Doğuş Üniversitesi Dergisi, 13 (1) 2012, 161-170
INTERLINKAGES BETWEEN OPENNESS AND FOREIGN
DEBT IN PAKISTAN
PAKİSTAN’DA DIŞA AÇIKLIK İLE DIŞ BORÇ ARASINDA KARŞILIKLI
BAĞLANTI
Muhammad ZAKARIA
COMSATS Institute of Information Technology, Islamabad, Pakistan
[email protected]
ABSTRACT: The paper empirically studies the impact of trade openness on foreign
debt in Pakistan using quarterly data for the period 1972 to 2010. Generalized
method of Moments (GMM) estimation technique is applied to overcome the
potential endogeneity problem in the model. The study reveals a significant positive
effect of trade openness on foreign debt. The results are robust to different model
specifications. The results also highlight the role of other variables in determining
external debt. Terms of trade, fiscal deficit and inflation significantly positively
affect foreign debt; while foreign Exchange reserves and foreign direct investment
have significant negative impacts on foreign trade.
Keywords: Foreign Debt; Openness; GMM
JEL Classification: C22; F13; F34
ÖZET : Makale, 1972'den 2010'a dek olan dönem için çeyrek dönem verileri
kullanarak, Pakistan'daki dış ticaret serbestliğinin dış borç üzerine olan etkisini
ampirik olarak incelemektedir. Modeldeki potansiyel içsellik probleminin üstesinden
gelmek için Genelleştirilmiş Momentler Yöntemi (GMM) tahmin tekniği
kullanılmıştır. Çalışma, dış ticaret açıklığının dış borç üzerinde anlamlı bir pozitif
etkisi olduğunu ortaya çıkarmaktadır. Sonuçlar farklı model tanımlamalarına göre
robust bulunmuştur. Sonuçlar ayrıca dış borcun belirlenmesinde diğer değişkenlerin
rolünün de altını çizer. Döviz rezervleri ve doğrudan yabancı yatırımların borç
üzerine anlamlı bir negatif etkisi varken, ticaret hadleri, mali açık ve enflasyon dış
borcu anlamlı bir şekilde pozitif olarak etkiler.
Anahtar Kelimeler: Dış Borç; Dışa Açıklık; GMM
1. Introduction
Developing countries accumulate foreign debt at their initial phase of economic
development because in these countries domestic savings and capital stocks are low,
current account deficits are high and capital imports are necessary to enhance
domestic resources. Economic theory also suggests that reasonable levels of external
borrowing are likely to augment growth in developing countries as in these countries
investment returns are apt to be greater than in developed countries. However, this is
true only if borrowed funds are used for productive projects that produce enough
returns to render debt superfluous. Pattillo et al. (2002, 2004) found empirical
support for a nonlinear effect of foreign debt on economic growth. At low levels,
foreign debt positively affects economic growth but above particular thresholds or
turning points, additional debt has a negative impact on growth (the so-called debt
Laffer curve). In the second half of the 1990s and after the recent financial crisis,
policymakers around the world have concerns that high foreign debt in many
162
Muhammad ZAKARIA
developing countries is retarding their economic growth and development. This
concern is also recognized by G-8 leaders, as well as the Bretton-Woods Institutions
and the WTO Ministerial Declaration at the Doha Round in 2001 by emphasizing
the need for a durable solution to the developing countries’ external indebtedness
problem.
Almost all developing countries like Pakistan agree that market access for their
products is a prerequisite to reduce their foreign debt burden by generating trade
surplus. In other words, developing countries can improve their debt position by
increasing their foreign trade, which can be achieved through (both domestic and
world) trade liberalization given that they have export capacity and that they are
globally competitive. According to Auboin (2004) trade openness can improve the
allocation of resources at national and international levels, thereby improving the
buoyancy to external debt shocks. It also favorably affects the debt servicing
capacity of the countries as foreign exchange reserves increase due to increase in net
exports and foreign direct investment – a cheaper source of foreign capital than
foreign borrowing. Further, imported capital goods lead to fast track
industrialization process in the domestic country, which will increase the domestic
growth rate. High output growth and economic development in the country will
decrease the dependence on external borrowing (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti, 2000).
Moreover, trade openness increases credibility in international capital market, which
leads to high level of capital inflows, thereby decreasing the dependence on foreign
debt. All it indicates is that liberalizing trade restrictions can have a positive impact
on external debt and debt servicing position of developing countries. Thus, the
brighter side shows the picture where the external debt is inversely related to the
trade openness measures, any attempt to open the economy may cause a decline in
the external debt burden.
In contrast to these arguments the darker side of the coin particularly for the
developing countries shows a positive relationship between external debt and trade
openness policy. If exports are greater than imports only then external debt position
will be improved after trade openness. However, in developing countries like
Pakistan imports have become larger than exports after trade openness and the scope
for increased exports is also limited, which has created trade deficit in these
countries. To overcome this trade deficit, these countries have borrowed a huge
amount from IMF and other organizations. Further, advancing trade liberalization
requires the gradual removal of exports and imports tariffs, which are important
sources of revenues for developing countries. The resulting fiscal deficits in these
countries may then have to be filled with increased foreign borrowing (Caliari,
2005; Baunsgaard and Keen, 2005). The high dependence on exports of primary
commodities is also an important reason of high external borrowing in developing
countries because world prices of these commodities have been declining for so
many years and that the variability of these prices have made the income stream of
these countries unpredictable (Caliari, 2005). Moreover, when various developing
countries open their borders for international trade simultaneously, export prices
decrease due to an excess supply of similar products (Khattry and Rao, 2002). It
worsens their terms of trade, which adversely affects revenues directly through
reduced export revenues, or indirectly through the lower income earned from
exports and hence lower income tax receipts. Limited available empirical literature
Interlinkages between Openness and Foreign Debt in Pakistan
163
also suggests that in developing countries trade openness has worsened their foreign
debt positions e.g. see Osuji and Olowolayemo (1998), and Zafar and Butt (2008).
Pakistan’s leading challenge today is to reduce its external debt burden through trade
(not aid). To increase trade, Pakistan has opened its economy for international trade
for many years. This trade openness has decreased external debt burden in Pakistan
or not, this is an empirical question. Thus, the objective of this paper is to
empirically analyze the effects of trade openness policies on external debt in
Pakistan using quarterly time series data for the period 1972 to 2010. The
relationship in the context of external debt and trade openness is not familiar in
Pakistan. The only reported study is Zafar and Butt (2008), which has shown
positive effect of trade openness on foreign debt in Pakistan. However, the main
shortcoming of this study is that it does not tackle the endemic problem of
endogeneity among explanatory variables. The results thus found are spurious and
the policy implications drawn are not reliable.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The following section provides a brief
history of trade openness and external debt in Pakistan. Section 3 constructs a
theoretical model. Data description, estimation and interpretation of the results are
provided in Section 4. Final section concludes the paper.
2. Openness and Foreign Debt in Pakistan: A Brief History
2.1. Trade Openness
At the time of independence in 1947, Pakistan implemented import substituting
industrialization policy to protect its nascent industrial units from international
competition. The government facing the foreign exchange shortages after the war
with India in 1965 further implemented different kinds of controls on imports. In
December 1971, after the secession of East Pakistan (now Bangladesh) from West
Pakistan (now Pakistan), government initiated the trade liberalization policies. The
most important policies were the massive devaluation of domestic currency, the
elimination of the export bonus scheme, and the end of restrictive licensing.
However, in late 1970s, when Pakistan faced an acute shortage of foreign exchange
after the oil shock, imports were again restricted with new and more restrictive
nontariff barriers. Under the auspices of the World Bank and the IMF, in late 1980s
government started a comprehensive program of trade liberalization reforms. The
most important initiatives were the reduction of tariffs on a number of raw materials,
intermediate and capital goods, reduction in the number of banned items on
restricted list, replacement of non-tariff barriers with tariffs, and the establishment of
Tariff Commission to make recommendations on fiscal anomalies and effective
protection. The thrust of Pakistan’s trade policies in the 21st century has been on
greater openness through trade liberalization with minimal tariff and non-tariff
barriers and the market based exchange rate system. Pakistan, like many other
countries of the world, is in the process of implementing the provisions of the WTO
guidelines and agreements.
2.2. Foreign Debt
At the time of independence in 1947, domestic saving rate was too low to finance
economic growth through productive investment. Therefore, Pakistan opted for
external borrowing to accelerate the growth rate of the economy with the view that
increased growth rate in future would raise the saving rate and produce sufficient
164
Muhammad ZAKARIA
exportable surplus to retire the debt. This growth strategy remained successful in
1960s when Pakistan witnessed a high level of economic growth. The situation in
1970s was still manageable despite a reduction in growth rate of the economy,
mainly because the size of external debt was small and the terms and conditions for
external borrowing were still acceptable. During 1980s, the situation became critical.
However, the aid from USA to assist in the Afghan war helped to postpone the debt
crisis. As the American aid dried up the situation aggravated during 1990s.
Governments not only opted to postpone the burden by rolling-over the existing debt
but also ignored the core issue of management. After the event of 9/11 when
Pakistan became the front line state against terrorism, it gained a huge amount of
foreign aid from USA. Pakistan also wrote off some of its loans from USA and other
lenders, and also restructured and rescheduled its loans which were due at that time.
Due to hiked oil prices and after the recent financial crisis, Pakistan faced a huge
current account deficit. It has also eroded the foreign exchange reserves of the
country. To cope with this situation Pakistan has agreed a standby program with
IMF worth $11.3 billions but with harsh terms and conditions for reforming the
economy. Now the total foreign debt and liabilities of Pakistan has reached $58.5
billions. Pakistan has paid a total $5.6 billion as debt serving in the fiscal year
2009/10, which accounts for more than 33% of the entire foreign exchange reserves
of the country. The only way to get rid of this vicious circle of debt is to generate
enough income from internal resources to pay off the debt servicing and the debts.
For this purpose, the government has to increase its tax net. If government fails to
generate income from indigenous resources then it has to take more loans to pay
previous loans.
3. The Model
This sub-section derives the foreign debt model, which will be empirically estimated
in subsequent section. In line with precious research on the topic, the following
variables, which include both policy and endogenous ones, are identified as possible
determinants of foreign debt. Each of these variables and the relevant theory that
justifies its inclusion in the model are explained turn by turn.
fdt t 0 1 opennesst 2 tot t 3 fd t 4 forext 5 fdit 6 INFt t
(1)
where the lowercase letters denote that the underlying variables are in natural log
form, and where t ~ N (0, 2 ) . Various variables are defined as follows.
fdtt
= Foreign debt
opennesst
= Trade openness
tott
= Terms of trade
fd t
forext
fdit
= Fiscal deficit
= Foreign direct investment
INFt
= Inflation rate
t
= White-noise error term
= Foreign exchange reserves
As discussed previously the effect of trade openness on foreign debt is equivocal. If
exports earnings are greater than import bill after trade liberalization then openness
Interlinkages between Openness and Foreign Debt in Pakistan
165
is expected to have a negative effect on foreign debt and vice versa. However, in
developing countries imports increase faster than exports after trade liberalization,
therefore trade openness is considered to positively affect foreign debt. Thus, the
coefficient on trade openness 1 is assumed to be positive i.e. 1 0 .
If demand for exported goods is price inelastic, improved terms of trade will
alleviate debt burden problems (Birsdall and Hamoudi, 2002).1 In turn, decline in
terms of trade could lead to a drop in external earnings if this is accompanied by a
decrease in exports, which will further exacerbate the debt burden or stress.
Evidence has shown that terms of trade of developing countries have been
deteriorated for so many years, which has worsened their foreign debt situation.
However, the sign of coefficient of terms of trade 2 cannot be determined a priori.
If a country persistently faces budget deficits then its foreign debt level will increase
(Ishfaq and Chaudhary, 1999). The intuition is that if a country is unable to mobilize
its domestic resources to meet fiscal deficits then it has to rely on foreign resources.
So, fiscal deficit is considered to positively affect foreign debt i.e. 3 0 .
Amassing foreign exchange reserves reduces the demand for foreign borrowing,
therefore it negatively affects the debt stock of the country. Thus, the coefficient of
foreign exchange reserves 4 is assumed to be negative i.e. 4 0. Foreign direct
investment is a stable form of capital relative to other forms of financing. It has
positive spillovers not only on the technical development of host countries but also
on their balance of payments and capital formation (Lehmann, 2002). It also does
not involve capital or interest repayments. Theoretically, the foreign investment is
expected to improve the foreign debt position by generating valuable foreign
exchange for the host country. The coefficient associated with foreign direct
investment 5 is expected to be negative i.e. 5 0 .
As the domestic level of inflation increases exports will decrease and the country
will run trade deficit. Inflation also reduces the real value of government revenues,
thereby creating budget deficits. To tackle both external and internal deficits
government has to borrow funds from abroad. Thus, domestic inflation leads to
accumulation of foreign debt. Further, inflation also increases the nominal value of
foreign debt expressed in local currency. It indicates that the inflation positively
influences the accumulation of foreign debt i.e. 6 0 (Gylfason, 1991).
4. Data, Estimation and Interpretation of Results
4.1. Data Overview
The study employs quarterly time series data for the period 1972 to 2010. Foreign
debt variable is constructed by dividing total foreign debt with nominal GDP. Trade
openness is defined as the ratio of sum of exports and imports to nominal GDP.
Terms of trade is defined as the relative price of exportable to importable.
Government budget deficit is taken as ratio of GDP. Foreign exchange reserves are
taken in real terms. Foreign direct investment is obtained by dividing foreign direct
investment with nominal GDP. Inflation is growth rate of CPI. The data is taken
1
Improved terms of trade will aggravate debt burden problem if demand for exported goods is price
elastic.
166
Muhammad ZAKARIA
from International Financial Statistics (IFS), World Development Indicators (WDI)
and Pakistan Economic Surveys.
Table 1 contains summary statistics for the variables used in this study, which may
help in the interpretation of the coefficient estimates by providing the scale of the
relevant variables. Table 2 presents the correlation matrix for the variables. Column
(1) of Table 2 correlates foreign debt with all independent variables. The value of
correlation coefficient of openness variable is 0.32, which indicates that foreign debt
is positively correlated with trade openness. Figure 1 plots the simple regression
between foreign debt and total trade. The figure displays an apparent positive
(nonlinear, inverse S-shaped) relationship between foreign debt and total trade in
Pakistan. The positive relationship shows that as trade increases, to finance trade
deficit government borrows more funds from abroad. The rate at which government
borrows funds first increases, then decreases and then again starts increasing,
thereby giving a nonlinear inverse S-shaped curve. However, it is evident from the
figure that as the number of ploynominal terms are increased, the value of their
coefficients become economically weak. The simple regression analysis, being
essentially bivariate and simplistic, calls for exploration in a more rigorous
framework. This is what the next section of the paper attempts to do.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of the Variables [1972Q1 – 2010Q2]
Variables
Mean
Median
Foreign Debt (% of GDP)
Openness (% of GDP)
Terms of Trade
Fiscal Deficit (% of GDP)
Foreign Exchange
Reserves ($ Billions)
Foreign Direct
Investment (% of GDP)
Inflation (%)
228.35
34.03
1.50
7.04
227.37
34.07
1.52
7.00
Standard
Deviation
53.75
5.03
0.37
2.03
2.87
0.91
0.92
2.30
Minimum
Maximum
Count
128.70
16.61
0.72
2.39
369.37
52.80
2.58
13.15
154
154
154
154
3.93
0.11
14.51
154
0.59
1.11
0.01
6.27
154
1.81
2.11
-1.15
15.26
153
Table 2. Correlation Matrix for the
Variables Included in the Regressions [1972Q1 – 2010Q2]
Foreign
Terms of
Openness
Debt
Trade
Foreign Debt
Openness
Terms of Trade
Fiscal Deficit
Foreign Exchange
Reserves
Foreign Direct
Investment
Inflation
Fiscal
Deficit
Foreign
Foreign
Exchange
Direct
Inflation
Reserves Investment
1
0.32
0.68
0.58
1
-0.34
-0.09
1
0.44
1
-0.68
0.28
-0.76
-0.63
1
-0.55
0.s39
-0.63
-0.35
0.69
1
0.25
0.26
0.06
0.16
-0.02
0.07
1
Interlinkages between Openness and Foreign Debt in Pakistan
167
Figure 1. Simple Regression between Foreign Debt
and Total Trade [1972Q1 – 2010Q2]
4.2. Estimation and Interpretation of the Results
To estimate our model we cannot apply least square method as the potential
endogeneity of the variables can render the least square estimators biased and
inconsistent. Therefore, we have applied Generalized Method of Moments (GMM)
estimation technique of Arellano and Bond (1991), Arellano (1993) and Arellano
and Bover (1995) to estimate foreign debt equation. The GMM estimators control
for the potential endogeneity of the lagged dependent variable and for the potential
endogeneity of other explanatory variables in the model (Judson and Owen, 1999).
Lagged values of the variables are used as instruments.2
Results of foreign debt equation (1) are reported in Table 3. The t-statistics on
openness coefficient (2.247) indicates that there is a statistically significant positive
relationship between trade openness and foreign debt in Pakistan.3 The coefficient
for the openness stood at 0.239, which means that a one-standard-deviation increase
in openness (5.03) leads to about 1.2 percent increase in foreign debt. In other words,
one percent increase in openness will increase foreign debt by 0.239 percent. The
fraction of the variation in foreign debt due to openness, as explained by column (2),
is nontrivial. The remaining columns of the table investigate the robustness of these
results to some simple changes in specification. These changes alter the results only
trivially. Thus, the estimated impact of trade openness on foreign debt is robust to
alternative equation specifications. This finding is consistent with the notion that
trade openness leads to more imports than exports. To overcome this external deficit
a country has to borrow from abroad. The results show that trade deficits and the
2
To verify long-run relationship between dependent and independent variables, we have applied ADF
unit-root tests. The results show that only one variable namely inflation is stationary at levels, while the
remaining five variables are integrated of order one. It indicates that the estimate of foreign debt equation
can form a long-run relationship of foreign debt with five of the six explanatory variables, while the
relationship with the one stationary variable is based on short-term variations in the latter.
3
To check the non-linear effect of openness on foreign debt, both squared and cubic terms of openness
were included in the model. However, their effects on foreign debt turned out to be statistically
insignificant and hence excluded from the estimation.
168
Muhammad ZAKARIA
resulting foreign debt is a constraint on policymakers’ incentives to liberalize trade
in Pakistan.
Terms of trade significantly positively affects foreign debt. It indicates that in
Pakistan demand for exported goods is price elastic, thereby improvement in terms
of trade will aggravate debt burden problems. In fact, Pakistan’s main exports
include low value added and primary goods. These goods are not only price elastic
and but the world prices of these commodities are steadily declining for so many
years and they are subjected to sharp fluctuations. The value of coefficient on terms
of trade indicates that one percent improvement in terms of trade will increase the
level of foreign debt by 0.503 percent. This result is robust with alternative equation
specifications. Fiscal deficit variable also significantly positively affect the foreign
debt in Pakistan. The results show that as fiscal deficit increases by one percent of
GDP, foreign debt increases by 0.111 percent of GDP. This result is consistent with
the findings of Ishfaq and Chaudhary (1999), who have also shown that fiscal deficit
has positively affected Pakistan’s foreign debt position. Consistent with the
theoretical literature foreign exchange reserves have shown a significant negative
effect on foreign debt. The value of coefficient indicates that one percent increase in
foreign exchange reserves will decrease the foreign debt burden by 0.05 percent of
GDP. Although statistically this result is significant, economically it is somewhat
weak.
Table 3: The GMM Estimates of the Relationship between Foreign Debt and
Trade Openness [1972Q1 – 2010Q2]
Constant
(1)
(2)
(3)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1.392
0.986
0.563
1.891
1.338
0.925
0.900
1.649
0.916
(5.157)*
Openness
0.239
(5.523)* (4.064)* (5.740)* (5.555)* (6.467)* (5.372)* (7.877)* (3.320)*
0.265
0.070
(2.247)* (1.671)** (0.520)
Terms of Trade
Fiscal Deficit
Foreign Exchange
Reserves
Foreign Direct
Investment
Inflation
AR(1)
0.295
0.247
0.253
0.268
0.255
0.372
(2.275)* (2.073)* (2.245)* (1.835)** (2.655)* (2.889)*
0.503
0.670
0.584
(4.841)*
(4.998)*
(6.905)*
0.111
0.296
0.319
(1.757)**
(3.292)*
(4.646)*
-0.052
-0.078
(-1.903)**
(-2.292)*
0.035
(1.214)
-0.015
0.006
(-1.687)**
(0.692)
-0.022
(-2.283)*
0.575
0.661
1.349
(2.469)*
(2.066)*
(3.940)*
0.860
(2.862)*
0.935
0.873
0.899
0.927
0.942
0.952
0.765
0.968
(4.946)* (2.398)* (3.520)* (5.136)* (5.101)* (4.691)* (8.656)* (5.962)*
R2
0.920
0.927
0.906
0.912
0.922
0.926
0.933
0.894
0.917
Adjusted R2
0.916
0.926
0.904
0.911
0.920
0.924
0.931
0.891
0.914
S.E. of regression
0.069
0.065
0.073
0.071
0.067
0.065
0.062
0.078
0.069
DW statistics
1.930
2.073
1.993
1.917
2.126
2.098
2.085
2.059
2.208
Note: Values in parentheses denote underlying student-t values. The t statistics significant at 5 % and
10 % levels of significance are indicated by * and ** respectively.
Like foreign exchange reserves, foreign direct investment also has a significant
negative effect on foreign debt. The value of the estimated coefficient shows that if
Interlinkages between Openness and Foreign Debt in Pakistan
169
foreign direct investment increases by one percent of GDP foreign debt will
decrease by 0.015 percent of GDP. Again this result is statistically significant but
economically it is weak. The reason is that Pakistan has a very limited amount of
foreign investment and at worst foreign investment has decreased to a considerable
extent in recent years due to eruption of terrorist activities in the country. Finally, as
theoretically expected, inflation has eroded the foreign debt position in the country.
The results show that one percent increase in inflation will increase foreign debt by
0.575 percent of GDP. Recent high inflation and the projected double digit inflation
in next few years are contemplated to further exacerbate the situation. Reasonable
values of overall R-squares and adjusted R-squares suggest that the model fits the
data well. In estimations autoregressive (AR) process has been applied to remove
autocorrelation problem from the models. The values of Durbin-Watson (DW)
statistics are reasonably close to the desired value of two, indicating the absence of
autocorrelation problem.
5. Conclusion
In recent empirical literature much attention has been given to explore the effect of
trade openness on various macroeconomic variables like growth, income inequality,
inflation, etc. However, only limited attention is given to the issue of impact of trade
openness on external debt burden. The present paper tries to fill this gap. This paper
empirically examines the effect of trade openness on foreign debt in Pakistan using
quarterly time series data for the period 1947 to 2010. To control the potential
endogeneity problem GMM estimation technique has been applied. The results show
that trade openness has a statistically significant positive effect on foreign debt in
Pakistan, which indicates that in Pakistan trade openness is acting as a stimulator of
external debt accumulation. This result is robust with different model specifications.
The results also show that foreign debt depends on a number of other endogenous
and policy variables. Specifically, fluctuations in foreign debt can be explained by
terms of trade shocks, government fiscal policies, accumulation of foreign exchange
reserves, foreign investment policies, and domestic inflation rate.
For openness to reduce the debt burden, Pakistan has to take appropriate steps to
boost its exports. Pakistan needs to, inter alia, increase export competitiveness,
improve and strengthen trade infrastructures, diversify exports from primary goods
to value-added goods, support the technological content of exports, foster infant
industries by providing financing, and enhance overall productivity and
competitiveness. To increase its exports Pakistan also needs to increase its access to
foreign market, particularly to the European Union and USA for its textile exports.
For this purpose Pakistan can use export marketing strategies. Pakistan also needs to
reduce inflation rate as domestic inflation is higher compared to inflation in the
counter trading partners, which is discouraging exports. On the import side, Pakistan
has to transform its imports from consumer goods to capital goods because capital
goods are usually associated with better productivity and higher returns over the
investment. Further, importation of capital goods leads to increase in domestic
output of goods and services, which ultimately result in the less dependence on the
import sector and thus reduce the external debt burden.
External trade policies should be supported by policies aimed at mobilizing
domestic private savings and foreign investment. To mobilize private savings there
is need to improve macroeconomic management and financial sector. To increase
170
Muhammad ZAKARIA
foreign investment inflows Pakistan has to improve law and order situation and
business condition in the country. Further, a thorough evaluation of programs and
policies introduced by the IMF and the World Bank is inevitable as some of the
packages are adversely affecting the Pakistan’s economy.
References
ARELLANO, M. (1993). On testing of correlation effects with panel data. Journal of
Econometrics, 59 (1), pp.87-97.
ARELLANO, M., BOVER, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation
of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, pp.29-51.
ARELLANO, M., BOND, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo
evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58,
pp.277-297.
AUBOIN, M. (2004). The trade, debt and finance nexus: at the cross-roads of micro-and
macroeconomics. Discussion Paper No. 2004(6), WTO, Geneva.
BAUNSGAARD, T., KEEN, M. (2005). Tax revenue and (or?) trade liberalization. IMF
Working Paper No. 2005(112), Washington DC.
BIRDSALL, N., HAMOUDI, A. (2002). Commodity dependence, trade and growth: when
“openness” is not enough. CGD Working Paper No. 2002(7), Washington DC.
CALIARI, A. (2005). The debt-trade connection in debt management initiatives: need for
paradigm change. in Debt and Trade: Time to Make the Connections., Dublin, Ireland:
Veritas Publication, pp.101-122.
GYLFASON, T. (1991). Inflation, growth, and external debt: a view of the landscape. World
Economy, 14(3), pp.279-297.
ISHFAQ, M., CHAUDHARY, M.A. (1999). Fiscal deficits and debt dimensions of Pakistan.
Pakistan Development Review, 38(4), pp.1067-1080.
JUDSON, R.A., OWEN, A.L. (1999). Estimating dynamic panel data models: a guide for
macroeconomists, Economics Letters, 65(1), pp.9-15.
KHATTRY, B., RAO, J.M. (2002). Fiscal faux pas?: an analysis of the revenue implications
of trade liberalization. World Development Review, 30(8), pp.1431-1444.
LANE, P.R., MILESI-FERRETTI, G.M. (2000). External capital structure: theory and
evidence. IMF Working Paper No. 2000(152), Washington DC.
LEHMAN, A. (2002). Foreign direct investment in emerging markets: income, repatriations
and financial vulnerabilities. IMF Working Paper No. 2002(47), Washington DC.
OSUJI, L. O., OLOWOLAYEMO, S.O. (1998). The impact of trade liberalization policy on
Sub-Saharan African countries’ debt burden. African Economic and Business Review,
1(2), pp.59-73.
PATTILLO, C.A., POIRSON, H., RICCI, L.A. (2002). External debt and growth. IMF
Working Paper No. 2002(69), Washington DC.
PATTILLO, C.A., POIRSON, H., RICCI, L.A. (2004). What are the channels through which
external debt affects growth?. IMF Working Paper No. 2004(15), Washington DC.
ZAFAR, S., BUTT, M.S. (2008). Impact of trade liberalization on external debt burden:
econometric evidence from Pakistan. Working Paper No. 2008(9548), MPRA.