % points
5.02% 4.12% –0.90 % points
–0.29 % points**
–0.29 % points**
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ** p<0.01
Table 5.59
FTs
Scotland
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of Chapter A, 2003/4-2004/5
2003/4 2004/5 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
5.39% 4.92% –0.47 % points
3.85% 3.94% –0.09 % points
–0.55 % points‡
–1.18 % points*
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05 * p<0.05
135
Table 5.60
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in proportion of Chapter A in all
non-elective spells, 2004/5-2005/6
2004/5 2005/6 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
‘with complications’
proportion of ‘with
complications’
Non-FTs 4.14% 3.71% –0.43 % points
Scotland 3.94% 3.54% –0.40 % points
–0.04 % points‡
+0.21 % points‡
Simple
Adjusted
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
5.11.4 Cardiology and general medicine outpatients
The tariff for cardiology outpatients is lower than for general medicine and it is
argued that this activity is simply being coded under general medicine instead to
attract the higher tariff. We investigated whether under PbR there is a proportional
shift in activity from cardiology to general medicine. The results presented in Table
5.61 to 5.63 show that there was growth in the proportion of cardiology outpatients by
FTs and non-FTs. However none of the DiD results are statistically significant
suggesting that the growth was not associated with the introduction of the tariffs.
Table 5.61
FTs’ DiD with Scotland in outpatient attendances for cardiology as
a proportion of cardiology and general medicine, 2005/6 and 2006/7
2005/6 2006/7 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
cardiology outpatients
proportion of cardiology
outpatients
FTs
36.68% 40.01% +3.33 % points
Scotland 40.54% 42.99% +2.45 % points
+5.3 % points‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
Table 5.62
FTs’ DiD with non-FTs’ in the proportion of all outpatient
attendances for cardiology as a proportion of cardiology and general medicine,
2005/6 and 2006/7
2005/6 2006/7 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
cardiology outpatients
proportion of cardiology
outpatients
FTs
36.68% 40.01% +3.33 % points
Non-FTs 39.33% 43.04% +3.71 % points
–2.1 % points‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
136
Table 5.63
Non-FTs’ DiD with Scotland in the proportion of all outpatient
attendances for cardiology as a proportion of cardiology and general medicine,
2005/6 and 2006/7
2005/6 2006/7 Change in proportion of Difference in change in
cardiology outpatients
proportion of cardiology
outpatients
Non-FTs 39.33% 43.04% +3.71 % points
Scotland 40.54% 42.99% +2.45 % points
+7.3 % points‡
Simple
Notes: ‡ not significant at p<0.05
5.11.5
Summary of results on up-coding
We have investigated six pairs or groups of HRGs for evidence of such activity. We
examined changes in the proportions of ‘with complications’ in maternity care and
instances elsewhere (in hip replacement and head injuries) where such an unintended
incentive, associated with differences in the tariffs, was perceived.
We found very limited evidence of a change in the pattern of coding or treatment of
patients associated with the introduction of tariff. Of the six investigations, we found
that only the coding (or perhaps practice) of caesarean section by FTs and normal
delivery by non-FTs had changed in the direction expected if up-coding is happening.
It should be noted that the introduction was expected to be accompanied by greater
transparency in the system and that the system encourages more accurate and
complete coding of patients. It is not possible from this analysis to determine whether
the very limited up-coding we identified was inappropriate or due to increased
accuracy.
137
References
Alvarez-Rosete, A., Bevan, G., Mays, N., Dixon, J. Effect of diverging policy across
the NHS’, British Medical Journal, 331, 946-950, 2005.
Appleby, J., Renu, J. Payment by Results: the NHS financial revolution. New
Economy, 11(4), 195-200, 2004.
Appleby, J., Smith, A., Devlin., Parkin, P. Effects on activity and waiting times of a
new fixed price activity –based reimbursement system for English NHS hospitals.
Poster presented at 5th World Congress of the International Health Economics
Association, Barcelona, July, 2005.
Audit Commission. Early lesson of Payment by Results. October, 2005
Audit Commission. Payment by Results Assurance Framework. Pilot Results and
Recommendations. December 2006.
Bevan, G., Hood, C. Have targets improved performance in the English NHS? British
Medical Journal, 332, 419-22, 2006.
Blundell, R., Costas Dias, M. Evaluation methods for non-experimental data. Fiscal
Studies, 21, 427-468, 2000.
BMA. BMA Survey of A&E Waiting Times. March 2005.
Chalkley, M., Malcomson, JM . Government Purchasing of Health Services. In AJ
Culyer and JP Newhouse (eds.) Handbook of Health Economics, 2000.
Croxson, B., Propper, C., Perkins, A. Do doctors respond to financial incentives? UK
family doctors and the GP fundholder scheme. Journal of Public Economics, 79, 2,
375-398, 2001.
Dawson, D., Goddard, M. Longer-term contract agreements for health services: what
will they achieve? In P. Smith (ed), Reforming Markets in Health Care. An Economic
Perspective. Open University Press, Buckingham, 2000.
Dawson, D., Gravelle, H., Jacobs, R., Martin, S., Smith, P. The effects of expanding
patient choice of provider on waiting times: evidence from a policy experiment.
Health Economics, 16, 113–128, 2007.
Department of Health. The NHS Plan: a plan for investment, a plan for reform. The
Stationery Office, London, 2000.
Department of Health. Reforming Emergency Care. October 2001.
Department of Health (2002a) Reforming NHS Financial Flows: Introducing Payment
by Results, October 2002.
Department of Health (2002b) A guide to Foundation Trusts. October 2002.
138
Department of Health (2002c) Growing capacity. Independent sector diagnosis and
treatment centres. December 2002.
Department of Health. (2002d) NHS Performance Indicators 6(iv), 6(v), 6 (vi), A (iii),
A(iv), A(v) Clinical Indicators 1A, 1B, 1C. 2002.
http://www.performance.doh.gov.uk/nhsperformanceindicators/2002/trers_t.doc
(accessed October 2007).
Department of Health (2003a). The activity measure for funding inpatient care –
spells or FCEs? Payment by Results Technical Paper, July 2003.
Department of Health (2003b). Response to consultation on Reforming Financial
Flows, February 2003.
Department of Health. (2003c) Payment by Results, Consultation document.
Preparing for 2005. August 2003
Department of Health. The NHS Improvement Plan – putting people at the heart of
public services. The Stationery Office, London, 2004.
Department of Health. (2004a) Calculating Tariff Uplift from FCEs to Spells, January
2004
Department of Health. (2004b) NHS Reference Costs 2003 and national Tariff 2004
(Payment by Results Core tools 2004). February 2004.
Department of Health (2004c). Implementing Payment by Results. Technical
Guidance 2005/06 (version 1.0). December 2004.
Department of Health. Implementing Payment by Results. Technical Guidance
2005/06 (version 2.0) July 2005.
Department of Health. Health Reform in England: update and commissioning
framework. July 2006.
Dismuke, CE., Guimaraes, P. Has the caveat of case-mix based payment influenced
the quality of inpatient hospital care in Portugal? Applied Economics, 34, 10, 13011307, 2002.
Dixon, J. Payment by Results: new financial flows in the NHS. British Medical
Journal, 328, 969-970, 2004.
Donaldson, C., Gerard, K. The Economics of Healthcare Financing: the Visible Hand.
2004.
Goddard, M., Mannion, R., Ferguson, B. Contracting in the UK NHS: purpose,
process and policy. University of York Discussion Paper 156. 1997.
139
Goddard, M., Mannion, R., Smith, P. Enhancing performance in health care: a
theoretical perspective on agency and the role of information. Health Economics,
9:95-107, 2000.
Ham, C. Health Policy in Britain. The politics and organisation of the National
Health Service. Macmillan. 1992.
Healthcare Commission. NHS performance ratings 2003/04. July 2004.
Healthcare Commission. NHS performance ratings 2004/05. July 2005.
Jegers, M., Kesteloot, K., De Graeve, D., Giles, W. A typology for provider payment
systems in health care. Health Policy, 60, 255-273, 2002.
Jervis, P., Plowden, W. The impact of political devolution on the UK’s Health
Services. The Nuffield Trust, 2003.
Kjerstad, E. Prospective funding of general hospitals in Norway – incentives for
higher production? International Journal of Healthcare Finance and Economics, 3,
231-251, 2003.
Ljunggren, B., Sjoden, P-O. Patient reported quality of care before and after the
implementation of a diagnosis related groups classification and payment system in
one Swedish county. Scandinavian Journal of Caring Sciences, 15(4), 283-294, 2001.
Mannion, R., Marini, G., Street, A. Demand management and administrative costs
under payment by results. Health Policy Matters, October 2006.
Mikkola, H. Keskimaki, I., Hakkinen, U. DRG related prices applied in a public
health care system – can Finland learn from Norway and Sweden? Health Policy,
59(1), 37-51, 2002.
Monitor. NHS Foundation Trusts: Review of six months to September 2007. 2007.
http://www.monitor-nhsft.gov.uk/documents/Q2_report_final_Dec07.pdf
Newhouse, JP., Byrne, DJ. Did Medicare prospective payment system cause length of
stay to fall? Journal of Health Economics, 7, 413-416, 1988.
NHS Executive. The new NHS Modern and Dependable: A National Frameworl for
Assessing Performance. Consultation document. January 1998.
Propper C, Sutton M, Witnall C, Windmeijer F. Did targets and terror reduce waiting
times in England for hospital care? CMPO Working Paper Series no. 07/179. 2007.
Raftery, J., Robinson, R,. Mulligan, J., Forrest. S. Contracting in the NHS Quasimarket. Health Economics, 5, 353 – 362, 1996.
Roger-France, F. Case mix use in 25 countries: a migration success but international
comparisons failure. International Journal of Medical Informatics, 70, 215-219, 2003.
140
Roger, R., Williams, S., Jarman, b., Aylin, P. “HRG” drift and payment by results.
British Medical Journal, 330, 563, 2005.
Rosenberg, M., Browne, M. The impact of the inpatient prospective payment system
and diagnostic related groups: a survey of the literature. The North American
Actuarial Journal, 5(4),84-95,2001.
Scottish Executive Health Department. Our National Health: a plan for action, a plan
for change. 2001.
Scottish Executive Health Department. Fair to all, personal to each. The next steps
for Scotland. 2004.
Scottish Executive Health Department. Letter to NHS Board Chief Executives on
2005-06 Implementation 15 July 2005.
Street, A., Sawson, H. Would Roman soldiers fight for the financial flows regime?
The re-issue of Diocletian’s English NHS. Public Money and Management, 24, 5,
301-308, 2004.
Sussex, J., Street, A. Activity-based financing for hospitals: English policy and
international experience. Office of Health Economics, London, 2005.
Timmins, T. Challenges of private provision in the NHS. British Medical Journal,
331, 193-1195, 2005.
141